Invoicing Currency Choice:
Strategic Complementarities and Currency Matching
Yushi Yoshida
a f
, Junko Shimizu
b f
, Takatoshi Ito
c f
, Kiyotaka Sato
d f
,
Taiyo Yoshimi
e f
, and Uraku Yoshimoto
f
a
Shiga University
b
Gakushuin University
c
Columbia University and NBER
d
Yokohama National University
e
Chuo University
f
Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance
January 5, 2024
Abstract
Japanese exporters’ choice of invoice currencies is investigated using newly available of-
ficial Customs declaration data, which records detailed information, including the trading
partners’ names, invoicing currency, and product descriptions. The strategic complementar-
ity mechanism, that is, choosing the same invoice currency as others in the same industry or
the same destination market, is found among Japanese exporters. We propose the “broad
two-way exporters” whose export destinations and import origins do not necessarily match
and the “narrow two-way exporters” whose export destination and import origins match in
the same year. It is found that currency matching for exports and imports is as essential as
strategic complementarity for two-way exporters. However, as one of this paper’s novelty,
we found evidence that newly entering two-way exporters are less concerned about currency
matching. Therefore, the currency matching mechanism for two-way exporters is gradually
formed as they continue to survive in international markets.
corresponding author: yushi.yoshida@biwako.shiga-u.ac.jp. This study is the result of research conducted
jointly with the Policy Research Institute (PRI), which submitted an offer of use to the Ministry of Finance based
on the “Guideline on the utilization of Customs’ import and export declaration data in a joint research with Policy
Research Institute,” and received approval in February 2022. The views expressed in this research are those of the
author’s personal responsibility and do not represent the official views of the Ministry of Finance or the Policy
Research Institute of the Ministry of Finance. The authors thank the staff at the PRI for the great research
support they received, especially Kenta Ando, Fumiharu Ito, and Shintaro Negishi, for the use of transaction-
level microdata. We especially thank Wanyu Chung, Rob Elliott, and Kazunobu Hayakawa for their insightful
comments on the earlier version of this paper, and we also thank the participants in the research meetings at the
PRI, universit´e Sud Bretagne, University of Birmingham, ETSG conference at the University of Surry, French-
Japanese Webinar, and JSME conference at Kyushu University for their useful comments. Yoshida gratefully
acknowledges financial support from the JSPS KAKENHI 20H01518, 22K18527, and 23H00836. Shimizu, Sato,
Yoshimi, and Yoshimoto thank 18K01698, 23H00836 & 23K17550, 20H01518 & 20KK0289, and JP21K20172, for
financial support, respectively.
1
Keywords: Currency Matching; Customs Data; Dominant Currency; invoicing currency;
Strategic Complementarities.
JEL Classification: F14; F31; F61.
2
1 Introduction
In addition to making decisions for producing and distributing their products to foreign cus-
tomers, exporters must choose the invoicing currency for their exports. Faced with fluctuating
exchange rates, the choice of invoicing currency affects the exporter’s revenue in terms of home
currency, as discussed in Gopinath and Rigobon (2008) and Gopinath, Itskhoki, and Rigobon
(2010).
1
This study investigates determinants of invoicing currency choice by utilizing the ex-
port/import transaction level data at Japan Customs that have become available recently. Each
transaction entry includes the identification of the exporter/importer, the departing/landing
port, the content of products, invoicing currency, volume, value, the identification of the trading
partner, the port in the partner’s country, mode of transport, and other detailed information
regarding exporting and importing.
Instead of working on individual raw transaction records, we aggregated transaction records
by pairs of exporters and trading partner countries. The choice of the aggregation strategy
makes us depart from the existing studies in the literature. The aggregation of granular data is
not usually pursued in research simply because of fear of losing information and the number of
observations. However, the benefits of some aggregation outweigh the cost. Invoicing currency
decisions at the granular level are not independent of each other.
The choice of invoice currency will depend on the destination countries. For example, the
exporter is more likely to choose US dollar invoicing for exports to the United States while
choosing the British Pound for exports to the United Kingdom. These considerations lead us to
work on the pairs of exporters and trading partner countries. Moreover, there will be no loss of
observations, as the aggregation still leaves the data set with three million transaction records
of exports for seven years between 2014 and 2020, as shown in Table 2.
Using the Belgian firm transaction level data, Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) showed the
phenomenon called strategic complementarity, i.e., the competitors’ choice of invoicing currency
in the same industry and market induces an exporter to choose the same currency.
2
Following
Gopinath, Itskhoki, and Rigobon (2010) and Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022), we examine
whether Japanese exporters choose invoicing currency with consideration of strategic comple-
1
The choice of invoicing currency also has a macroeconomic consequence for the importing country. If a large
portion of the import is invoiced in the importing country’s currency, i.e., local currency pricing, the import price
index shows a small change with respect to a change in the exchange rate. In contrast, invoiced in the exporter’s
currency, i.e., producer currency pricing, the import price index demonstrates a relatively large proportionate
change.
2
Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2019) define strategic complementarity in terms of the elasticity of own price
to a change in the competitors’ price.
3
mentarities, that is, to select the same invoicing currency as their competitors. For exporters
facing competition from other firms, setting their prices to move in tandem with competitors’
prices is essential. For example, Japanese exporters use the US dollar as invoicing currency
because their competitors also use US dollar invoicing in the same destination country and/or
in the same industry. Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) constructed strategic complemen-
tarity variables at the industry-destination level. However, they did not differentiate exports
by destination or by industry. We investigate which one of the destination countries or which
industry factor puts more pressure on an exporter’s choice of invoice currency. The country-
specific strategic complementarity variable is the ratio of all other firms’ exports invoiced in the
US dollar to the overall export value of all other firms in the destination country. The industry-
level strategic complementarity variable is constructed in two steps. First, we construct the US
dollar ratio in each HS 4-digit industry by all other firms to all destination countries. Second,
the weighted average of US dollar ratios at HS 4-digit industries, with weight being the share of
firms’ exports in the industry over the firm’s total exports.
In addition, we also find that exporters tend to choose the invoicing currency for exports to
match the invoicing currency for their imports. Previous studies in the literature found such
a link. Chung (2016) finds that using producer currency for inputs increases the likelihood of
UK exporters choosing local currency for exports. As in other authors, the observation unit
in Chung (2016) is firm-product-destination. We generalize the concept and broaden it to the
firm-destination level. The Japanese exporters favor using US dollar invoicing in exports to
a destination if their imports from the same country are invoiced in US dollars. This is not
only so for the case of dominant currency but also applies to the cases of producer currency
pricing and local currency invoicing. With this data set, we define narrow two-way exporters as
exporters that export to and import from the same country.
3
Among determinants of invoicing
currency choice, we found that currency matching is as essential as strategic complementarity
for exporters who do imports and exports. By matching the invoice currency for exports with
that for imports, the exporter can minimize the exchange risk generated by currency mismatch.
Our contribution is sixfold. First, this study is one of the first to use the Japan Customs
transaction data, which have only recently become available for select researchers. The avail-
ability of transaction-level data with information on currency invoicing made it possible for us to
push forward the research on invoicing currency choice for Japanese exporters. Some countries
have inherent problems in investigating the issue of invoicing currency choice. The US dollar
is simultaneously the dominant and local currency for US imports, as argued in (Gopinath and
3
In the empirical section, we propose narrowly defined and broadly defined two-way exporters.
4
Rigobon 2008); therefore, it is impossible to distinguish between the effects of local and dominant
currency. A particular problem arises for EU member countries: No information on invoicing
currency is recorded at the Customs office because intra-EU trade is exempt from customs. The
Belgian exporters use the euro extensively with neighboring countries
4
; thus, excluding these ex-
ports from the analysis may distort the results(Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings 2022), reducing the
sample size significantly. Since the U.K. is not in the Eurozone, the UK data seem to have fewer
similar problems, as shown in Chung (2016),Crowley, Han, and Son (2021),Corsetti, Crowley,
and Han (2022).
5
Therefore, investigating the exporters with their home currency being neither
the dollar nor the euro is expected to make an important contribution to the literature.
6
Using
the new data set for Japanese firms, we examine how dollar invoicing is used for non-dollar des-
tination countries without discarding a large portion of trade data, unlike some previous studies
in the literature.
Second, the primary variable of analysis is the firm-destination pair. Instead of using raw
transaction data, we aggregated the data at the level of exporting firms and destination coun-
tries. In this way, we can capture the exporters’ motive for the common invoicing currency,
i.e., the cost of managing multiple currencies can be avoided. More formally, the decisions on
invoicing currency are not independent among transactions, at least for those under the same
macroeconomic environment, i.e., exports to the same destination country. We are aware of the
trade-off between the benefit of aggregation and the loss of detailed information. The optimal
level of aggregation for investigating the choice of invoicing currency depends on the objective
of the research. We believe that using a firm-destination pair in this study brings forth several
advantages without significant loss of information in the original dataset. We assume that firms
make an invoicing currency decision at the partner country level, not at each transaction level.
Theoretical models in the literature, for example, Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) assume
that a firm sells only one product to one market. In this case, the solution to the firm’s optimiza-
tion problem leads to a uniquely chosen single currency. However, in reality, a firm tends to sell
many products to the same market. The firm’s optimal decision would not be a single currency
for exports for all products. Different products may have different invoicing currencies. The
choice of a product is affected by each product’s idiosyncratic sensitivity of marginal cost and
4
In 2018, non-EU destination exports (imports) by Belgian firms made up only 27 (34) percent of total exports
(imports), (Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings 2022). However, Boz, Casas, Georgiadis, Gopinath, Le Mezo, Mehl,
and Nguyen (2022) demonstrate that assuming the use of the euro being 100 percent within the Euro area is not
plausible.
5
In 2011, non-EU destination exports by UK firms accounted for 46.5% of the total UK exports, (Chung 2016).
6
The strong presence of the Japanese yen in foreign exchange markets also makes it interesting. The Japanese
yen as an invoicing currency is relatively more acceptable by trading partners than minor currencies.
5
markup to foreign currencies. Our empirical analysis shows that the firm’s invoicing currency
decisions are well explained at the firm-country pair level.
Third, we provide two decomposed dimensions of strategic complementarity: destination
country and industry. The existing studies, such as Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022), measure
strategic complementarity at the firm- industry-country level. The index at this level correctly
captures the interaction among the Belgian exporters, but distinguishing the difference among
destinations is not measured. We constructed a strategic complementary index based on the
destination country, i.e., how much other Japanese exporters use US dollars as an invoicing
currency given the destination country. The other index based on industry is more complicated
because we use firm-level instead of single transaction as a unit of observations. As a preliminary
step, we construct the US dollar ratio as an invoicing currency for each HS 4-digit industry. Then,
we calculate a weighted US dollar ratio by other exporters with weights as industry proportions
of an exporter’s exports. We find that the positive effects of both dimensions of strategic
complementarity are statistically significant and robust to any specifications. The magnitude
of strategic complementarity at the industry dimension is significantly larger. Therefore, the
invoicing currency choice is driven more by which industry an exporter competes in than where
it competes.
Fourth, two definitions of two-way exporters are proposed considering the matching of invoic-
ing currencies between exports and imports. broad two-way exporters are defined as those who
export and import, with destination and origin may not be the same. Narrow two-way exporters
are defined as those who export to and import from the same country. We find that narrow
two-way exporters are more inclined to match invoicing currencies of exports and imports than
broad two-way exporters.
Fifth, we adopt a fractional probit regression with instrumental variables. In the previous
studies examining the invoicing currency choice at the transaction level, probit or logit models
were applied to the binary dependent variable of taking the value of one if the target currency
is chosen and zero otherwise. We apply the fractional probit estimation method because the
invoicing currency ratio ranges between zero and one.
Sixth, we also examine the invoicing currency choice of firms newly entering export markets.
The panel estimates may suffer from biased estimates because currency invoicing decisions are
persistent. Long-surviving firms may only repeatedly use the same currency as the previous
years. In order to capture the first decision of choosing invoicing currency, new entrants that
did not engage in any international trade in the last year are free from such a bias. The currency
matching motive is less pursued, whereas the strategic complementarity motive is essential from
6
the first year.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The next section describes how the data set
is prepared in this study. Section 3 provides empirical models, and section 4 shows empirical
evidence. Section 5 revisits the invoicing currency choice of new exporters, and the last section
concludes.
2 Invoicing Currency Choice at the Firm-Country level
2.1 The Export and Import Declarations submitted to the Japan Customs
Office
The data set became available in 2022 under a program of government-owned data utilization
at the Ministry of Finance, Japan.
7
The data consists of a complete set of general export and
import declarations between 2014 and 2020.
8
Each transaction is recorded as a separate record,
even for the same firm, and the number of records for exports is in the order of millions for one
year. Table 1 summarizes this dataset between 2014 and 2020 by invoicing currency.
The left part of Table 1 provides the statistical summary of this export data set. On the
top row, with the total export values at the leftmost, the ratios of invoicing currencies are
shown. Four currencies of interest are (i) the Japanese yen, the producer currency for Japanese
exporters; (ii) the US dollar, the dominant currency of the world; (iii) the euro, the largest
regional currency in Europe; and (iv) local currencies, i.e., the official national currency used in
the destination country. US dollars have the largest share, 51 percent, in the invoicing currency
of Japanese exports. The Japanese yen is also extensively used for 36 percent of the invoiced
currency in Japanese exports, but the euro plays a small part as it is only 6 percent of Japan’s
exports. The seemingly high ratio of local currency invoicing can be explained using the US
dollar in the US and the Euro in the Euro area.
Panel A of Table 1 shows the use of invoicing currencies by country and region. The US
dollar is overwhelmingly used in exports to the US market, and it is also the largest invoicing
currency in China and the rest of Asia. Although a small share in overall trade, Euro invoicing
is significant at 56 percent in the Euro area.
9
For the rest of the world, excluding the US and
Euro area, the local currency invoicing is below six percent, not shown in the table.
7
Researchers affiliated with universities need to be cross-appointed by the Ministry of Finance and work under
the binding regulations of public officers. Any private information revealed to the researchers during the research
must be kept secret.
8
Low-value cargoes under the simplified customs clearance are excluded from the database.
9
The countries included in the Asia and Euro area are listed in the appendix.
7
Panel B of Table 1 shows invoicing currency for selected industries. The overall picture does
not change much; however, the Japanese yen is the most-used invoicing currency in the textile
industry, and the US dollar use is even amplified to 68 percent in the base metal industry. The
right part represents the invoicing currency for imports. Like exports, the US dollar is also
the dominant invoicing currency in Japanese imports. The use of the US dollar is even more
pronounced in imports, 61 percent. The noteworthy facts are that 71 percent of imports from
China are invoiced in the US dollar, and textile imports are invoiced in the currency of the
exporting country for only five percent.
8
Table 1: Invoice currency by region and industry (2014-2020)
Exports Imports
values JPY (PCP) USD EUR LC values JPY (LCP) USD EUR PC
ALL 552 0.36 0.51 0.06 0.27 563 0.32 0.61 0.04 0.14
Panel A: by trading regions values JPY (PCP) USD EUR LC values JPY (LCP) USD EUR PC
US 105 0.13 0.87 0.00 0.87 61 0.25 0.74 0.01 0.74
Euro Area 46 0.32 0.12 0.56 0.56 55 0.53 0.11 0.33 0.33
China 136 0.42 0.52 0.00 0.06 138 0.24 0.71 0.01 0.04
ASIA 167 0.47 0.47 0.00 0.05 133 0.38 0.58 0.00 0.03
Panel B: by HS sections values JPY (PCP) USD EUR LC values JPY (LCP) USD EUR PC
Chemical (Sec.6) 44 0.33 0.57 0.05 0.20 47 0.54 0.38 0.04 0.16
Textiles (Sec.11) 7 0.48 0.45 0.05 0.12 29 0.16 0.79 0.03 0.05
Base Metal (Sec.15) 46 0.26 0.68 0.03 0.13 28 0.37 0.57 0.03 0.13
Machinery & Electronics (Sec.16) 204 0.41 0.47 0.07 0.24 134 0.25 0.67 0.05 0.16
Transport (Sec.17) 127 0.31 0.50 0.08 0.48 23 0.50 0.31 0.14 0.25
Precision Instruments (Sec. 18) 35 0.35 0.49 0.09 0.29 25 0.43 0.41 0.07 0.28
Note: The figures in the first column (values) represent the total export values in trillion Japanese yen between 2014 and 2020.
The figures in other columns represent the ratio of invoice currency used in the corresponding region/sectors. LC and PC are
trade partners’ currencies. LC in exports represents local currency invoicing, and PC in imports represents producer currency
invoicing. Asia region includes 21 countries, excluding China. The number of countries in the Euro Area varies as new members
adopt the Euro. The countries in the Asia and Euro Area are listed in the appendix. ’0.00’ in some cells is not exactly zero, only
representing rounded values. Sections 6, 11, 15, 16, 17, and 18, respectively, consist of a group of two-digit industries (chapters):
HS28 through HS38, HS50 through HS63, HS72 through HS83, HS84 and HS85, HS86 through HS89, and HS90 through HS92.
9
2.2 Firm-country Invoicing Currency Ratio
The previous studies extensively used the Custom data at the transaction level to investigate
the exporters’ choice of invoicing currency (Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings 2022, Gopinath, Boz,
Casas, D´ıez, Gourinchas, and Plagborg-Møller 2020, Chung 2016, Crowley, Han, and Son 2021,
Devereux, Dong, and Tomlin 2017) among others. The optimal currency choice problem in
Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) can be shown as follows:
l = argmax
l
(max
p
l
i
EΠ
i
(p
l
i
e
l
| Ω)) (1)
where firm i determines the level of optimal price, p
l
i
, for a given currency l and its associated
exchange rate e
l
to maximize the expected profit, Π
i
. The expected profit is also conditional
with information set Ω. Export i chooses currency l, which brings the highest expected profit
among other currencies.
However,Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) discuss the possibility of firms adopting com-
mon invoicing when considering additional fixed costs associated with using each currency.
l = argmax
l
(max
p
l
i
EΠ
i
(p
l
i
e
l
| Ω) F
l,i
) (2)
where they introduce an additional fixed cost F
l,i
for using currency l for exporter i. Reducing the
number of currencies saves an exporter fixed costs associated with managing additional foreign
currencies. Therefore, treating individual transactions of the same firm separately misses the
firm’s possible strategy of common invoicing. Exporters need to make the choice of invoicing
currency for each transaction, and they have to make these decisions several times over the period
if they make multiple transactions. However, these decisions are not mutually independent. A
straightforward way to capture the tendency to use the common currency is to calculate the
likelihood of each firm using dollars, i.e., the ratio of the sum of dollar-invoiced transactions to
all transactions.
Furthermore, we assume fixed cost also varies with destination country k,
l = argmax
l
(max
p
l
i
EΠ
i
(p
l
i
e
l
| Ω) F
l,i,k
) (3)
We assume a currency-firm-destination idiosyncratic fixed effect because the cost associated with
currency management should differ between the use of US dollars in the US and in UK, i.e.,
F
USD,i,U S
̸= F
USD,i,U K
. Whether this specification is appropriate is an empirical question, and
we pursue this dimension of data granularity in this study.
We now describe how we calculate each firm-country pair’s US dollar invoicing ratio. The
export and import declarations, which exporters and importers must submit to Japan Customs,
10
Figure 1: The invoicing currency ratio and currency matching
Note: This figure represents the subset of transaction-level data in the data and shows how the
calculation of the invoicing currency ratio is structured.
include the identity of the reporting company and the foreign trading partner, product char-
acterization, corresponding HS 9-digit code, the value and quantity of transactions, and the
invoicing currency. The value of each transaction record has five arguments: invoicing currency
c, firm i, product j, partner country k, and year t: val(c, i, j, k, t). We construct the dollar
invoicing ratio by exporter-destination pairs in year t as follows.
ϕ
i,k,t
= IC
c=D,i,k,t
=
P
j,c=D
val(c, i, j, k, t)
P
c,j
val(c, i, j, k, t)
, (4)
where c = D represents the US dollar invoicing currency. The numerator in equation (4)
represents the value of transactions invoiced in US dollars, and the denominator is the value
of all transactions. For the rest of the paper, we use IC with corresponding subscripts, D, to
denote the dollar invoice ratio.
Figure 1 demonstrates how an invoicing currency ratio, ϕ
i,k,t
, is calculated with the example
of four export transactions by exporter A. In the example, export transactions are invoiced in
different currencies; however, we set exchange rates so that the values of all transactions are
equivalent in the common currency. Exporter A exported to the UK in two transactions, both
invoiced in US dollars, and to Germany in two transactions, one in US dollars and the other in
11
Japanese yen. In this case, ϕ
A,UK,t
= 1.00 and ϕ
A,DE,t
= 0.50.
2.3 Determinants of Currency Choice
Gopinath, Boz, Casas, D´ıez, Gourinchas, and Plagborg-Møller (2020) propose the dominant
currency paradigm in which exporters set prices in a dominant currency, face strategic com-
plementarities in pricing, and use foreign inputs. Following their dominant currency paradigm
model, they empirically confirm the model’s implications by using the worldwide coverage of
bilateral trades. The theoretical model in Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) showed that
the desired exchange rate pass-through depends on the exposure of the firm’s marginal cost to
exchange rates, ϕ, and the exposure of the firm’s desired markup to exchange rates, γ. In turn,
the invoicing currency is chosen based on the lowest variance of the desired price expressed in
that currency. Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) proxy for ϕ with the firm’s share of im-
ported inputs in total variable costs, sourced in foreign (non-euro) currencies for the Belgian
exporters. The proxy variables for γ use the export-weighted average currency use of the firm’s
Belgian competitors in a given destination industry. Using the UK transaction level of exports
and imports between 2010 and 2016, Crowley, Han, and Son (2021) find that the US dollar is
an invoicing currency choice for UK exports to extra-EU destinations, i.e., transactions with all
countries outside of the EU, are driven by strategic complementarities, operational hedging, and
prior experience.
2.3.1 Strategic Complementarity Indices
The first strategic complementary index we introduce is the likelihood of dollar use by the
competitors in the destination market, k.
γ
k,t
= IC
c=D,i,k,t
=
P
c=D,i,j
val(c, i, j, k, t)
P
c,i,j
val(c, i, j, k, t)
(5)
where i indicates that the sum is taken over for all firms except firm i.
The second strategic complementary index is the likelihood of dollar use by the competitors
in the industries associated with the firm. This takes two steps. First, we construct the dollar
invoicing ratio in each HS 4-digit industry.
IC
c=D,i,j,t
=
P
c=D,i,k
val(c, i, j, k, t)
P
c,i,k
val(c, i, j, k, t)
(6)
IC
c=D,i,j,t
is the dollar ratio in industry j and is adjusted for each Japanese exporter. Then,
12
Figure 2: Strategic complementarity variables
Note: This figure represents the subset of transaction-level data in the data and shows how the
calculation of strategic complementarity variables is structured.
we calculate each firm’s weighted average of these industry indices.
γ
i,t
=
X
j
p
i,t
(j)IC
c=D,i,j,t
(7)
where p
i,t
(j) is the share of firm i’s export in HS 4-digit industry j in year t. This index
reflects how much dollar invoice is used by the competitors in the industries with which firm i
is associated.
Figure 2 shows how the strategic complementarity indices are calculated. In this figure,
all transactions by all exporters are shown. There are three export transactions to the UK
and Germany each. The product categories of these transactions are either HS8701 or HS8705
at the HS 4-digit industry. Exchange rates are set so that the values of all transactions are
equivalent in the common currency. The strategic complementarity index at the country level
is straightforward as in equation (5). Two out of three transactions to the UK are invoiced
in US dollars, so γ
UK,t
= 0.66. Similarly, we can calculate the US dollar invoicing ratio in
Germany; γ
DE,t
= 0.33. The calculation of the strategic complementarity index reflecting
industry dimension involves two steps. First, the US dollar invoicing ratios are calculated for
each industry as in equation (6). Only one out of four transactions in HS8701 industry is
13
invoiced in US dollars; therefore, IC
USD,HS8701,t
= 0.25. Similarly, the US dollar invoicing
ratio for HS8705 is calculated as IC
USD,HS8705,t
= 1.00. Second, these indices are used to
calculate the industry-weighted average for each exporter, as in Equation (7). If firm A exports
80 percent to the HS8701 industry and 20 percent to the HS8705 industry, the industry-wise
strategic complementarity index for firm A is γ
A,t
= 0.40.
10
2.3.2 Currency Matching Index
Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) construct the Belgian firm’s import intensity as the
ratio of total imports from outside the eurozone to total variable costs. They use this variable
as a proxy for the firm’s marginal cost sensitivity to the exchange rate. The underlying implicit
assumption is that these imports are not invoiced in euros.
11
If, as an extreme example, all
imports from non-Euro countries are invoiced in euros, the Belgian firms are unaffected by a
change in the exchange rate, at least from the importing side.
Theoretical models of exchange rate pass-through and currency invoicing explicitly consid-
ered the imported inputs in the international finance literature.
12
Chung (2016) is one of the
first empirical studies that highlighted the link between imported inputs and exporters’ deci-
sions on invoicing currency. Chung (2016) introduced the ratio of imported inputs invoiced in
the exporter’s currency to its total imported inputs at the UK firm level to consider the role of
exporter’s operational hedging behavior.
13
Our approach to constructing an import intensity variable is to consider the invoicing cur-
rency choice in imports, similar to (Crowley, Han, and Son 2021). The new contribution of
this study is to introduce three indices that are complementary to each other. The first is a
straightforward extension of the currency choice variable to the import side. The dollar used
on the import side is matched with the export side at the firm-country level. Note that this
variable has two dimensions, in firms and destinations, whereas the import intensity index in
Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) varies only over firms.
14
The currency matching variable
10
γ
A,t
= 0.8 IC
USD,HS8701,t
+ 0.2 IC
USD,HS8705,t
= 0.40
11
Therefore, Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) further breaks the import intensity index into euro-invoiced
import intensity and non-euro-invoiced import intensity for alternative specifications.
12
The role of imported inputs in exporting firms has also been well examined in the international trade literature.
Imported inputs can be used to measure the degree of participation in global value chains as surveyed in Johnson
(2018). Imported inputs can be a source of growth engine for multinational firms (Halpern, Koren, and Szeidl
2015).
13
Operational hedge is also found essential even in domestic transactions in the dollarization economy of Uruguay
(Licandro and Mello 2019). On the other hand, Lyonnet, Martin, and Mejean (2022) found that large EU firms
are more willing to use non-euro invoicing if financial hedging tools are available.
14
In fact, the import intensity index in Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) is also time-invariant, whereas our
14
is formulated as the following with an asterisk indicating the importing side:
ϕ
i,k,t
= IC
c=D,i,k,t
=
P
j,c=D
val
(c, i, j, k, t)
P
c,j
val
(c, i, j, k, t)
(8)
Figure 1 shows that exporter A imports from the UK but not from Germany. In this case, we
can calculate ϕ
A,UK,t
= 0.50, but not for Germany.
In regression models in the following section, We implicitly assume that exporters make an
invoicing currency choice, given the invoicing currency of their imports. However, a priori, there
is no consensus on the causality direction, and we face a simultaneity problem. To address this
endogeneity issue, we introduce the second and the third ratios that are the import side version
of equations (5) and (7).
γ
k,t
= IC
c=D,k,t
=
P
c=D,i,j
val
(c, i, j, k, t)
P
i,j
val
(c, i, j, k, t)
(9)
γ
i,t
=
X
j
p
i,t
(j)IC
c=D,j,t
(10)
These two indices are the US dollar invoicing ratios of the competitors’ imports, therefore not
directly linked to firm i’s decision on invoicing currency choice of its exports. We use them as
instrumental variables when we include the import intensity index, i.e., equation (8).
2.3.3 Control variables
The variables of interest in this study are two strategic complementarity variables and the
currency-matching variable we discussed in the previous subsections. In this subsection, we
describe other control variables that capture the other effects on currency choice. We introduce
firm size and market share variables to control individual firm characteristics. Devereux, Dong,
and Tomlin (2017) found that market shares of both exporters and importers matter for exchange
rate pass-through.
The firm size variable is the natural log of the firm i’s total export to destination k:
lnSize
i,k,t
= ln
P
c,j
val(c, i, j, k, t). As the robustness check in section 4.3, we use alterna-
tive definitions for firm size: total export to all destinations, the sum of export to and import
from country k, and the sum of export to and import from all countries. The first of these
alternatives corresponds to the firm size used in Crowley, Han, and Son (2021).
Market share variable is the value-weighted average of market shares at HS 4-digit indus-
tries: MShare
i,t
=
P
j
w
j
(
P
c,k
val(c, i, j, k, t)/
P
c,i,k
val(c, i, j, k, t)). For each 4-digit industry
indices change by year.
15
(across all destination countries) in which firm i exports, the market share is calculated. Then,
these market shares are taken average with firm i’s export share at HS 4-digit industries,w
j
,
as weights.
15
In robustness section 4.3, we also use three alternative definitions for market
share. Two alternatives use HS 2-digit and HS 6-digit levels instead of HS 4-digit level. The
last definition uses the market share in the destination country.
Fixed effects can potentially be constructed at the level of firms, destination countries, indus-
tries, and years. We avoided using firm-fixed effects because the firm-year-varying market share
variable, MShare
i,t
, already controls this dimension. Similarly, we do not use destination-fixed
effects because the strategic complementarity variable, γ
k,t
, captures destination characteristics.
Industry-fixed effects are not appropriate because the observation unit in this study aggregates
over industries. Therefore, we only include year-fixed effects to control for time-varying effects
on a firm’s currency choice.
3 Empirical Model of Invoicing Currency Choice
The data records all export and import declarations individually.
16
Therefore, even within
a year, the same product is exported multiple times to the same destination market by the
same exporter.
17
Instead of analyzing exports at each declaration, we pooled exports by the
exporter and destination market each year. The advantage of pooling products at this level is
that we can measure the likelihood of choosing a specific invoicing currency for an exporter in
a particular destination market. Therefore, the choice of invoicing currency is aggregated at
the pair of exporter and destination market as the dollar ratio, ϕ
i,k,t
with subscripts denoting
exporter i, destination country k, and year t, see equation (4). The choice of invoicing currency
is also constructed for imports as ϕ
i,k,t
, see equation (8).
3.1 Invoicing Currency Choice and Strategic Complementarities
The first base model only includes firm size and strategic complementarity variables. The
dependent variable is the ratio of the values invoiced in the US dollar in total export values by
firm-destination pair, ϕ
i,k,t
.
15
Due to these definitions in the base model, two firm characteristics variables measure different aspects of
exporters. lnSize
i,k,t
measures the total exports to destination market k whereas M Share
i,t
is a weighted
measure of total exports to all destination countries. A priori, these variables should be free of multicollinearity
problem.
16
Low-value cargoes under the simplified customs clearance are excluded from the database.
17
For example, in the first six months of 2014, for about four percent of the sample, different invoice currencies
are chosen for the same HS 9-digit export to the same destination country by the same exporter within a month.
16
ϕ
i,k,t
= α + β
0
lnSize
i,k,t
+ β
1
MShare
i,t
+ β
2
γ
k,t
+ β
3
γ
i,t
+ ϵ
i,k,t
(11)
The firm’s size, lnSize
i,k,t
, is the natural log of the firm i’s total export to destination k,
the market share of the firm, MShare
i,t
, is the value-weighted average of market shares at HS
4-digit industries, and the two complementarity indices are the likelihood of dollar invoice in the
destination market, γ
k,t
, and the likelihood of dollar invoice in associated industries, γ
i,t
. The
definitions of complementarity indices are shown in equations (5) and (7).
The dependent variable is fractional, 0 ϕ
i,k,t
1, with non-zero mass at the two extreme
values. The predicted values from an OLS regression cannot be guaranteed to lie between 0 and
1. Therefore, similar to binary dependent variable models, we assume that
E(ϕ
i,k,t
| X
i,k,t
) = G(X
i,k,t
B) (12)
where X
i,k,t
denotes the vector of explanatory variables, B is the vector of parameters, and
G(·) is the standard normal cumulative density function, satisfying 0 < G(z) < 1 for all z .
In particular, we apply the fractional response regression proposed by Papke and Wooldridge
(1996).
The expected signs of two strategic complementary indices, γ
k,t
and γ
i,t
, are positive. The
expected sign of firm size is less evident in the previous studies. Firm size positively correlates
with non-euro invoicing for the Belgian exporters in Table 2 of Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings
(2022). This non-euro currency includes US dollars, destination currency, and other currencies.
Table 4 of Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) further shows that firm size negatively correlates
with US dollar invoicing. On the other hand, the dollar invoicing by UK exporters is positively
correlated with firm size in Crowley, Han, and Son (2021). These analyses are based on the
extra-EU exports for Belgian and UK firms. A significant number of observations are excluded
from the original sample. On the market share, the expected sign is ever less clear in previous
empirical evidence. The market share is estimated to positively affect non-euro invoicing for
the Belgian firms in Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022); however, the statistical significance of
market share disappears when the firm size variable is introduced in the regression model.
3.2 Currency Matching
Our approach slightly differs from Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) and Crowley, Han,
and Son (2021) in implementing the import side variables. Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022)
use firm-specific import intensity, i.e., the ratio of total extra-EU import to total variable costs.
17
This import intensity is also constructed for non-euro invoicing and dollar invoicing. Construct-
ing this variable requires matching trade data and accounting data by identifying each firm
in both data sets and is much more data-demanding. However, their index is the average of
the entire sample period and is time-invariant and destination-invariant. Crowley, Han, and
Son (2021), on the other hand, rely solely on the trade data set; therefore, their construction
of import-side indices is similar to ours. Their index is the share of the firm’s dollar invoiced
imports in its total imports. This variable is time-varying but not destination-varying. Our
index, ϕ
i,k,t
, in equation (8) is both destination-varying and time-varying. This new index has
an important implication when we focus on two-way exporters. More precisely, we define a
firm-destination pair as two-way if we observe export and import data in the same year. Note
that the definition of two-way exporter applies to the pair of firm-destination so that a firm can
be two-way for one market and not for another. Our regression model for evaluating a firm’s
incentive to match the invoice currencies of exports and imports is the following.
ϕ
i,k,t
= α + β
0
lnSize
i,k,t
+ β
1
MShare
i,t
+ β
2
γ
k,t
+ β
3
γ
i,t
+ β
4
ϕ
i,k,t
+ ϵ
i,k,t
(13)
The analysis with the import-side variables has one drawback: The invoicing currency choice
on exports and imports are simultaneous decisions. Also, from the perspective of the importing
side, a similar relationship between the firm’s import invoicing and competitors’ import invoicing
should hold.
18
Alternatively, using γ
k,t
and γ
i,t
as instruments, we also estimate equation (13)
by instrumental variable (IV) fractional probit.
3.2.1 Two-way Exporters
For broad two-way exporters, imports from other countries should affect the invoicing cur-
rency choice of exports. For example, a Japanese exporter exporting to China and importing
from Germany and the US would not be a narrow two-way because it does not import from
the country of export destination, China. The observation of this exporter’s export to China
would be dropped from the above regression when we restrict the sample to narrow two-way
exporters. However, up to the degree of US dollar invoicing for its imports from Germany and
the US, the exporter considers the use of US dollar invoicing for its exports to China. This
concept is adopted by Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022), and we define it as broad two-way.
We also estimate equation (13) with the sample of broad two-way exporters, and import side
index, ϕ
i,k,t
, is replaced by ϕ
i,t
, the US dollar ratio for import invoicing at the firm level.
18
We estimated an import-side regression analogous to equation (11) and obtained similar results.
18
Table 2: Invoice currency by exporter type (2014-2020)
all exporters broad two-way narrow two-way
(no. of pairs) 3,043,901 1,949,043 921,088
(no. of firms) 747,353 187,354 131,923
(trillion yen) 551.9 538.0 495.1
USD 0.51 0.52 0.53
- excl. US (0.35) (0.35) (0.35)
JPY 0.36 0.35 0.34
EUR 0.06 0.07 0.07
LC 0.27 0.28 0.30
- excl. US (0.11) (0.11) (0.11)
Note: Broad two-way exporters are those exporters that also import in the same year. Narrow
two-way exporters are defined over the exporter and destination country pairs that also import
from the same destination country in the same year. These definitions are applied to the
observations of each year. The first row represents the number of exporter-country pairs whereas
the second row indicates the number of distinct exporters. The ratio in parenthesis excludes the
US from the calculation. LC is local currency invoicing.
19
Table 2 summarizes the use of invoicing currencies by exporter types. The first column
represents all exporters, corresponding to the first row of Table 1. In the second and third
columns, the summary statistics for invoicing currencies for broadly defined and narrowly defined
two-way exporters are shown, respectively. There are some salient features. Based on our
definitions of firm-destination, the number of observations for seven years decreases to about
two-thirds in the broad two-way sample and one-third in the narrow two-way sample. The
corresponding firms are 747, 187, and 131 thousand firms for all, broad two-way, and narrow
two-way exporters, respectively. This implies that about 75 percent of Japanese exporters do
not import at all and that about 70 percent of firms engaging in both exports and imports,
in fact, use (at least) one particular country for both exports and imports. More importantly,
these two-way exporters conduct a large share of exports (in terms of values): 97 percent by
broad two-way and 90 percent by narrow two-way exporters. On the other hand, only a little
difference exists in the use of invoicing currencies among exporter types.
4 The Empirical Results
For the empirical investigation on the choice of invoicing currency in Japanese exports, we
use the general export and import declarations submitted to Japan Customs, the Ministry of
Finance, between 2014 and 2020. As described in section 3, we use the US dollar invoicing
ratio at the firm-country level as the dependent variable in the base model and estimate the
regression models (11) and (13). The appendix table A.1 provides the statistical summary of
variables used in the regression models.
4.1 US dollar Invoicing, Dominant Currency
Table 3 shows regression (11) estimation results by all exporters, broadly defined two-way
exporters, and narrowly defined two-way exporters for the panel between 2014 and 2020. The
models are estimated by fractional probit, and the table shows the marginal effects of covari-
ates. The sign of γ
k
, the US dollar invoicing ratio in the destination k, is positive and it captures
strategic complementarity among exporting firms. By comparing the magnitude, it is interesting
to find that two-way exporters in columns (2) and (3) are more inclined to follow the currency
choice of competitors than the entire sample of exporters in column (1). More specifically, the
effect of strategic complementarity in the destination country dimension is more substantial for
narrowly defined two-way exporters. Exporters that export to and import from the same country
pay more attention to the competitors’ choice of invoicing currency in that market. Similarly,
20
the competitors’ currency choice in the corresponding industries, γ
i
, the weighted average of the
dollar ratio with the firm’s exporting value by industries as weights, are positive and statistically
significant. An exporter is likely to increase the use of US dollars as invoicing currency if the dol-
lar is predominantly used in a destination country and/or in the firm’s associated industries. On
the other hand, big exporters, measured as large total exports to the corresponding destination
countries or higher market share, lower the use of the US dollar. At this moment, it should not
be confused with the notion implicitly indicating that they prefer the Japanese yen as invoicing
currency. Local currency or other vehicle currency is also possible besides the Japanese yen as
an alternative invoicing currency. We will come back to this issue in subsection 4.2.
Table 3: US dollar invoicing and strategical complementarity, 2014-2020
(1) USD (2) USD (3) USD
Fractional Probit Fractional Probit Fractional Probit
lnSize
i,k,t
-0.0061*** -0.0084*** -0.0096***
(0.0012) (0.0006) (0.0009)
MShare
i,t
(HS4) -0.9715*** -1.0216*** -0.7431***
(0.1349) (0.1380) (0.1876)
γ
k,t
(SC Country USD) 0.2573*** 0.3442*** 0.4528***
(0.0213) (0.0132) (0.0113)
γ
i,t
(SC HS4 USD) 1.1298*** 1.1140*** 1.0982***
(0.0187) (0.0116) (0.0147)
year fixed effects yes yes yes
N. of observations 3,043,872 1,949,018 921,088
Psuedo R
2
0.35 0.27 0.29
firm-type all broad two-way narrow two-way
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. The coefficients and
standard errors estimated by a fractional probit model are shown for the marginal effect. The
standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of destination countries and years.
broad two-way exporters are those exporters that also import in the same year. Narrow two-
way exporters are defined over the exporter and destination country pairs that also import from
the same destination country in the same year. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
21
Table 4: US dollar invoicing with import side invoicing currency, 2014-2020
(1) USD (2) USD (3) USD (4) USD (5) USD w/o US
Fractional Probit IV Frac. Probit Fractional Probit Frational Probit IV Frac. Probit
lnSize
i,k,t
-0.0074*** -0.0073*** -0.0082*** -0.0077*** -0.0082***
(0.0008) (0.0007) (0.0008) (0.0006) (0.0004)
MShare
i,t
(HS4) -0.7316*** -0.7317*** -0.6870*** -0.9607*** -0.6207***
(0.1709) (0.1708) (0.1724) (0.1302) (0.1448)
γ
k,t
(SC Country USD) 0.2676*** 0.2651*** 0.4248*** 0.3359*** 0.1857***
(0.0127) (0.0168) (0.0115) (0.0131) (0.0119)
γ
i,t
(SC HS4 USD) 0.9664*** 0.9647*** 1.0002*** 1.0517*** 0.8893***
(0.0164) (0.0211) (0.0187) (0.0129) (0.0207)
ϕ
i,k,t
(USDRatio im) 0.1925*** 0.1954*** 0.2136***
(0.0056) (0.0135) (0.0132)
ϕ
i,t
(byfirm USDRatio im) 0.1203*** 0.0827***
(0.0079) (0.0038)
year fixed effects yes yes yes yes yes
N. of observations 921,088 921,088 921,088 1,949,018 809,308
Pseudo R
2
0.33 0.30 0.27
firm-type narrow two narrow two narrow two broad two narrow two
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. The coefficients and standard errors are shown for
marginal effect. The standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of destination countries and years. broad
two-way exporters are those exporters that also import in the same year. Narrow two-way exporters are defined over the exporter
and destination country pairs that also import from the same destination country in the same year. ***, **, * represent one,
five, and ten percent significance level.
22
Table 3 shows that the results of two-way exporters are qualitatively the same as those
of all exporters, including one-way exporters. Table 4 presents the estimated results with the
dollar invoicing ratio on the import side. This variable is not introduced here to relate the
exporter’s choice of invoicing currency with the competitors’ currency strategies as in Table
3. This analysis examines a possible incentive for firms to match currencies on the asset, i.e.,
receipt from exports, and debit side, i.e., payment for imports, of the balance sheet, and we call
it a currency-matching incentive. If the cash inflow from exports and cash outflow for imports
are in the same currency, the exchange rate risk hinges only on the net balance.
The first column in Table 4 includes the US dollar ratio of imports, ϕ
i,k,t
, as an additional
explanatory variable for narrow two-way exporters. The US dollar ratio for imports is similarly
constructed as the US dollar ratio, the dependent variable, for the same firm and the same
country. The US dollar ratio for imports is statistically significant. The estimated coefficient
indicates that a ten-percentage point increase in the US dollar ratio for imports in the same
industry and country induces a 1.93 percentage point increase in the dollar use in exports.
The endogeneity issue may exist for the import-side variable.
19
In the second column, we re-
estimated the model as in column (1) but used γ
k
and γ
i
as instruments in the instrumental
variable fractional probit model. The estimated results are similar to those in column (1).
In columns (3) and (4), we replace the US dollar ratio for firm-destination import,ϕ
i,k,t
, with
the US dollar ratio for firm import, ϕ
i,t
, which is not destination-specific. Firm size, market
share, and strategic complementarity variables are only marginally affected, and their estimates
remain statistically significant at the one percent level. In column (3), the magnitude of the
currency-matching coefficient at the firm level is smaller than the currency-matching variable
at the firm-destination level in column (1). This result implies that a typical firm pays more
attention to balancing the currency flows on a country basis than managing every currency
flow over the firm’s entire accounting. Column (4) shows that the US dollar invoicing ratio
for broad two-way exporters is less sensitive to the firms’ US dollar invoicing for imports. To
summarize, narrow two-way exporters are more inclined than broad two-way exporters to match
the invoicing currency of exports to the overall invoicing currency of imports, and they pay more
attention to a country basis for currency matching.
19
We estimated the corresponding estimation model as of equation (11) for imports and found that similar
results hold for the import side.
23
4.2 Vehicle Currency, Producer Currency, and Local Currency Invoicing
We found supporting evidence for strategic complementarities and currency matching for
the US dollar invoicing in the preceding section. In this section, we investigate other currency
invoicing practices and show that the central message holds.
Table 5: Producer currency pricing and local currency pricing
(1) JPY (2) JPY (3) LC (4) LC
Frac. Probit IV Frac. Probit Frac. Probit IV Frac. Probit
lnSize
i,k,t
0.0046*** 0.0017*** 0.0024*** 0.0033***
(0.0006) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005)
MShare
i,t
(HS4) 0.1242 0.2521*** -0.9528*** -0.7118***
(0.0996) (0.0904) (0.1116) (0.1042)
γ
k,t
(SC Country JPY(LC)) 0.3811*** 0.2806*** 0.3797*** 0.2560***
(0.0258) (0.0193) (0.0069) (0.0267)
γ
i,t
(SC HS4 JPY(LC)) 1.0501*** 0.9623*** 0.7737*** 0.7137***
(0.0063) (0.0076) (0.0311) (0.0379)
ϕ
i,k,t
(JPY(LC)Ratio im) 0.2168*** 0.1239***
(0.0067) (0.0299)
year fixed effects yes yes yes yes
N. of observations 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088
Psuedo R
2
0.30 0.41
firm-type narrow two narrow two narrow two narrow two
Note: The dependent variable is the Japanese yen invoicing ratio in columns (1) and (2) and the local
currency invoicing ratio in columns (3) and (4). The coefficients and standard errors are shown for the
marginal effect. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of destination countries
and years. Narrow two-way exporters are defined over the pairs of exporter and destination country that
also import from the same destination country in the same year. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten
percent significance level.
4.2.1 Vehicle Currency: The US dollar Invoicing to non-US markets
Including the US as a destination country in the estimation for the US dollar invoicing may
bias the estimates. The US dollar invoicing to non-US destination countries is a form of vehicle
currency invoicing. This pervasive use of the US dollar in trade with countries other than the
U.S. supports the fundamental idea of the dominant currency paradigm in the literature, for
24
example, in Gopinath, Boz, Casas, D´ıez, Gourinchas, and Plagborg-Møller (2020). Therefore,
we re-estimate the regressions, excluding the US as the destination country.
Column (5) in Table 4 presents the estimated equation (13) results by excluding the US from
destination countries. This robustness check confirms that the qualitative results remain intact
even when the US is excluded from the sample, reducing approximately 12 percent of firm-
destination observations. The impact of strategic complementarity in the destination market is
lower, consistent with our expectations. In the competing industries, it is also lower but less
substantially. The effect of currency matching is slightly more significant. To summarize, the
preceding results of US dollar invoicing do not hinge on the presence of the US in the sample,
but vehicle currency use or the dominant currency role of the US dollar is supported in samples
other than the United States.
4.2.2 Producer Currency Invoicing: Japanese yen Invoicing
Examining whether the strategic complementarity and currency matching mechanisms also
work on other invoicing currencies is important. In our data set, we turn to the producer
currency invoicing, i.e., the Japanese yen invoicing. The dependent variable is the Japanese yen
invoicing ratio at the firm-destination pairs. The explanatory variables are similarly constructed
for the Japanese yen invoicing. The first two columns of Table 5 present the estimation results
for the Japanese yen invoicing.
There is one noteworthy difference between the US dollar and Japanese yen invoicing. The
estimated signs of size and market share variables are opposite of the US dollar invoicing model.
Therefore, it implies that a larger-sized Japanese exporter is more likely to choose the Japanese
yen over the US dollar. The market share, representing the competitiveness of exporters, allows
the Japanese exporters to use their own currency. This is consistent with the results found in Ito,
Koibuchi, Sato, and Shimizu (2012) that firms that responded positively to the questionnaire
about their international competitiveness are more likely to choose Japanese yen invoicing.
Besides these differences, the qualitative results are the same for the US dollar and Japanese
yen invoicing.
4.2.3 Local Currency Invoicing
Columns (3) and (4) in Table 5 show the results for local currency pricing. The estimated
sign of the size variable is positive and opposite of the US dollar invoicing model. In contrast,
the market share variable shows the same sign as in the US dollar invoicing model. The size
variable is consistent with the result in Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022) with the subsample
25
analysis of dollar-invoicing against local-currency invoicing for non-US and non-USD-pegging
countries. The estimated coefficients of the firm’s employees are negative and statistically sig-
nificant, implying a larger firm is more likely to invoice in local currencies.
20
Regarding strategic complementarity and currency matching variables, the estimates are a
little smaller than the US dollar invoicing, but they are all statistically significant at the one
percent level. Therefore, regardless of the dominant vehicle, producer, or local currency, strategic
complementarity and currency-matching mechanisms for choosing the invoicing currency work
for Japanese exporters.
4.3 Robustness: Alternative size, market share, and strategic complemen-
tarity
Some of the control variables used so far can be defined differently. In this section, we re-
estimate the models by replacing the original variables with alternatives. The estimated results
of the base model, column (2) in Table 4, are reproduced in column (1) of Table 6. First, we
evaluate the robustness of firm size. The size of firms is measured initially as export values by a
firm to a destination country. Alternatively, export values by a firm to all destination countries
in column (2), the sum of export and import values by a firm to a destination country in column
(3), and the sum of all exports and imports by a firm in column (4) are used in the model. The
estimated coefficients of alternative size variables are consistent with the estimate in column
(1); they are negative and statistically significant at the one percent level, and the estimates are
smaller.
Second, we check the robustness of market share. Alternative variables are defined as the
firm’s export value to total export values by all Japanese exporters in a destination country
in column (5), and HS 2-digit and 6-digit instead of HS 4-digit level are used in columns (6)
and (7), respectively. All the estimates are consistent with the result of the base model. The
magnitude varies among alternatives due to decreased measure of market share as industry
classification becomes broader. Third, the strategic complementarity variable is replaced with
those with different levels of industry classification in columns (8) and (9). The estimated results
are almost identical to the result of the original variable. In summary, the results in previous
sections are robust to alternative definitions of explanatory variables.
20
See, Table IV in Amiti, Itskhoki, and Konings (2022).
26
Table 6: Alternative definitions of size, market share, and strategic complementarity
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
alternative variable size (e, all) size (e&i) size (e&i, all) ms (dest.) ms (HS2) ms (HS6) sc (HS2) sc (HS6)
size -0.0073*** -0.0064*** -0.0044*** -0.0035*** -0.0075*** -0.0072*** -0.0074*** -0.0075*** -0.0074***
(0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0008) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0007)
ms -0.7317*** -0.5842*** -0.9623*** -0.8997*** -0.0847* -2.6846*** -0.2910*** -0.3568*** -0.7524***
(0.1708) (0.1678) (0.1736) (0.1784) (0.0515) (0.2497) (0.0820) (0.1188) (0.1733)
γ
k,t
(SC country) 0.2651*** 0.2469*** 0.2529*** 0.2462*** 0.2661*** 0.2645*** 0.2654*** 0.2482*** 0.2585***
(0.0168) (0.0189) (0.0180) (0.0194) (0.0168) (0.0168) (0.0168) (0.0172) (0.0169)
γ
i,t
(SC industry) 0.9647*** 0.9835*** 0.9552*** 0.9647*** 0.9624*** 0.9661*** 0.9637*** 1.0000*** 0.9404***
(0.0211) (0.0202) (0.0208) (0.0198) (0.0213) (0.0213) (0.0211) (0.0197) (0.0214)
ϕ
i,k,t
(USDRatio im) 0.1954*** 0.1890*** 0.2096*** 0.2044*** 0.1952*** 0.1953*** 0.1955*** 0.2053*** 0.2067***
(0.0135) (0.0143) (0.0135) (0.0136) (0.0135) (0.0136) (0.0135) (0.0142) (0.0135)
year fixed effects yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
NOB 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088 921,088
N. of firms 131,923 131,923 131,923 131,923 131,923 131,923 131,923 131,923 131,923
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are estimated by instrumental variable fractional
probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country
and years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent significance level. The first column
is the base model and corresponds to column (2) in Table 4. From columns (2) to (4), alternative definitions for firm size are used; (e,
all) export values to all destination countries, (e&i) the sum of export and import values to the same destination country, and (e&i, all)
the sum of export and import values to and from all countries. From column (5) to (7), alternative definitions for market share are used:
(dest.) market share of firms’ export values in the destination country, (HS2) market share of firms’ export in the corresponding HS 2-digit
categories, and (HS6) market share of firms’ export in the corresponding HS 2-digit categories. In the last two columns, alternative strategies
complementarity variables are constructed at the level of HS 2-digit and 6-digit industries.
27
5 New Exporters
As discussed in section 3.2, one way to address the simultaneous problem of choosing in-
voicing currency in exports and imports is to use instrumental variable estimation or two-stage
least squares. These are statistical methods to obtain consistent estimators. We applied the
instrumental variable fractional probit estimation method in the previous section. Alternatively,
we propose to focus on the subsample of firms that have yet to record international trade trans-
actions in the last year. Therefore, the invoicing currency decision we analyze here is the first
decision on new exporters’ invoicing currency. In this way, we can at least exclude the pre-
determined decision of the previous year on imports from affecting the current year’s decisions
on exports. For these subgroups of firms, we re-estimate the regression model in equation (13).
In the following years, firms may reevaluate the first decision and may alter the invoicing cur-
rency. This analysis implies that a currency-matching mechanism gradually forms as a firm
accumulates years of trade experience
21
The first column in Table 7 shows the estimation results of equation (13) for 2015, including
all narrow two-way exporters. Even for this particular single year, we confirm that strategic
complementarity variables and currency matching variables, at the firm-destination level, sig-
nificantly impact the invoice decision of the Japanese exporters. Size effect and market share
effects are also consistent with the panel results.
21
Crowley, Han, and Son (2021) also examine the dynamic effects of dollar invoicing for UK firms. However,
their focus is on the impact of the experience of using the dollar in any markets on choosing the dollar invoice in
a new market.
28
Table 7: New Exporters in 2015
previous year no trade no trade
lnSize
i,k
-0.0099*** -0.0199*** -0.0112*** -0.0207***
(0.0012) (0.0015) (0.0014) (0.0016)
MShare
i
(HS4) -1.0604*** 0.0615 -0.9712*** 0.0473
(0.2738) (0.5655) (0.2896) (0.6070)
γ
k
(SC Country USD) 0.2579*** 0.2009*** 0.4521*** 0.2737***
(0.0497) (0.0305) (0.0305) (0.0270)
γ
i
(SC HS4 USD) 0.8995*** 1.4673*** 0.9420*** 1.4688***
(0.0512) (0.1226) (0.0419) (0.1278)
ϕ
i,k
USDRatio im 0.2320*** 0.1698***
(0.0328) (0.0242)
ϕ
i
byfirm USDRatio im 0.1347*** 0.1328***
(0.0168) (0.0213)
NOB 131,417 5,343 131,417 5,343
N. of firms 49,935 4,494 49,935 4,494
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are
estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects.
Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country and
years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
29
Figure 3: The effects of currency matching on new exporters
Note: The marginal effects are estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit. The
vertical lines represent the confidence interval of two standard deviations for the impact of
currency matching on the choice of invoicing currency in firm-destination pairs. All four panels
are based on the estimated results for narrowly defined two-way exporters. For the definitions
of currency matching, the upper panels use the firm-destination invoicing currency ratio,
whereas the lower panels use the firm-level invoicing currency ratio. The left panels show the
results without restrictions on the previous year’s experience. The right panels show the
sample with no trade in the last year.
30
The second column limited the sample to only new exporters in 2015. More precisely, the
sample included only narrow two-way exporters in 2015, but these exporters did not export to
or import from any countries in 2014. Regarding the number of firm-destination observations,
compared with column (1), new exporters were about four percent of all exporters in 2015.
Regarding the number of firms, new exporters in 2015 were about ten percent of all exporters.
By replacing the currency matching variable with the firm-level measure, the third and fourth
columns show the estimation results of equation (13) for all exporters and new exporters, re-
spectively. In columns (2) and (4), the estimated coefficients remain statistically significant for
firm size and two strategic complementarity indices. On the other hand, the market share is not
statistically significant. The variable of interest in this section is currency matching variables,
ϕ
i,k,t
in column (2) and ϕ
i,t
in column (4). The noteworthy point is that the magnitude of the
estimate for the US dollar invoicing ratio substantially declined for new exporters, although still
statistically significant.
The effects of currency matching for new exporters for other years are summarized in Figure
3.
22
The figure shows the point estimate and two standard deviation bands for the currency-
matching variable. The estimates of currency matching variables at the firm-destination level
are shown in the upper panel, and those of firm-level currency matching are shown in the lower
panel. The currency matching variables are statistically significant at the one percent level when
the sample includes all two-way exporters. However, the effects of currency matching became no
longer statistically significant for 2016, 2018, and 2020 at the two standard deviations level when
the sample only included new exporters. There are some differences in the estimation results
among sample years; however, the qualitative results remain the same, namely, that currency
matching evidence is weak at best for new exporters.
We have shown in the previous section that exporters choose their invoicing currency based
on strategic complementarity and currency matching. This mechanism holds for the US dollar
invoicing as well as producer currency invoicing, i.e., the Japanese yen invoicing in this study and
local currency pricing. New exporters also choose their invoicing currency based on imitating
their competitors’ decisions in the destination country and the competing industries. However,
currency matching is not the primary force for new exporters. How can this result of new
exporters reconcile with the result of experienced exporters who consider currency matching as
an essential factor for invoicing currency decisions?
One interpretation of these results is the following. A new exporter enters a destination
market and observes what other competitors are doing, including invoicing currency choices.
23
22
The estimates of all variables are shown in the appendix tables.
23
Exporters do not directly observe their competitors’ invoicing currency, but they face business practices and
31
An exporter may import intermediate inputs from the same country but accept the import
contract with the specified invoicing currency. As an exporter continues these transactions for
several years, currency matching becomes an important issue. It may renegotiate with the
incumbent trade partner about altering the invoicing currency or switch to a new partner that
accepts the invoicing currency of the exporter’s choice.
6 Discussions and Conclusions
We contribute to the literature by providing evidence of the Japanese exporters, not only
as another example but as a country not using the US dollar or euro as its own currency nor
being involved in dominant currency regimes, such as the UK or Canada. No study using this
new database has appeared because the data set became available only in 2022. This is not to
claim that no previous studies examined the invoicing currency choice of Japanese exporters.
Ito, Koibuchi, Sato, and Shimizu (2012) and Ito, Koibuchi, Sato, and Shimizu (2018) conducted
multi-year questionnaire surveys to the listed multinational corporations in Japan and concluded
that foreign exchange risk management is the driving force for the dominating share of US dollar
invoicing for Japanese exporters, especially to the US and China as destination markets. They
also found that intra-firm trade occupies a lion’s share of international trade for multinational
firms, and the parent firms headquartered in Japan tend to use the currency of subsidiaries’
locations. This study complements the earlier findings that the competitors’ currency choice
and matching with the invoicing currency of imports are also important factors for invoicing
currency choice for Japanese exporters.
In addition, we focus our attention on two-way exporters and provide narrow and broad
definitions. A broader definition of two-way exporters includes a firm that imports from country
A and exports to country B. As long as a firm experiences exports and imports in the same year
regardless of which countries, by a broader definition, it is labeled as a broad two-way exporter.
Our definition of narrow two-way exporter excludes those firms.
24
This narrow definition has
important implications. Firms surviving this screening may be more active in intra-firm trade,
especially if located in the middle of a vertical production network. Another plausible scenario
is that the sample merely captures the fact that narrow two-way exporters are trading with big
countries with a prominent share in both producing and consuming in the world, such as the
standards for pricing when they enter the market. Their trade counterparts will likely request new exporters to
follow the current business practices.
24
More precisely, our definition does not mechanically exclude a firm that imports from A and exports to B. It
is labeled a two-way exporter as long as it also imports from B.
32
United States. We confirmed that the latter is not a decisive factor, as shown by the analysis
of excluding the US from the sample in section 4.2.1. More importantly, we find evidence of
matching with invoicing currency of imports, ϕ
i,k
, even when we restrict to this narrow definition
of two-way exporters, which should make detecting the effect more difficult.
For future research, this study suggests an essential extension to the exchange rate pass-
through (ERPT) literature for Japanese firms. Gopinath, Itskhoki, and Rigobon (2010) in-
vestigate how currency choice is endogenously chosen and affects the observed exchange rate
pass-through. The US import price survey data collected by the BLS are examined for the
invoicing currency for their study. The ERPT regressions are estimated for US imports, distin-
guishing those invoiced in the US dollar and those invoiced in non-US dollar currencies. They
find that ERPT for goods invoiced in US dollars is about 25 percent, and ERPT for non-US dol-
lars is about 95 percent. The Devereux, Dong, and Tomlin (2017) study utilizes transaction-level
data on Canadian import. Most Canadian imports are invoiced in US dollars because Canada
shares its border with the US and has a solid economic tie to the US. Using the transaction-level
customs data for Canadian imports in monthly frequency between 2002 and 2008, Devereux,
Dong, and Tomlin (2017) found the invoicing currency matters for the observed exchange rate
pass-through. Using Japan Customs data, examining the effect of invoicing currency on the
ERPT is left for our future work.
33
References
Amiti, M., O. Itskhoki, and J. Konings (2019): “International Shocks, Variable Markups,
and Domestic Prices,” The Review of Economic Studies, 86(6), 2356–2402.
(2022): “Dominant Currencies: How Firms Choose Currency Invoicing and Why it
Matters,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 137(3), 1435–1493.
Boz, E., C. Casas, G. Georgiadis, G. Gopinath, H. Le Mezo, A. Mehl, and T. Nguyen
(2022): “Patterns of invoicing currency in global trade: New evidence,” Journal of Interna-
tional Economics, 136, 103604.
Chung, W. (2016): “Imported inputs and invoicing currency choice: Theory and evidence from
UK transaction data,” Journal of International Economics, 99, 237–250.
Corsetti, G., M. Crowley, and L. Han (2022): “Invoicing and the dynamics of pricing-to-
market: Evidence from UK export prices around the Brexit referendum,” Journal of Inter-
national Economics, 135, 103570.
Crowley, M., L. Han, and M. Son (2021): “Dominant currency dynamics: Evidence on
dollar-invoicing from UK exporters,” .
Devereux, M. B., W. Dong, and B. Tomlin (2017): “Importers and exporters in exchange
rate pass-through and currency invoicing,” Journal of International Economics, 105, 187–204.
Gopinath, G., E. Boz, C. Casas, F. J. D
´
ıez, P.-O. Gourinchas, and M. Plagborg-
Møller (2020): “Dominant Currency Paradigm,” American Economic Review, 110(3), 677–
719.
Gopinath, G., O. Itskhoki, and R. Rigobon (2010): “Currency Choice and Exchange Rate
Pass-Through,” American Economic Review, 100(1), 304–336.
Gopinath, G., and R. Rigobon (2008): “Sticky Borders,” The Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics, 123(2), 531–575.
Halpern, L., M. Koren, and A. Szeidl (2015): “Imported Inputs and Productivity,” Amer-
ican Economic Review, 105(12), 3660–3703.
Ito, T., S. Koibuchi, K. Sato, and J. Shimizu (2012): “THE CHOICE OF AN INVOIC-
ING CURRENCY BY GLOBALLY OPERATING FIRMS: A FIRM-LEVEL ANALYSIS OF
JAPANESE EXPORTERS,” International Journal of Finance & Economics, 17(4), 305–320.
34
(2018): Managing Currency Risk: How Japanese Firms Choose Invoicing Currency.
Edward Elgar.
Johnson, R. C. (2018): “Measuring Global Value Chains,” Annual Review of Economics,
10(1), 207–236.
Licandro, G., and M. Mello (2019): “Foreign currency invoicing of domestic transactions
as a hedging strategy: evidence for Uruguay,” Journal of Applied Economics, 22(1), 622–634.
Lyonnet, V., J. Martin, and I. Mejean (2022): “Invoicing Currency and Financial Hedg-
ing,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 54(8), 2411–2444.
Papke, L. E., and J. M. Wooldridge (1996): “Econometric methods for fractional response
variables with an application to 401(k) plan participation rates,” Journal of Applied Econo-
metrics, 11(6), 619–632.
35
A Appendix:
The list of 21 Asian countries included in Table 1
Bangladesh, Bhutan, Brunei, Cambodia, India, Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Laos, Malaysia,
Maldives, Mongolia, Myanmar, Nepal, Pakistan, Philippines, Singapore, Sri Lanka, Thailand,
Timor-Leste, Viet Nam, and Taiwan.
The list of Euro area countries included in Table 1
Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Latvia,
Lithuania (from 2015), Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, and
Spain.
36
Table A.1: Statistical Summary for regression variables
all exporters broad two-way exporters narrow two-way exporters
Variable observations mean std. dev observations mean std. dev observations mean std. dev
USDRatio 3,043,901 0.2571 0.4239 1,949,043 0.3082 0.4437 921,088 0.3325 0.4448
JPYRatio 3,043,901 0.6807 0.4526 1,949,043 0.6079 0.4693 921,088 0.5645 0.4676
LCRatio 3,043,901 0.0879 0.2758 1,949,043 0.1001 0.2898 921,088 0.1508 0.3429
size (base) 3,043,901 13.4956 3.6387 1,949,043 14.2880 3.6974 921,088 14.9796 3.9483
size (e, all) 3,043,901 16.3558 4.6324 1,949,043 18.2988 3.9995 921,088 18.2667 4.2292
size (e&i) 921,088 16.9312 3.0968 921,088 16.9312 3.0968 921,088 16.9312 3.0968
size (e&i, all) 921,088 19.9535 3.3963 921,088 19.9535 3.3963 921,088 19.9535 3.3963
ms (dest.) 3,043,901 0.0005 0.0107 1,949,043 0.0008 0.0129 921,088 0.0006 0.0097
ms (HS2) 3,043,901 0.0002 0.0025 1,949,043 0.0003 0.0031 921,088 0.0004 0.0033
ms (HS4) 3,043,901 0.0006 0.0069 1,949,043 0.0009 0.0075 921,088 0.0010 0.0077
ms (HS6) 3,043,901 0.0013 0.0131 1,949,043 0.0016 0.0133 921,088 0.0018 0.0147
SC (country) 3,043,872 0.4540 0.2211 1,949,018 0.4292 0.2266 921,088 0.4587 0.2261
SC (HS4) 3,043,901 0.1076 0.1724 1,949,043 0.1369 0.1826 921,088 0.1518 0.1914
USDRatio* 18,941,417 0.4159 0.4878 1,970,981 0.4970 0.4798 921,088 0.5189 0.4712
byfirm USDRatio* 19,969,372 0.4241 0.4642 2,998,936 0.5293 0.3977 921,088 0.5371 0.3867
SC (country)* 18,941,386 0.5447 0.2599 1,970,967 0.4825 0.2793 921,088 0.5196 0.2603
SC (HS4)* 18,941,417 0.2644 0.3148 1,970,981 0.3223 0.2706 921,088 0.3225 0.2650
Note: Broad two-way exporters are those exporters that also import in the same year. Narrow two-way exporters are defined over the
exporter and destination country pairs that also import from the same destination country in the same year. These definitions are applied to
the observations of each year. The first row represents the number of exporter-country pairs whereas the second row indicates the number
of distinct exporters. The ratio in parenthesis excludes the US from the calculation. LC is local currency invoicing.
37
Table A.2: New Exporters in 2016
previous year no trade no trade
lnSize
i,k
-0.0064*** -0.0025** -0.0073*** -0.0026**
(0.0015) (0.0010) (0.0018) (0.0011)
MShare
i
(HS4) -1.4520*** 0.2470 -1.3882*** 0.3317
(0.2864) (1.1597) (0.3144) (1.2514)
γ
k
(SC Country USD) 0.2816*** 0.1270*** 0.4366*** 0.1563***
(0.0415) (0.0157) (0.0217) (0.0148)
γ
i
(SC HS4 USD) 0.9841*** 1.0130*** 1.0268*** 1.0223***
(0.0505) (0.0383) (0.0438) (0.0306)
ϕ
i,k
USDRatio im 0.1782*** 0.0518**
(0.0350) (0.0207)
ϕ
i
byfirm USDRatio im 0.0967*** 0.0393*
(0.0204) (0.0201)
NOB 130,863 4,905 130,863 4,905
N. of firms 49,404 4,247 49,404 4,247
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are
estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects.
Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country and
years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
38
Table A.3: New Exporters in 2017
previous year no trade no trade
lnSize
i,k
-0.0069*** -0.0054*** -0.0077*** -0.0055***
(0.0015) (0.0019) (0.0018) (0.0020)
MShare
i
(HS4) -0.3815 -0.0310 -0.3433 -0.0401
(0.3789) (0.1670) (0.3804) (0.1934)
γ
k
(SC Country USD) 0.2678*** 0.1587*** 0.4107*** 0.2057***
(0.0425) (0.0298) (0.0253) (0.0223)
γ
i
(SC HS4 USD) 0.9744*** 1.0986*** 1.0144*** 1.1128***
(0.0517) (0.0229) (0.0473) (0.0313)
ϕ
i,k
USDRatio im 0.1777*** 0.0759***
(0.0340) (0.0271)
ϕ
i
byfirm USDRatio im 0.1001*** 0.0559**
(0.0217) (0.0275)
NOB 132,648 8,315 132,648 8,315
N. of firms 50,825 6,494 50,825 6,494
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are
estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects.
Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country and
years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
39
Table A.4: New Exporters in 2018
previous year no trade no trade
lnSize
i,k
-0.0065*** -0.0031 -0.0074*** -0.0034*
(0.0015) (0.0019) (0.0018) (0.0020)
MShare
i
(HS4) -0.7688 0.4015 -0.7540 0.3133
(0.4897) (1.1139) (0.4981) (1.1955)
γ
k
(SC Country USD) 0.2719*** 0.1538*** 0.4185*** 0.1791***
(0.0455) (0.0216) (0.0266) (0.0155)
γ
i
(SC HS4 USD) 0.9810*** 1.0325*** 1.0231*** 1.0578***
(0.0490) (0.0230) (0.0447) (0.0228)
ϕ
i,k
USDRatio im 0.1775*** 0.0376
(0.0328) (0.0233)
ϕ
i
byfirm USDRatio im 0.0997*** 0.0235
(0.0201) (0.0225)
NOB 130,776 6,460 130,776 6,460
N. of firms 49,134 5,560 49,134 5,560
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are
estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects.
Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country and
years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
40
Table A.5: New Exporters in 2019
previous year no trade no trade
lnSize
i,k
-0.0063*** -0.0009 -0.0070*** -0.0011
(0.0017) (0.0011) (0.0019) (0.0011)
MShare
i
(HS4) -0.7293 6.0224** -0.7085 6.6410**
(0.4849) (2.7632) (0.5036) (2.9414)
γ
k
(SC Country USD) 0.2789*** 0.0748*** 0.4295*** 0.0986***
(0.0376) (0.0178) (0.0172) (0.0197)
γ
i
(SC HS4 USD) 1.0106*** 0.9665*** 1.0500*** 0.9826***
(0.0523) (0.0418) (0.0480) (0.0394)
ϕ
i,k
USDRatio im 0.1750*** 0.0525***
(0.0313) (0.0188)
ϕ
i,
byfirm USDRatio im 0.0999*** 0.0404**
(0.0203) (0.0165)
NOB 129,953 4,106 129,953 4,106
N. of firms 49,137 3,674 49,137 3,674
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are
estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects.
Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country and
years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
41
Table A.6: New Exporters in 2020
previous year no trade no trade
lnSize
i,k
-0.0029 0.0010 -0.0033 0.0010
(0.0022) (0.0008) (0.0025) (0.0009)
MShare
i
(HS4) -1.3609*** 0.7241 -1.3424*** 0.8296
(0.2818) (2.0715) (0.2884) (2.0540)
γ
k
(SC Country USD) 0.2575*** 0.0310*** 0.3724*** 0.0396***
(0.0403) (0.0107) (0.0146) (0.0091)
γi(SC HS4 USD) 1.0703*** 0.8981*** 1.1022*** 0.9065***
(0.0584) (0.0636) (0.0566) (0.0632)
ϕi, k
USDRatio im 0.1453*** 0.0234**
(0.0374) (0.0098)
ϕ
i
byfirm USDRatio im 0.0841*** 0.0179*
(0.0286) (0.0092)
NOB 133,242 8,589 133,242 8,589
N. of firms 55,831 7,627 55,831 7,627
Note: The dependent variable is the US dollar invoicing currency ratio. These models are
estimated by instrumental variable fractional probit, and the coefficients are marginal effects.
Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered by the import size of the destination country and
years. Firm types are narrow two-way exporters. ***, **, * represent one, five, and ten percent
significance level.
42