The Effect of Home-Sharing on House Prices and Rents:
Evidence from Airbnb
Kyle Barron
Edward Kung
Davide Proserpio
§
Abstract
We assess the impact of home-sharing on residential house prices and rents. Using a dataset
of Airbnb listings from the entire United States and an instrumental variables estimation strat-
egy, we show that Airbnb has a positive impact on house prices and rents. This effect is stronger
in zipcodes with a lower share of owner-occupiers, consistent with non-owner-occupiers being
more likely to reallocate their homes from the long- to the short-term rental market. At the
median owner-occupancy rate zipcode, we find that a 1% increase in Airbnb listings leads to
a 0.018% increase in rents and a 0.026% increase in house prices. Finally, we formally test
whether the Airbnb effect is due to the reallocation of the housing supply. Consistent with
this hypothesis, we find that, while the total supply of housing is not affected by the entry of
Airbnb, Airbnb listings increase the supply of short-term rental units and decrease the supply
of long-term rental units.
Keywords: Sharing economy, peer-to-peer markets, housing markets, Airbnb
We thank Don Davis, Richard Green, Chun Kuang, Aske Egsgaard, Tom Chang, and seminar participants at
the AREUA National Conference, the RSAI Annual Meetings, the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, the UCI-
UCLA-USC Urban Research Symposium, and the PSI Conference for helpful comments and suggestions. All errors
are our own.
Department of Economics, UCLA; [email protected].
§
Marshall School of Business, USC; [email protected].
1
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
1 Introduction
The sharing economy represents a set of peer-to-peer online marketplaces that facilitate matching
between demanders and suppliers of various goods and services. The suppliers in these markets
are often small (mostly individuals), and they often share excess capacity that might otherwise go
unutilized—hence the term “sharing economy. Economic theory would suggest that the sharing
economy improves economic efficiency by reducing frictions that cause capacity to go underutilized,
and the explosive growth of sharing platforms (such as Uber for ride-sharing and Airbnb for home-
sharing) testifies to the underlying demand for such markets.
1
The growth of the sharing economy
has also come at the cost of great disruption to traditional markets (Zervas et al., 2017) as well
as new regulatory challenges, leading to contentious policy debates about how best to balance
individual participants’ rights to freely transact, the efficiency gains from sharing economies, the
disruption caused to traditional markets, and the role of the platforms themselves in the regulatory
process.
Home-sharing, in particular, has been the subject of intense criticism. Namely, critics argue
that home-sharing platforms like Airbnb raise the cost of living for local renters while mainly
benefitting local landlords and non-resident tourists.
2
It is easy to see the economic argument. By
reducing frictions in the peer-to-peer market for short-term rentals, home-sharing platforms cause
some landlords to switch from supplying the market for long-term rentals—in which residents are
more likely to participate—to supplying the short-term market—in which non-residents are more
likely to participate. Because the total supply of housing is fixed or inelastic in the short run, this
drives up the rental rate in the long-term market. Concern over home-sharing’s impact on housing
affordability has garnered significant attention from policymakers and has motivated many cities
to impose stricter regulations on home-sharing.
3
1
These frictions could include search frictions in matching demanders with suppliers and information frictions
associated with the quality of the good being transacted or with the trustworthiness of the buyer or seller. See Einav
et al. (2016) for an overview of the economics of peer-to-peer markets including the specific technological innovations
that have facilitated their growth.
2
Another criticism of Airbnb is that the company does not do enough to combat racial discrimination on its
platform (Edelman and Luca, 2014; Edelman et al., 2017) or that it generates negative externalities for neighbors
(Filippas and Horton, 2018) though we will not directly address these issues in this paper.
3
For example, Santa Monica outlaws short-term, non-owner-occupied rentals of fewer than 30 days as does New
York State for apartments in buildings with three or more residences. San Francisco passed a 60-day annual hard
cap on short-term rentals (which was subsequently vetoed by the mayor). It is unclear, however, to what degree to
which these regulations are enforced.
2
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Whether or not home-sharing increases housing costs for local residents is an empirical question.
There are a few reasons why it might not. The market for short-term rentals may be very small
compared to the market for long-term rentals. In this case, even large changes to the short-term
market might not have a measurable effect on the long-term market. The short-term market could
be small—even if the short-term rental rate is high relative to the long-term rate—if landlords prefer
more reliable long-term tenants and a more stable income stream. Alternatively, it is possible that
home-sharing simply does not cause much reallocation from the long-term rental stock to the short-
term rental stock. Owner-occupiers—those who own the home in which they live—may supply the
short-term rental market with spare rooms and cohabit with guests or they may supply their entire
home during temporary absences,
4
but either way, the participation of owner-occupiers in the short-
term rental market may not cause a reallocation from the long-term rental stock if these housing
units are still primarily used as long-term rentals in the sense that the owners are renting long-term
to themselves. Another type of participation in the short-term rental market that would not result
in reallocation is vacation homes that would not have been rented to long-term tenants anyway,
perhaps due to the restrictiveness of long-term leases causing vacation home-owners to not want to
rent to long-term tenants. In this case, the vacation home units were never part of the long-term
rental stock to begin with. In either case, whether owner-occupiers or vacation-home owners, these
homes would not be made available to long-term tenants independently of the existence of a home-
sharing platform. Instead, home-sharing provides these owners with an income stream for times
when their housing capacity would otherwise be underutilized.
In this paper, we study the effect of home-sharing on residential house prices and rents using
a comprehensive dataset of all U.S. properties listed on Airbnb, the world’s largest home-sharing
platform. The data are collected from public-facing pages on the Airbnb website between 2012 and
the end of 2016, covering the entire United States. From this data, we construct a panel dataset of
Airbnb listings at the zipcode-year-month level. From Zillow, a website specializing in residential
real estate transactions, we obtain a panel of house price and rental rate indices, also at the zipcode-
year-month level. Zillow provides a platform for matching buyers and sellers in the housing market
and landlords with tenants in the long-term rental market; thus, their price measures reflect sale
4
A frequently cited example is that of the flight attendant who rents out his or her home on Airbnb while traveling
for work.
3
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
prices and rental rates in the market for long-term housing. Finally, we supplement this data with
a rich set of time-varying zipcode characteristics collected from the Census Bureau’s American
Community Survey (ACS) and a set of variables correlated with tourism demand such as hotel
occupancy rates from STR, airport travelers from the Bureau of Transportation Statistics (BTS),
and hotels’ online reviews from TripAdvisor.
In the raw correlations, we find that the number of Airbnb listings in zipcode i in year-month
t is positively associated with both house prices and rental rates. In a baseline OLS regression
with no controls, we find that a 1% increase in Airbnb listings is associated with a 0.1% increase
in rental rates and a 0.18% increase in house prices. Of course, these estimates should not be
interpreted as causal and may instead be picking up spurious correlations. For example, cities that
are growing in population likely have rising rents, house prices, and numbers of Airbnb listings
at the same time. We therefore exploit the panel nature of our dataset to control for unobserved
zipcode level effects and arbitrary city level time trends. We include zipcode fixed effects to absorb
any permanent differences between zipcodes while fixed effects at the Core Based Statistical Area
(CBSA)-year-month level control for any shocks to housing market conditions that are common
across zipcodes within a CBSA.
5
We further control for unobserved zipcode-specific, time-varying factors using an instrumental
variable that is plausibly exogenous to local zipcode level shocks to the housing market. To con-
struct the instrument, we exploit the fact that Airbnb is a young company that has experienced
explosive growth over the past five years. Figure 1 shows worldwide Google search interest in Airbnb
from 2008 to 2016. Demand fundamentals for short-term housing are unlikely to have changed so
drastically from 2008 to 2016 as to fully explain the spike in interest, so most of the growth in
Airbnb search interest is likely driven by information diffusion and technological improvements to
Airbnb’s platform as it matures as a company. Neither of these should be correlated with local zip-
code level unobserved shocks to the housing market. By itself, global search interest is not enough
for an instrument because we already control for arbitrary CBSA level time trends. We therefore
interact the Google search index for Airbnb with a measure of how “touristy” a zipcode is in a
base year, 2010. We define “touristy” to be a measure of a zipcode’s attractiveness for tourists and
5
The CBSA is a geographic unit defined by the U.S. Office of Management and Budget that roughly corresponds
to an urban center and the counties that commute to it.
4
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
proxy for it using the number of establishments in the food service and accommodations industry.
6
These include eating and drinking places as well as hotels, bed and breakfasts, and other forms
of short-term lodging. The identifying assumptions of our specification are that: 1) Landlords in
more touristy zipcodes are more likely to switch into the short-term rental market in response to
learning about Airbnb than landlords in less touristy zipcodes and 2) ex-ante levels of touristiness
are not systematically correlated with ex-post unobserved shocks to the housing market at the
zipcode level that are also correlated in time with Google search interest for Airbnb. We discuss
the instrument, its construction, and exercises supporting the exclusion restriction in more detail
in Sections 5, 5.1, and in the Appendix B.
Using this instrumental variable, we estimate that for zipcodes with the median owner-occupancy
rate (72%), a 1% increase in Airbnb listings leads to a 0.018% increase in the rental rate and a
0.026% increase in house prices. We also find that the effect of Airbnb listings on rental rates and
house prices is decreasing in the owner-occupancy rate. For zipcodes with a 56% owner-occupancy
rate (the 25th percentile), the effect of a 1% increase in Airbnb listings is 0.024% for rents and
0.037% for house prices. For zipcodes with an 82% owner-occupancy rate (the 75th percentile),
the effect of a 1% increase in Airbnb listings is only 0.014% for rents and 0.019% for house prices.
These results are robust to a number of sensitivity and robustness checks that we discuss in detail
in Sections 5.1 and 6.2.
The fact that the effect of Airbnb is moderated by the owner-occupancy rate suggests that the
effect of Airbnb could be driven by non-owner occupiers being more likely (because of Airbnb) to
reallocate their housing units from the long- to the short-term rental market. We directly test this
hypothesis using the same instrumental strategy described above and data on various measures of
housing supply that we collected from the American Community Survey. We find that: (i) the total
housing stock (which is the sum of all renter-occupied, owner-occupied, and vacant units) is not
affected by the entry of Airbnb, (ii) an increase in Airbnb listings leads to an increase in the number
of units held vacant for recreational or seasonal use,
7
(iii) an increase in Airbnb listings leads to a
decrease in the number of units available to long-term renters, and (iv) the above effects on supply
6
We focus on tourism because Airbnb has historically been frequented more by tourists than business travelers.
Airbnb has said that 90% of its customers are vacationers but is attempting to gain market share in the business
travel sector.
7
According to Census methodology, units without a usual tenant but rented occassionally to Airbnb guests would
be classified as vacant for recreational or seasonal use. We describe the data in more detail in Section 6.4.
5
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
are smaller for zipcodes with a higher owner-occupancy rate. These results are consistent with
the hypothesis that Airbnb increases rents and house prices by causing a reallocation of housing
supply from the long-term rental market to the short-term rental market. Moreover, the size of
the reallocation is greater in zipcodes with fewer owner-occupiers because, intuitively, non-owner-
occupiers may be more likely to reallocate. Finally, it is worth mentioning that we cannot rule out
the possibility of other effects of Airbnb such as any of the positive or negative externalities; thus,
our results should be interpreted as the estimated net effect with evidence for the presence of a
reallocation channel.
2 Related literature
We are aware of only two other academic papers that directly study the effect of home-sharing on
housing costs, and both of them focus on a specific U.S. market. Lee (2016) provides a descriptive
analysis of Airbnb in the Los Angeles housing market while Horn and Merante (2017) use Airbnb
listings data from Boston in 2015 and 2016 to study the effect of Airbnb on rental rates. Using
a fixed effect model, they find that a one standard deviation increase in Airbnb listings at the
census tract level leads to a 0.4% increase in asking rents. In our data, we find that a one standard
deviation increase in listings at the within-CBSA zipcode level in 2015-2016 implies a 0.54% increase
in rents.
We contribute—and differentiate from previous work—to the literature concerning the effect
of home-sharing on housing costs in several important ways. First, we present the first estimates
of the effect of home-sharing on house prices and rents that use comprehensive data from across
the United States. Second, we are able to exploit the panel structure of our dataset to control
for unobserved neighborhood heterogeneity as well as arbitrary city-level time trends. Moreover,
we identify a plausible instrument for Airbnb supply and conduct several exercises to support its
validity. These exercises reassure us that the measured association between Airbnb and house prices
and rents is likely causal. Third, we show that the effect of Airbnb is strongly moderated by the
rate of owner-occupiers, a finding consistent with the hypothesis that the Airbnb effect operates
through the reallocation of housing supply from the long- to the short-term rental market. Fourth,
we provide direct evidence in support of this hypothesis by showing that Airbnb is associated with
6
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
a decrease in long-term rentals supply and an increase in short-term rentals supply while having no
association with changes in the total housing supply. Fifth, by showing that the effects of Airbnb
are moderated by the owner-occupancy rate, our results highlight the importance of the marginal
homeowner in terms of reallocation (since owner-occupiers are much less likely to reallocate their
housing to the permanent short-term rental stock). Thus, the marginal propensity of homeowners
to reallocate housing from the long- to the short-term rental market is a key elasticity determining
the overall effect of home-sharing.
Our paper also contributes to the growing literature on peer-to-peer markets. Such literature
covers a wide array of topics, from the effect of the sharing economy on labor market outcomes
(Chen et al., 2017; Hall and Krueger, 2017; Angrist et al., 2017), to entry and competition (Gong et
al., 2017; Horton and Zeckhauser, 2016; Li and Srinivasan, 2019; Zervas et al., 2017), to trust and
reputation (Fradkin et al., 2017; Proserpio et al., 2017; Zervas et al., 2015). Because the literature
on the topic is quite vast, here we focus only on papers that are closely related to ours and refer
the reader to Einav et al. (2016) for an overview of the economics of peer-to-peer markets and to
Proserpio and Tellis (2017) for a complete review of the literature on the sharing economy.
Closely related to the marketing literature and this work we find papers that study the effects
of the entry of peer-to-peer markets and the competition that they generate. Gong et al. (2017),
for example, provide evidence that the entry of Uber in China increased the demand for new cars;
Farronato and Fradkin (2018), Li and Srinivasan (2019), and Zervas et al. (2017) study the effect
of Airbnb on the hotel industry; however, each one of them focuses on a different question. Zervas
et al. (2017) focus on the subsitution patterns between Airbnb and hotels, and show that, after
Airbnb entry in Texas, hotel revenue dropped. Moreover, the authors show that this negative
effect is stronger in periods of peak demand. Farronato and Fradkin (2018) focus instead on the
gains in consumer welfare generated by the entry of Airbnb in 50 U.S. markets. Finally, Li and
Srinivasan (2019) study how the flexible nature of Airbnb listings affects hotel demand in different
markets. The authors show that, in response to the entry of Airbnb, some hotels may benefit
from moving away from seasonal pricing. Our paper looks at a somewhat unique context in this
literature because we focus on the effect of the sharing economy on the reallocation of goods from
one purpose to another, which may cause local externalities. Local externalities are present here
because the suppliers are local and the demanders are non-local; transactions in the home-sharing
7
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
market, therefore, involve a reallocation of resources from locals to non-locals.
8
Our contribution
is therefore to study this unique type of sharing economy in which public policy may be especially
salient.
Finally, our work is related to papers studying the consequences of what happens when a online
platform lowers the cost to entry for suppliers. For example, both Kroft and Pope (2014) and
Seamans and Zhu (2013) study the impact of Craiglist on the newspaper industry and find a
substantial substitution effect between the two.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 3, we discuss the economics of home-
sharing and how home-sharing might be expected to affect housing markets. In Section 4, we
describe the data we collected from Airbnb and present some basic statistics. In Section 5, we
describe our methodology and present exercises in support of the exclusion restriction of our in-
strument In Section 6, we discuss the results and present several robustness checks to reinforce the
validity of our results. Section 7 discusses our findings, the limitations of our work, and provides
concluding remarks.
3 Theory
The market for long and short-term rentals is traditionally viewed as segmented on both the
supply and demand side. On the demand side, the demanders for short-term rentals are tourists,
visitors, and business travelers while the demanders for long-term rentals are local residents. On
the supply side, the suppliers of short-term rentals are traditionally hotels and bed and breakfasts
while the suppliers of long-term rentals are local landlords. Local residents who own their own
homes (owner-occupiers) are on both the demand and the supply side for long-term rentals (they
rent to themselves.)
Segmentation exists between the long- and short-term markets despite the fundamental simi-
larity in the product being offered (i.e., space and shelter). The segmentation may exist for a few
reasons. First, short-term demanders may have very different needs than long-term demanders.
Short-term demanders may only require a bed and a bathroom while long-term demanders may
8
This may not be seen as a real economic cost, though a shift of welfare from locals to non-locals is important
for public policy because policy is set locally. Some have also argued that home-sharing can create a real negative
spillover for neighbors (Filippas and Horton, 2018).
8
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
also require a kitchen and a living area. Second, the legal environment is very different for short
and long-term demanders. Long-term tenants are typically afforded rights and protections that are
not available to short-term visitors. Because of this segmentation, the unit price of renting exhibits
a term structure with the price of a short-term rental typically being much higher than the price
of a long-term rental. Marketplaces for long- and short-term rentals have historically remained
separate due to this segmentation.
Effects of home-sharing: Housing supply reallocation and expansion
With the advent of home-sharing, segmentation on the supply side is becoming blurred. Because
of home-sharing platforms like Airbnb, it is now much easier for properties that were traditionally
used only for long-term rental to now also be used for short-term rental.
9
Now that it has become easier for owners of traditionally long-term housing to supply the
short-term market, what can we expect the effects to be? First, we can expect some owners of
traditionally long-term housing to switch from supplying a long-term demander to supplying short-
term demanders. In the short run, the supply of housing and of hotels is inelastic, so this reduces
the supply of housing available in the long-term rental market and increases the supply of rooms
in the short-term rental market. This, in turn, pushes up rents in the long-term rental market
and pushes down rents in the short-term rental market (Horn and Merante, 2017; Zervas et al.,
2017). To the extent that search and matching frictions exist in both rental markets, this should
also reduce the vacancy rate in the long-term rental market and increase the vacancy rate in the
short-term rental market.
In the long run, we may also expect a supply response. The quantity of homes that are able
to supply both long- and short-term renters (i.e., homes traditionally built for long-term housing)
would be expected to increase in the long-run, while the quantity of hotel rooms that are only
able to supply the short-term market should decrease. The degree to which there will be quantity
adjustments will depend on the amount of land available in the city and the stringency of land use
regulations as well as the cost of construction (Gyourko and Molloy, 2015).
The size of the price and quantity response to home-sharing will also depend on the degree to
9
Home-sharing platforms greatly reduce traditional frictions that previously prevented some homeowners from
participating in the short-term rental market such as transactional frictions associated with trust (Einav et al., 2016).
9
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
which owners of traditionally long-term rental housing reallocate to the short-term rental market.
There are many reasons why an owner would choose not to reallocate. First and foremost, the
owner may live in her home. Thus, the owner will not reallocate from the long-term market (where
she rents to herself) to the short-term market. She may still participate in the short-term market by
selling unused capacity such as spare rooms or time when she is away, but this does not constitute
a reallocation from the long-term rental stock to the short-term rental stock because those spare
units of capacity would not have been allocated to a long-term tenant anyway and therefore does
not push up long-term rental rates. However, the allocation of spare capacity to the short-term
rental market, which constitutes a pure supply expansion, can reduce prices in the short-term rental
market.
10
Second, the owner may not reallocate from the long-term market to the short-term market
because the costs outweigh the benefits. There could be many costs associated with supplying the
short-term rental market. Short-term renters may annoy neighbors, thus reflecting poorly on the
host and reducing his social capital in the community. In some cases, an owner may be bound
against renting to short-term renter by a homeowners’ association. Short-term renters may also
be more likely than long-term renters to cause property depreciation. A property owner may also
prefer the steadier stream of payments offered by a long-term tenant over the lumpier stream of
payments offered by sporadic visitors booking the home for short stays. Owners who simply choose
not to use the short-term market will cause no reallocation and therefore have no effect on prices
in either the long-term or the short-term rental markets.
Finally, it is worth pointing out that reallocation from the long-term rental stock to the short-
term rental stock does not require that expected rents in the short-term rental market be higher
than expected rents in the long-term rental market. There may be reasons for preferring to rent
short-term instead of long-term even if the expected rents from short-term are lower, as may be
the case according to Coles et al. (2017). One reason could be that the owner does not like the
restrictiveness of a long-term lease. Even if the owner does not plan to use the property as a
primary residence or a vacation home, not renting to a long-term tenant increases the option value
for other uses such as letting family or friends stay or even holding out for higher long-term rents
10
If the owner-occupier is currently allocating spare rooms to the long-term market (i.e., by having a roommate)
and then decides to stop renting to a roommate and instead use Airbnb, then this would constitute a reallocation.
10
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
in the future while capitalizing on surges in short-term demand.
Effects of home-sharing: Externalities and option value
Besides reallocation of housing supply, home-sharing can affect long-term rental rates in a few other
ways. First, there may be both positive and negative externalities. On the positive side, home-
sharing may draw tourist money into the neighborhood, increasing revenues to local businesses and
increasing the demand for space in the neighborhoods. This would have the effect of increasing both
long and short-term rental rates. Farronato and Fradkin (2018) and Coles et al. (2017) document
that home-sharing has drawn tourists into neighborhood that previously had very few, and Alyakoob
and Rahman (2018) find a positive relation between Airbnb and restaurant employment. On the
negative side, the tourists that home-sharing draws in may be unpleasant or noisy. This can make
the neighborhood a more unpleasant place to live, thus decreasing rents. In local debates over
Airbnb, this has proven to be an unexpectedly salient point (Filippas and Horton, 2018).
Second, if tenants themselves are able to sell unused capacity in the short-term market, even
while under a long-term rental lease, then this would increase the demand for renting. In the short
run where supply is inelastic, this would push up rents in the long-term rental market. The degree
to which rents are increased depends on the degree to which tenants are willing and able to sell
unused capacity.
11
In the long-run, this effect could lead to further expansion in housing supply.
So far, the discussion has focused on rental rates. Since buying a house can be viewed as
purchasing the present value of future rental payments, house prices should be equal to the ex-
pected present value of rents for a similar unit, adjusted for any tax implications, borrowing costs,
maintenance costs, and physical depreciation (Poterba, 1984). Thus, any effect of home-sharing
on long-term rental rates will be directly capitalized into house prices. However, because home-
sharing also allows the homeowner to sell unused capacity on the short-term market, it should have
an additional effect of increasing prices even further than the direct effect on rents.
Finally, we note that it is possible that home-sharing externalities differentially affect homeown-
ers and renters. For example, homeowners may be more sensitive to noisy neighbors than renters. If
such were the case, then the net effect of home-sharing on the price-to-rent ratio could be negative
11
In practice, this will depend on the laws of individual cities and the types of leases landlords sign with tenants,
and the enforceability of any associated clauses.
11
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
even though the increased option value of using spare capacity would increase it.
Effects of home-sharing: Other effects
Finally, we note two other effects that home-sharing may have on short and long-term rental
markets. First, in the long-run, home-sharing may change the characteristics of the housing stock.
For example, by increasing the option value of spare capacity, home-sharing may cause future homes
to be built with spare capacity in mind. There may be an increase in the supply of homes with
accessory dwelling units that are optimized for delivery to short-run tenants with the main unit
simultaneously being occupied by the owner.
Second, home-sharing may change the short-run supply elasticity of short-term rentals. Without
home-sharing, the short-run supply of short-term rentals is inelastic because there is only a fixed
number of hotel rooms in any given neighborhood. High development costs and regulations make
it difficult to adjust this number quickly. Home-sharing increases the flexibility of traditionally
long-term housing to freely move between the long and short-term rental markets, thus leading to a
more elastic supply in the short-term market that is able to quickly expand in response to surges in
demand and then quickly contract when the surge is over. Farronato and Fradkin (2018) document
this phenomenon and evaluate its welfare implications.
Summary
To summarize, we have argued that home-sharing will have the following effects. First, it will cause
a reallocation from the long-term housing supply to the short-term rental market. In the short-run,
this will push up rental rates and house prices, and decrease vacancy rates in the long-term market.
In the long-run, this could lead to an increase in housing supply, depending on the housing supply
curve of the market. Second, the size of the reallocation effect will depend on the propensity of
homeowners to reallocate housing from the long-term market to the short-term market in response
to home-sharing. The effect of home-sharing will be smaller when there are fewer homeowners
choosing to reallocate. Third, rents and prices should both increase due to the increased option
value of spare housing capacity, with prices increasing more than rents, thus leading to an increased
price-to-rent ratio. Countervailing these three effects (which are all positive on prices and rents)
is the possibility of negative externalities. If home-sharing makes the neighborhood less desirable
12
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
to live in, then this could have a negative effect on rents and prices. If homeowners are especially
sensitive to these externalities, home-sharing could decrease the price-to-rent ratio. On the other
hand, there could also be positive externalities that have the opposite effects.
The predicted effects of home-sharing on rental rates and house prices is therefore ambiguous.
In this paper, we aim simply to test for the net effect. We will find that the net effect is positive
on rental rates, house prices, and the price-to-rent ratio in a way that is consistent with both the
reallocation channel and with increasing the option value of spare capacity. We also provide some
direct evidence of the reallocation channel. However, we cannot rule out the potential for other
effects like externalities, nor do we disentangle the size of the various channels. It is also worth
mentioning that, in this paper, we focus only on short-run effects. This choice is dictated by two
reasons: First, home-sharing is a relatively new phenomenon, and Airbnb itself is only a decade
old. Cities are still actively grappling with how to respond to home-sharing, and so we believe
that it is too early to look for long-run effects. Second, in this paper, we do not find any empirical
evidence that Airbnb (as yet) is associated with changes to the total housing supply, though we do
find evidence for reallocation of housing from long-term rental stock to short-term rental stock.
4 Data and Background on Airbnb
4.1 Background on Airbnb
Recognized by most as the pioneer of the sharing economy, Airbnb is a peer-to-peer marketplace for
short-term rentals, where the suppliers (hosts) offer different kinds of accommodations (i.e. shared
rooms, entire homes, or even yurts and treehouses) to prospective renters (guests). Airbnb was
founded in 2008 and has experienced dramatic growth, going from just a few hundred hosts in 2008
to over three million properties supplied by over one million hosts in 150,000 cities and 52 countries
in 2017. Over 130 million guests have used Airbnb, and with a market valuation of over $31B,
Airbnb is one of the world’s largest accommodation brands.
4.2 Airbnb listings data
Our main source of data comes directly from the Airbnb website. We collected consumer-facing
information about the complete set of Airbnb properties located in the United States and about
13
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
the hosts who offer them. The data collection process spanned a period of approximately five years,
from mid-2012 to the end of 2016. We performed scrapes at irregular intervals between 2012 to
2014 and at a weekly interval starting January 2015.
12
Our scraping algorithm collected all listing information available to users of the website, in-
cluding the property location, the daily price, the average star rating, a list of photos, the guest
capacity, the number of bedrooms and bathrooms, a list of amenities such as WiFi and air condi-
tioning, etc., and the list of all reviews from guests who have stayed at the property.
13
Airbnb host
information includes the host name and photograph, a brief profile description, and the year-month
in which the user registered as a host on Airbnb.
Our final dataset contains detailed information about 1,097,697 listings and 682,803 hosts span-
ning a period of nine years, from 2008 to 2016. Because of Airbnb’s dominance in the home-sharing
market, we believe that this data represents the most comprehensive picture of home-sharing in
the U.S. ever constructed for independent research.
4.3 Calculating the number of Airbnb listings, 2008-2016
Once we have collected the data, the next step is to define a measure of Airbnb supply. This task
requires two choices: First, we need to choose the geographic granularity of our measure; second,
we need to define the entry and exit dates of each listing in the Airbnb platform. Regarding
the geographic aggregation, we conduct our main analysis at the zipcode level for a few reasons.
First, it is the lowest level of geography for which we can reliably assign listings without error
(other than user input error).
14
Second, neighborhoods are a natural unit of analysis for housing
markets because there is significant heterogeneity in housing markets across neighborhoods within
cities but comparatively less heterogeneity within neighborhoods. Zipcodes will be our proxy for
neighborhoods. Third, conducting the analysis at the zipcode level as opposed to the city level helps
with identification. This is due to our ability to compare zipcodes within cities, thus controlling for
any unobserved city level factors that may be unrelated to Airbnb but that affect all neighborhoods
12
In their paper, Horn and Merante (2017) incorrectly state that our Airbnb dataset comes form InsideAirbnb.com
(probably referencing an older version of this paper), but, in fact, the current results are based on data that one of
the authors of this paper scraped and collected.
13
Airbnb does not reveal the exact street address or coordinates of the property for privacy reasons; however, the
listing’s city, street, and zipcode correspond to the property’s real location.
14
Airbnb does report the latitude and longitude of each property but only up to a perturbation of a few hundred
meters. So it would be possible, but complicated, to aggregate the listings to finer geographies with some error.
14
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
within a city such as a city-wide shock to labor productivity.
The second choice, how to determine the entry and exit date of each listing, comes less naturally.
First, our scraping algorithm did not constantly monitor a listing’s status to determine whether it
was active or not but rather obtained snapshots of the properties available for rent in the US at
different points in time until the end of 2014 and at the weekly level starting in 2015. Second, even
if it did so, measuring active supply would still be challenging.
15
Thus, to construct the number of
listings going back in time, we employ a variety of methods following Zervas et al. (2017), which
we summarize in Table 1.
Table 1: Methods for Computing the Number of Listings
Listing is considered active ...
Method 1 starting from host join date
Method 2 for 3 months after host join date and after every guest review
Method 3 for 6 months after host join date and after every guest review
Method 1 is our preferred choice to measure Airbnb supply and will be our main independent
variable in all the analyses presented in this paper. This measure computes a listing’s entry date
as the date its host registered on Airbnb and assumes that listings never exit. The advantage of
using the host join date as the entry date is that for a majority of listings, this is the most accurate
measure of when the listing was first posted. The disadvantage of this measure is that it is likely
to overestimate the listings that are available on Airbnb (and accepting reservations) at any point
in time. However, as discussed in Zervas et al. (2017), such overestimation would cause biases only
if, after controlling for several zipcode characteristics, it is correlated with the error term.
16
Aware of the fact that method 1 is an imperfect measure of Airbnb supply, we also experiment
with alternative definitions of Airbnb listings’ entry and exit. Methods 2 and 3 exploit our knowl-
edge of each listing’s review dates to determine whether a listing is active. The heuristic we use
is as follows: A listing enters the market when the host registers with Airbnb and stays active for
15
Estimating the number of active listings is a challenge even for Airbnb. Despite the fact that Airbnb offers an
easy way to unlist properties, many times hosts neglect to do so, creating “stale vacancies” that seem available for
rent but in actuality are not. Fradkin (2015), using proprietary data from Airbnb, estimates that between 21% and
32% of guest requests are rejected due to this effect.
16
The absence of bias in this measure is also confirmed by Farronato and Fradkin (2018) where using Airbnb
proprietary data resulted in the same estimates obtained by Zervas et al. (2017) (where the data collection and
measures of Airbnb supply are similar to those used in this paper).
15
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
m months. We refer to m as the listing’s Time To Live (TTL). Each time a listing is reviewed,
the TTL is extended by m months from the review date. If a listing exceeds the TTL without any
reviews, it is considered inactive. A listing becomes active again if it receives a new review. In our
analysis, we test two different TTLs, 3 months and 6 months.
Despite the fact that our different measures of Airbnb supply rely on different heuristics and
data, because of Airbnb’s tremendous growth, all our measures of Airbnb supply are extremely
correlated. The correlation between method 1 and each other measure is above 0.95 in all cases. In
the Appendix, we present robustness checks of our main results to the different measures of Airbnb
supply discussed above and show that results are qualitatively and quantitatively unchanged.
17
4.4 Zillow: rental rates and house prices
Zillow.com is an online real estate company that provides estimates of house and rental prices
for over 110 million homes across the U.S. In addition to giving value estimates of homes, Zillow
provides a set of indexes that track and predict home values and rental prices at a monthly level
and at different geographical granularities.
For house prices, we use the Zillow Home Value Index (ZHVI) that estimates the median
transaction price for the actual stock of homes in a given geographic unit and point in time. The
advantage of using the ZHVI is that it is available at the zipcode-month level for over 13,000
zipcodes.
For rental rates, we use the Zillow Rent Index (ZRI). Like the ZHVI, Zillow’s rent index is meant
to reflect the median monthly rental rate for the actual stock of homes in a geographic unit and
point in time. Crucially, Zillow’s rent index is based on rental list prices and is therefore a measure
of prevailing rents for new tenants. This is the relevant comparison for a homeowner deciding
whether to place her unit on the short-term or long-term market. Moreover, because Zillow is not
considered a platform for finding short-term housing, the ZRI should be reflective of rental prices in
the long-term market.
18
For each zipcode, we calculate the price-to-rent ratio as simply the ZHVI
17
One additional source of error in our computations is listings that were posted and then taken down between
2008 and 2011 since we did not start scraping until 2012. However, the number of such listings is likely to be small,
as shown in Figure 3. Moreover, our regressions use only data starting in 2011, so the influence on our results is likely
minimal. Further, as we show in Table 15 of the Appendix, our results are robust to the exclusion of early years.
18
Since the ZHVI and ZRI measure medians, our results only apply to the middle of the housing market. In the
Appendix, we explore effects on different segments of the housing market and find that the effects are qualitatively
similar.
16
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
divided by the ZRI.
4.5 Other data sources
We supplement the above data with several additional sources.
Variables used for the instrument We use monthly Google Trends data for the search term
“airbnb”, which we downloaded directly from Google. This index measures how often people
worldwide search for the term “airbnb” on Google and is normalized to have a value of 100 at
the peak month. We use the Census’s Zipcode Business Patterns data to measure the number of
establishments in the food services and accommodations industry (NAICS code 72) for each zipcode
in 2010.
Zipcode level time-varying characteristics We collect from the American Community Survey
(ACS) zipcode level annual estimates of median household income, population, share of 25-60 years
old with bachelors’ degrees or higher, and employment rate. From the ACS, we also obtain zipcode
level annual estimates of the number of housing units occupied by their owners or renters, and the
number of vacant units. The ACS also reports the reason a housing unit is vacant (for example,
whether the owner is holding it vacant so that he or she can use it occassionally for recreation or
whether it is vacant and currently looking for a tenant). We can therefore calculate the owner-
occupancy rate as the share of occupied units that are occupied by owners and the total housing
stock as the sum of owner-occupied units, renter-occupied units, and vacant units.
Proxies for tourism demand We obtained hotel occupancy rates at the CBSA-year-month
level from STR, a company that tracks hotel performance worldwide. We collected the number of
incoming airport travelers for all airports in the United States from the Bureau of Transportation
Statistics. Finally, we collected the complete set of hotel and restaurant reviews for all the hotels
and restaurants available on TripAdvisor. This data amount to about 18 million hotel reviews from
88,000 accommodation properties (hotels, inns, B&Bs) and about 25 million restaurant reviews
from about 478,000 restaurants from 2001 to the beginning of 2017 (2019 for restaurant reviews).
17
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
4.6 Summary statistics
Figure 2 shows the geographic distribution of Airbnb listings in June 2011 and June 2016. The map
shows significant geographic heterogeneity in Airbnb listings with most Airbnb listings occurring in
large cities and along the coasts. Moreover, there exists significant geographic heterogeneity in the
growth of Airbnb over time. From 2011 to 2016, the number of Airbnb listings in some zipcodes
grew by a factor of 30 or more; in others, there was no growth at all. Figure 3 shows the total
number of Airbnb listings over time in our dataset using methods 1-3. Using method 1 as our
preferred method, we observe that from 2011 to 2016, the total number of Airbnb listings grew by
a factor of 30, reaching over 1 million listings in 2016.
Table 2 gives a sense of the size of Airbnb relative to the housing stock at the zipcode level, for
the 100 largest CBSAs by population in our data. Even in 2016, Airbnb remains a small percentage
of the total housing stock for most zipcodes. The median ratio of Airbnb listings to housing stock
is 0.21%, and the 90th percentile is 1.88%. When comparing to the stock of vacant homes, Airbnb
begins to appear more significant. The median ratio of Airbnb listings to vacant homes (either
for long- or short-term rental) is 2.63%, and the 90th percentile is 20%. Perhaps the most salient
comparison—at least from the perspective of a potential renter—is the number of Airbnb listings
relative to the stock of homes listed as vacant and for rent (which are part of the long-term rental
supply). This statistic reaches 13.7% in the median zipcode in 2016 and 129% in the 90th percentile
zipcode. This implies that in the median zipcode, a local resident looking for a long-term rental
unit will find that about 1 in 8 of the potentially available homes are being placed on Airbnb instead
of being made available to long-term residents. Framed in this way, concerns about the effect of
Airbnb on the housing market do not appear unfounded.
5 Methodology
Let Y
ict
be either the price index or the rent index for zipcode i in CBSA c in year-month t, let
Airbnb
ict
be a measure of Airbnb supply, and let oorate
ic,2010
be the owner-occupancy rate in
18
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
2010.
19
We assume the following causal relationship between Y
ict
and Airbnb
ict
:
ln Y
ict
= α + βAirbnb
ict
+ γAirbnb
ict
× oorate
ic,2010
+ X
ict
η +
ict
(1)
where X
ict
is a vector of observed time-varying zipcode characteristics and
ict
contains unobserved
factors that may additionally influence Y
ict
. These factors could include anything that affects the
underlying desirability to live in zipcode i such as changes to local labor market conditions or
changes to local amenities like public school quality. If the unobserved factors are uncorrelated
with Airbnb
ict
, conditional on X
ict
, then we can consistently estimate β and γ by OLS. However,
ict
and Airbnb
ict
may be correlated through unobserved factors at the zipcode, city, and time
levels. We allow
ict
to contain unobserved zipcode level factors δ
i
, and unobserved time-varying
factors that affect all zipcodes within a CBSA equally, θ
ct
. Writing:
ict
= δ
i
+ θ
ct
+ ξ
ict
, Equation
(1) becomes:
ln Y
ict
= α + βAirbnb
ict
+ γAirbnb
ict
× oorate
ic,2010
+ X
ict
η + δ
i
+ θ
ct
+ ξ
ict
. (2)
Even after controlling for unobserved factors at the zipcode and CBSA-year-month level, there
may still be some unobserved zipcode-specific, time-varying factors contained in ξ
ict
that are corre-
lated with Airbnb
ict
. To address this issue, we construct an instrumental variable that is plausibly
uncorrelated with local shocks to the housing market at the zipcode level, ξ
ict
, but likely to affect
the number of Airbnb listings.
Our instrument begins with the worldwide Google Trends search index for the term “airbnb”, g
t
,
which measures the quantity of Google searches for “airbnb” in year-month t. Such trends represent
a measure of the extent to which awareness of Airbnb has diffused to the public, including both
demanders and suppliers of short-term rental housing. Figure 1 plots g
t
from 2008 to 2016, and it
is representative of the explosive growth of Airbnb over the past ten years. Crucially, the search
index is not likely to be reflective of growth in overall tourism demand because it is unlikely to
have changed so much over this relatively short time period. Moreover, it should not be reflective
19
We use the owner-occupancy rate in 2010 to minimize concerns about endogeneity of the owner-occupancy rate.
However, the results are robust to using the contemporaneous owner-occupancy rate as calculated from ACS 5-year
estimates from 2011 to 2016.
19
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
of overall growth in the supply of short-term housing, except to the extent that it is driven by
Airbnb.
20
The CBSA-year-month fixed effects θ
ct
already absorb any unobserved variation at the year-
month level. Therefore, to complete our instrument, we interact g
t
with a measure of how attractive
a zipcode is for tourists in base year 2010, h
i,2010
. We measure “touristiness” using the number of
establishments in the food services and accommodations industry (NAICS code 72) in a specific
zipcode. Zipcodes with more restaurants and hotels may be more attractive to tourists because
these are services that tourists need to consume locally—thus, it matters how many of these services
are near the tourist’s place of stay. Alternatively, the larger number of restaurants and hotels may
reflect an underlying local amenity that tourists value.
For the instrument to have power, potential hosts must be more likely to rent their property
in the short-term market in response to learning about Airbnb. We can verify this assumption
by examining the relationship between Google trends and the difference in Airbnb listings for
more touristy and less touristy zipcodes. Figure 4 shows that such difference increases as Airbnb
awareness increases, confirming our hypothesis.
In order for the instrument to be valid, z
ict
= g
t
× h
i,2010
must be uncorrelated with the
zipcode-specific, time-varying shocks to the housing market, ξ
ict
. This would be true if either
ex-ante touristiness in 2010 (h
i,2010
) is independent of time-varying zipcode level shocks (ξ
ict
) or
growth in worldwide Airbnb searches (g
t
) is independent of the specific timing of those shocks. To
see how our instrument addresses potential confounding factors, consider changes in zipcode level
crime rate as an omitted variable. It is unlikely that changes to crime rates across all zipcodes are
systematically correlated in time with worldwide Airbnb searches. Even if they were, they would
have to correlate in such a way that the correlation is systematically stronger or weaker in more
touristy zipcodes. Moreover, these biases would have to be systematically present within all cities
in our sample. Of course, we cannot rule this possibility out completely. We therefore now turn
to a detailed discussion of the instrument and its validity and present some exercises that suggest
that the exogeneity assumption is likely satisfied.
20
We provide further evidence to this effect in Section 6.2.
20
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
5.1 Discussion: Validity of the instrumental variable
The construction of an instrumental variable using the interaction of a plausibly exogenous time-
series (Google trends) with a potentially endogenous cross-sectional exposure variable (the touristi-
ness measure) is an approach that was popularized by Bartik (1991) and that researchers have
used in many prominent recent papers (Peri, 2012; Dube and Vargas, 2013; Nunn and Qian, 2014;
Hanna and Oliva, 2015; Diamond, 2016).
The approach is popular because one can often argue that some aggregate time trend, which
is exogenous to local conditions, will affect different spatial units systematically along some cross-
sectional exposure variable. In the classic Bartik (1991) example, national trends in industry-
specific productivity are interacted with the historical local industry composition to create an
instrument for local labor demand. Such an instrument will be valid if the interaction of the
aggregate time trend with the exposure variable is independent of the error term. This could
happen if either the time trend is independent of the error term (E[g
t
, ξ
ict
] = 0) or if the exposure
variable is independent of the error term (E[h
i,2010
, ξ
ict
] = 0). While this may seem plausible at
first glance, Christian and Barrett (2017) point out that if there are long-run time trends in the
error term, and if these long-run trends are systematically different along the exposure variable,
then the exogeneity assumption may fail. In our context, a story that may be told is the following.
Suppose there is a long-run trend toward gentrification that leads to higher house prices over time.
Suppose also that the trend of gentrification is higher in more touristy zipcodes. Since there is
also a systematic long-run trend in the time-series variable, g
t
, the instrument g
t
h
i,2010
is no longer
independent of the error term, and 2SLS estimates may reflect the effects of gentrification rather
than home-sharing.
We now proceed to make four arguments for why the exogeneity condition is likely to hold in
our setting.
Parallel pre-trends
As Christian and Barrett (2017) note, the first stage of this instrumental variable approach is anal-
ogous to a difference-in-differences (DD) coefficient estimates. In our case, since the specification
includes year-month and zipcode fixed effects, the variation in the instrument comes from compar-
21
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
ing Airbnb listings between high- and low-Airbnb awareness year-months, and between high- and
low-touristiness zipcodes. Because of this, Christian and Barrett (2017) suggest testing whether
spatial units with different levels of the exposure variable have parallel trends in periods before g
t
takes effect. This is similar to testing whether control and treatment groups have parallel pre-trends
in DD analysis. To do this, we plot the Zillow house price index for zipcodes in different quartiles
of 2010 touristiness (h
i,2010
) from 2009 to the end of 2016.
21
The results are shown in Figure 5.
The figure shows that there are no differential pre-trends in the Zillow Home-Value Index (ZHVI)
for zipcodes in different quartiles of touristiness until after 2012, which also happens to be when
interest in Airbnb began to grow according to Figure 1. This is true both when computing the raw
averages of ZHVI within quartile (top panel) and when computing the average of the residuals after
controlling for zipcode and CBSA-year-month fixed effects (bottom panel). The lack of differential
pre-trends suggests that zipcodes with different levels of touristiness do not generally have different
long-run house price trends, but they only began to diverge after 2012 when Airbnb started to
become well known.
IV has no effect in non-Airbnb zipcodes
To further provide support for the validity of our instrument, we perform another test that consists
of checking whether the instrumental variable predicts house prices and rental rates in zipcodes
that were never observed to have any Airbnb listings. If the instrument is valid, then it should only
be correlated to house prices and rental rates through its effect on Airbnb listings. So, in areas
with no Airbnb, we should not see a positive relationship between the instrument and house prices
and rental rates.
22
To test this, we regress the Zillow rent index and house price index on the instrumental variable
directly, using only data from zipcodes in which we never observed any Airbnb listings. The first
two columns of Table 3 report the results of these regressions and show that, conditional on the
fixed effects and zipcode demographics, we do not find any statistically significant relationship
21
We cannot repeat this exercise with rental rates because Zillow rental price data did not begin until 2011 or
2012 for most zipcodes.
22
This exercise is similar in spirit to an exercise performed by Martin and Yurukoglu (2017) to support the validity
of their instrument. Martin and Yurukoglu (2017) use the channel position of Fox News in the cable line-up as an
instrument for the effect of Fox viewership on Republican voting. They show that the future channel position of Fox
News is not correlated with Republican voting in the time periods before Fox News. This is analogous to us showing
that our instrument is not correlated with house prices and rents in zipcodes without Airbnb.
22
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
between the instrument and house prices/rental rates in zipcodes without Airbnb. If anything, we
find that there is a negative relationship between the instrument and house prices/rental rates in
zipcodes without Airbnb, though the estimates are imprecise and the sample size is considerably
reduced when considering only such zipcodes. By contrast, columns 3-4 of Table 3 show that if we
regress house prices and rental rates directly on the instrument for zipcodes with Airbnb, we find
a positive and statistically significant relationship.
Of course, the sample of zipcodes that never had any Airbnb listings could be fundamentally
different from the sample of zipcodes that did. In columns 1 and 2 of Table 4, we show that the
sample of zipcodes with Airbnb are indeed quite different from the sample of zipcodes without
Airbnb, which are richer and more educated in general. We therefore construct a third sample
of zipcodes with Airbnb, but that are more similar to the sample of zipcodes without Airbnb.
To do so, we use propensity-score matching. Starting with the full sample of zipcodes, we first
estimate a logistic regression at the zipcode level that predicts whether or not a zipcode will
be a non-Airbnb zipcode based on 2010 zipcode demographic characteristics (median household
income, population, college share, and employment rate) and touristiness. For each zipcode that
is observed to have no Airbnb, we find the nearest zipcode in terms of propensity score that
is observed to have some Airbnb entry over the whole 2011-2016 time period. In column 3 of
Table 4, we show that the propensity-score matched sample of zipcodes with Airbnb listings is (as
expected) demographically similar to the non-Airbnb sample (column 1). Columns 5-6 of Table
3 report the results when we regress house prices and rental rates directly on the instrument in
the propensity-score matched sample with Airbnb listings. The direct effect of the instrument is
positive and statistically significant, alleviating concerns that the null effect of the instrument in
the non-Airbnb sample is only because they are poorer and smaller than other zipcodes. Thus,
there does not appear to be any evidence that the instrument would be positively correlated with
house prices/rental rates, except through the effect on Airbnb.
Placebo test
As a final exercise, we follow Christian and Barrett (2017) to implement a form of randomization
inference to test whether the instrument is really exogenous or primarily driven by spurious time
trends. To do so, we keep constant touristiness, Google trends, the identity of zipcodes experiencing
23
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Airbnb entry, observable time-varying zipcode characteristics, housing market variables, and the
aggregate number of Airbnb listings in any year-month period. However, among the zipcodes with
positive Airbnb listings, we randomly swap the specific number of Airbnb listings across these
zipcodes. For example, we randomly assign to zipcode i the variable Airbnb
jct
(i.e., the Airbnb
counts of zipcode j for CBSA c in time t). The randomized regressor preserves the overall time
trends in the number of Airbnb listings but randomizes the identity of which zipcodes had how
much Airbnb growth and thus eliminates the impact of touristiness on the intensive margin of
Airbnb listings. If the results are primarily driven by a spurious time trends that interacts with
the extensive margin of whether there are any Airbnb listings, then this exercise will produce 2SLS
estimates that continue to be positively and statistically significant. Indeed, in their critique of
the Nunn and Qian (2014) instrument, Christian and Barrett (2017) perform this test and find
positive and statistically significant coefficients even using the randomized regressor. However, if
the effect of touristiness on the intensive margin of Airbnb listings is really what matters, as is our
argument, then the first-stage will become very weak when regressing the randomized regressor
on the instrument, leading to statistically insignificant estimates. Moreover, these estimates will
exhibit extremely large variance due to the weak first stage.
We estimate the 2SLS specification on this dataset for 1,000 draws of randomized allocations
of Airbnb listings among zipcodes that had positive Airbnb listings. We find that the measured
effect of Airbnb is statistically insignificant for over 99% of the randomized draws across our three
dependent variables, i.e., rent index, price index, and price-to-rent ratio, both in the main effect and
the interaction term with owner-occupancy rate. Figure 6 shows the distribution of the estimated
coefficients and the associated t-statistics that we estimate for both the main effect β , for each of the
three dependent variables.
23
As expected, the procedure produces a large variance of estimates that
are statistically insignificant. If spurious time trends were driving our results, we would expect the
Christian and Barrett (2017) procedure to give statistically significant estimates even when using
the randomized regressor.
24
The results of this test are therefore consistent with an instrument
that is exogenous.
23
Results for the interaction terms γ look similar but with a different sign.
24
See Figure 6 in Christian and Barrett (2017). In Appendix A, we discuss the test in greater detail using a Monte
Carlo simulation with both a valid and an invalid instrument and show that the results of this test we obtained with
our instrument are consistent with a valid instrument.
24
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Taken together, the preceding results paint a strong picture in support of the validity of our
instrument. We will therefore maintain this assumption for now, presenting results as though the
instrument were valid and discuss further threats to identification in Section 6.2.
6 Results
6.1 The effect of Airbnb on house prices and rents
We begin by reporting results in which Airbnb
ict
is measured as the natural log of one plus the
number of listings as measured by method 1 in Table 1.
25
Doing so, we estimate a specification
similar to that used in Zervas et al. (2017) and Farronato and Fradkin (2018) where the authors es-
timate the impact of Airbnb on the hotel industry. Therefore, our estimates represent the elasticity
of our dependent variables with respect to Airbnb supply.
In our main specifications, we consider three dependent variables: the natural log of the Zillow
Rent Index (ZRI), the natural log of the Zillow Home-Value Index (ZHVI), and the natural log of
the price-to-rent ratio (ZHVI/ZRI). In order to maintain our measure of touristiness, h
i,2010
, as a
pre-period variable, we only use data from 2011 to 2016. This time frame covers all of the period of
significant growth in Airbnb (see Figure 3). We also include only data from the 100 largest CBSAs,
as measured by 2010 population.
26
The data is monthly, so we deseasonalize all variables. Since the
regression in Equation 2 has two endogenous regressors (Airbnb
ict
and Airbnb
ict
× oorate
ic,2010
),
we use two instruments for the two-stage least squares estimation (g
t
× h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
×
oorate
ic,2010
).
Table 5 reports the regression results when the dependent variable is ln ZRI. Column 1 reports
the results from a simple OLS regression of ln ZRI on ln listings and no controls. Without controls,
a 1% increase in Airbnb listings is associated with a 0.1% increase in rental rates. Column 2 includes
zipcode and CBSA-year-month fixed effects. With the fixed effects, the estimated coefficient on
Airbnb declines by an order of magnitude. Column 3 includes the interaction of Airbnb listings
with the zipcode’s owner-occupancy rate. Column 3 shows the importance of controlling for owner-
25
We add one to the number of listings to avoid taking logs of zero. In Appendix B, we show that our results are
robust to dropping observations with 0 listings and using ln(listings) instead.
26
The 100 largest CBSAs constitute the majority of Airbnb listings (over 80%). In Appendix B, we show that our
results are robust to the inclusion of more CBSAs.
25
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
occupancy rate, as it significantly mediates the effect of Airbnb listings. Column 4 includes time-
varying zipcode level characteristics, including the ln total population, the ln median household
income, the share of 25-60 years old with Bachelors’ degrees or higher, and the employment rate.
Because these measures are not available at a monthly frequency, we linearly interpolate them to the
monthly level using ACS 5-year estimates from 2011 to 2016.
27
Column 4 shows that the results
are robust to the inclusion of these zipcode demographics. Finally, columns 5 and 6 report the
2SLS results using the instrumental variable with and without time-varying zipcode characteristics
as controls. Using the results from column 6 (our preferred specification), we estimate that a 1%
increase in Airbnb listings in zipcodes with the median owner-occupancy rate (72%) leads to a
0.018% increase in rents.The effect of Airbnb is significantly declining in the owner-occupancy rate.
At 56% owner-occupancy rate (the 25th percentile), the effect of a 1% increase in Airbnb listings
is to increase rents by 0.024%, and at 82% owner-occupancy rate (the 75th percentile), the effect
of a 1% increase in Airbnb listings is to increase rents by 0.014%.
Table 6 repeats the regressions with ln ZHVI as the dependent variable. As with the rental
rates, we find that controlling for owner-occupancy rate is very important as the estimated direct
effect of Airbnb listings increases by an order of magnitude when controlling for the interaction vs.
not. Further, including demographic controls still does not affect the results. Using the coefficients
reported in column 6 of Table 6, we estimate that a 1% increase in Airbnb listings leads to a 0.026%
increase in house prices for a zipcode with a median owner-occupancy rate. The effect increases
to 0.037% in zipcodes with an owner-occupancy rate equal to the 25th percentile and decreases to
0.019% in zipcodes with an owner-occupancy rate equal to the 75th percentile.
It is worth noting that in both the rental rate and house price regressions, the 2SLS estimates
(columns 5 and 6 of Tables 5 and 6) are about twice as large as the OLS estimates (columns 3 and 4
of Tables 5and 6). This goes against our initial intuition that omitted factors (such as gentrification)
are most likely to be positively correlated with both Airbnb listings and house prices/rents, thus
creating a positive bias. However, we note that the OLS estimate may also be negatively biased
or biased toward zero for two reasons. First, there may be measurement error in the true amount
of home-sharing, leading to attenuation bias. Measurement error may arise from the fact that we
only estimate the number of Airbnb listings, and we do not know their exact entry and exit, nor do
27
Results are not sensitive to different types of interpolations.
26
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
we know their availability for bookings. Measurement error may also arise from the fact that there
are other home-sharing platforms besides Airbnb that we do not measure.
28
Our estimate for the
number of listings is therefore a noisy measure of the true number of short-term rentals. Second,
simultaneity bias may be negative if higher rental rates in the long-term rental market would cause
a decrease in the number of Airbnb listings, ceteris paribus. This could happen if an increase in the
long-term rental rate causes fewer landlords to choose to supply the short-term market and more
to supply the long-term market.
Finally, Table 7 reports the regression results when ln ZHVI/ZRI is used as the dependent
variable. Column 6 shows that the effect of Airbnb listings on the price-to-rent ratio is positive,
and that, similarly to rents and prices, the effect is declining in owner-occupancy rate. At the
median owner-occupancy rate, a 1% increase in Airbnb listings leads to a statistically significant
0.01% increase in the price-to-rent ratio.
To summarize the results reported in Tables 5-7, we show that: 1) An increase in Airbnb listings
leads to both higher house prices and rental rates, 2) the effect is slightly higher for house prices
than it is for rental rates, and 3) the effect is decreasing in the zipcode’s owner-occupancy rate.
These results are consistent with the hypothesized effects of reallocation discussed in Section 3,
namely that Airbnb causes some landlords to reallocate housing from the long-term rental stock to
the short-term rental stock, pushing up prices and rents in the long-term market, and the effects
are attenuated in areas with more owner-occupiers because owner-occupier usage of Airbnb is less
likely to represent true reallocation. We provide further, more direct evidence of reallocation in
Section 6.4. The finding that the effect of Airbnb on price-to-rent ratio is positive suggests that
home-sharing may have increased homeowners’ option value for utilizing spare capacity. Finally, if
there are negative externalities generated by the use of Airbnb that spill over to house prices and
rental rates, they do not appear to be large enough to override the effects of reallocation.
28
Our results are robust, however, to the inclusion of controls reflecting the popularity of other home-sharing
websites like HomeAway and VRBO. We do so by using Google Trends index, a widely used proxy for demand in
several settings (Choi and Varian, 2012; Ghose, 2009; Li et al., 2016), as a proxy for demand for such platforms. We
report these results in Table 18 of Appendix B.
27
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
6.2 Threats to identification
As in any study using observational data without experimental variation, endogeneity is always a
concern. Even though we conducted a number of exercises in Section 5.1 that support the validity of
the instrument, one might still be concerned that the instrument is picking up spurious correlation.
In this section, we discuss three potential threats to our identification strategy, and provide evidence
that they do not affect our results.
Gentrification One may be concerned that post-2012, touristy and non-touristy zipcodes ex-
perienced differential trends in gentrification or neighborhood change. However, columns 5-6 of
Tables 5-7 show that the main results are unchanged by the inclusion of time-varying zipcode de-
mographic controls. Because the included demographic controls (population, household income,
share of college-educated, and employment rate) are fairly basic measurements of zipcode level eco-
nomic outcomes, they are likely to be highly correlated with other unobserved factors that affect
zipcode level housing markets such as local amenities or local labor market conditions. Therefore,
the fact that our results are not affected by these controls suggests that it is unlikely that the
instrument is correlated with other unobserved zipcode level factors that affect housing markets.
29
Tourism demand Another endogeneity concern would be that our instrument is actually picking
up changes in tourism demand, which would naturally increase the demand for space in more vs. less
touristy zipcodes and thus affect house prices and rents. A priori, we see no obvious reason to think
that, after controlling for city-year-month fixed effects, the time-variation in Google searches for
Airbnb should be correlated with aggregate tourism demand. Further, a simple comparison shows
that Google trends for Airbnb is uncorrelated with Google trends for other tourism-driven websites
(Figure 7). Despite this, we address this concern directly by controlling for various measures of
tourism demand. First, we control for annual counts of the number of food & accommodations
establishments in each zipcode as reported by the Census Bureau’s Zipcode Business Patterns data.
Second, we control for the total number of airport passengers arriving at each U.S. city each month
29
A related concern would be that demographics respond slowly to an underlying change in the desirability of
a neighborhood, but rental rates and prices respond more quickly. Then, contemporaneous measures of zipcode
demographics may not control for the unobserved factors. To account for this possibility, we try controlling for 1-year
ahead and 2-year ahead measures of zipcode demographics instead of contemporaneous measures and find that the
results are unchanged. We show these results in Appendix B.
28
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
and then allocate these arrivals to zipcodes based on the zipcode’s share of hotel rooms in each city.
Data on airport passengers come from the Bureau of Transportation Statistics and data on hotel
rooms come from STR, a company that tracks the hotel industry worldwide. Third, we control for
monthly hotel occupants in each zipcode using occupancy rates data we obtained from STR. STR
only provides the number of hotel occupants at the city level, so again we assign hotel occupants to
zipcodes based on the zipcode’s share of hotel rooms in each city. Finally, we control for the monthly
number of reviews written for accommodation properties (hotels, Inns, B&Bs) and restaurants in
each zipcode on the website TripAdvisor, a website specializing in reviews for tourist attractions,
restaurants, and accommodations. We report the results from these regressions in columns 1-4 and
6-9 of Table 8. We find that controlling for any of these factors does not change our main results,
either qualitatively or quantitatively, so it does not appear that unobserved changes to tourism
demand are driving spurious correlation in our estimates.
High and low-touristy zipcodes Finally, we rule out any differential effects between high- and
low- touristy zipcodes that are linear in time by directly controlling for the interaction of a linear
time trend with zipcode touristiness: t × h
i,2010
. The results are reported in columns 5 and 10 of
Table 8. The main results are robust even to the inclusion of these touristiness-specific time-trends.
The results reported in this section, combined with the exercises supporting the validity of
the instrument we discussed in Section 3, strongly support a causal interpretation of our main
estimates. Any potential confounder would have to (i) begin to differentially affect high- and
low-touristy zipcodes in 2012 (just when Airbnb started taking off), (ii) affect zipcodes with low
owner-occupancy rate more than zipcodes with high owner-occupancy rate, (iii) be uncorrelated
with house prices and rents in zipcodes that never had any Airbnb, but correlated with house prices
and rents in zipcodes that did—even among zipcodes that ex ante look demographically similar,
and (iv) it would have to be correlated over time with the Airbnb Google search index beyond the
linear time trend. Moreover, the potential confounder would have to be unrelated to changes in
zipcode demographic characteristics and unrelated to our measured changes in tourism demand.
While we cannot completely rule out the possibility of such a confounder, it does appear that most
of the plausible sources of spurious correlation are accounted for in our analysis.
29
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Finally, in the Appendix, we show that our results are robust to a number of sensitivity and
specification checks, such as using different measures of Airbnb supply and running the regression
on different subsamples of the data. For example, we show that our results hold for: (i) zipcodes
that are close and far from the city center, (ii) early (2011-2013) and late (2014-2016) time periods,
(iii) more or less populous cities, and (iv) different housing segments.
6.3 Effect magnitudes
In this section, we consider the economic significance of our estimated effects. Our baseline result
is that a 1% increase in Airbnb listings leads to a 0.018% increase in rents and a 0.026% increase
in house prices at a median owner-occupancy rate zipcode. The median year-on-year growth rate
in Airbnb listings was 28% across zipcodes in the top 100 CBSAs. Taken at the sample median,
then, Airbnb growth explains 0.5% in annual rent growth and 0.7% of annual price growth.
Another way to calculate effect size is to calculate the Airbnb contribution to year-over-year
rent and house price growth for each zipcode by multiplying median year-over-year changes in log
listings by the estimated coefficients
ˆ
β + ˆγ × oorate
i,2010
. We report these effects in Table 9 for the
median zipcodes in the 10 largest CBSAs as well as for the median zipcode in our sample of 100
largest CBSAs. We also include the average year-on-year rent and price growth for comparison.
While the size of the Airbnb contribution may seem large, we caution that estimating the effect at
the sample median masks substantial heterogeneity in the actual experiences of different zipcodes,
and ignores the very likely possibility of heterogeneous treatment effects, such as between different
quality segments of the housing market.
30
We also note that our estimated effects are consistent
with those found in Horn and Merante (2017) who study the effect of Airbnb on rents in Boston
from 2015-2016. They find that a one standard deviation increase in Airbnb listings leads to a
0.4% increase in rents. In our data, the within-CBSA standard deviation in log listings is 0.27 for
2015-2016, which at the median owner-occupancy rate implies a 0.54% increase in rents using our
estimates.
30
Our main results only speak to the effect of Airbnb on the median housing unit as we use median rents and
prices. In the Appendix, we explore the effects of Airbnb on other measures such as house prices separately for 1
through 4 bedroom homes, and rents for multifamily vs. single-family homes. The results are not very different from
each other, so we opt to only report median effects in the paper.
30
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
6.4 The effect of Airbnb on housing reallocation
In Section 6, we showed that Airbnb has a positive effect on house prices and rents and that this
effect is moderated by the owner-occupancy rate. This latter finding suggests that the effect of
Airbnb on the housing market is likely due to non owner-occupiers reallocating their properties
from the long- to the short-term rental market. As we explained in Section 3, assuming that the
total housing supply is inelastic in the short-run, this reallocation would decrease long-term supply,
thus increasing both rental rates and house prices.
In this section, we present direct evidence of this mechanism. To do so, we investigate the effect
of Airbnb on four measures of housing supply: (i) the number of homes that are vacant for seasonal
or recreational use, (ii) the number of homes vacant and for rent, (iii) the number of homes that
are rented to long-term tenants (renter-occupied units), and (iv) the total housing stock, which is
the sum of all renter-occupied, owner-occupied, and vacant units. We obtain this data from the
American Community Survey, an annual survey administered by the U.S. Census that randomly
samples individual housing units. Housing units that are found to be unoccupied, or occupied by
anyone who is not the usual resident (such as an Airbnb guest), are classified as vacant. The Census
then either asks the owner of the vacant unit (or the current occupant, or neighbors, if the owner
cannot be reached) why the unit is vacant. Thus, homes that are held vacant for use as short-
term rentals or are occupied by home-share guests at the time of the survey would be classified as
vacant for seasonal or recreational use. Homes that are vacant but in which the owner is seeking
a long-term tenant would be classified as vacant and for rent.
31
To summarize, short-term rental
properties would be contained in measure (i) while long-term rental properties are contained in
measures (ii) and (iii). Measure (iv) is the sum of all housing units.
We run regressions of the form given in equation (2) using the four housing supply variables
discussed above as dependent variables. One issue with this measure is that housing supply data
is not available at the zipcode level at a monthly frequency. We therefore have to use annual data,
so the time-period in the regressions is a year. Moreover, to smooth out annual fluctuations due
to sampling error, the ACS reports 5-year running averages of these variables. Therefore, there is
31
Other possible reasons for vacancy include being vacant and for sale, vacant for migrant workers, either rented
or sold but not yet occupied, or “other”. For more information, see the U.S. Census Bureau’s report titled “American
Commnunity Survey Design and Methodology (January 2014).
31
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
serial correlation in the dependent variable, which we account for by clustering standard errors at
the zipcode level.
If, as we hypothesized, the effect of Airbnb is mainly due to the reallocation effect discussed
above, then we would expect that Airbnb listings are associated with an increase in the short-term
rental supply (measure (i)) and with a decrease in long-term rental supply (measures (i) and (ii)).
Further, these changes should not be due to changes in the total housing supply. Thus, there should
not be any association between Airbnb listings and such variable (measure (iv)).
Table 10 reports the results of these regressions. Column 1 shows that higher Airbnb listings lead
to more homes that are vacant for seasonal or recreational use, which is consistent with an increase
in the short-term rental stock. Columns 2 and 3 show that higher Airbnb listings lead to fewer
homes that are vacant and for-rent and fewer homes that are renter occupied, which is consistent
with a decrease in the long-term rental stock. As with the results on rents and prices, the effects are
strongly moderated by the owner-occupancy rate of the zipcode with Airbnb having stronger effects
in zipcodes with fewer owner-occupiers. This makes sense because, as we discussed in Section 3,
non-owner-occupiers should be more likely than owner-occupiers to reallocate. Finally, there is no
short-run effect of Airbnb on the total supply of housing, which is consistent with housing supply
being very inelastic in the short-run (we did not test for long-run effects for reasons we discussed
in Section 3).
The results reported in this section provide strong evidence that are consistent with our hy-
pothesis that the effect of Airbnb is, at least in part, due to the reallocation of the housing stock
form the long- to the short term rental market.
7 Discussion & Conclusion
The results presented in this paper suggest that the increased ability to home-share has led to
increases in both rental rates and house prices. The increases in rental rates and house prices
occur through at least two channels. In the first channel, home-sharing increases rental rates by
inducing some landlords to switch from supplying the market for long-term rentals to supplying the
market for short-term rentals. The increase in rental rates through this channel is then capitalized
into house prices. In the second channel, home-sharing increases house prices directly by enabling
32
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
homeowners to generate income from excess housing capacity. This raises the value of owning
relative to renting and therefore increases the price-to-rent ratio directly.
The results of this paper contribute to the debate surrounding home-sharing and its impact on
the housing market. While Airbnb and proponents of the sharing economy argue that the platform
is not responsible for higher house prices and rental rates,
32
critics of home-sharing argue that
Airbnb does raise housing costs for local residents. This paper provides evidence supporting the
latter hypothesis, and it does so using the most comprehensive dataset about home-sharing in the
US available to date.
Moreover, by showing that the effects of Airbnb are moderated by the owner-occupancy rate,
this paper highlights the importance of the marginal homeowner in terms of reallocation (since
owner-occupiers may be less likely to reallocate their housing to the permanent short-term rental
stock). Thus, this paper demonstrates that the marginal propensity of homeowners to reallocate
housing from the long- to the short-term rental market is a key elasticity determining the overall
effect of home-sharing.
Turning to how cities and municipalities should deal with the steady increase in home-sharing,
our view is that regulations on home-sharing should (at most) seek to limit the reallocation of
housing stock from long-term rentals to short-term rentals without discouraging the use of home-
sharing by owner-occupiers. One regulatory approach could be to only levy occupancy tax on
home sharers who rent the entire home for an extended period of time or to require a proof of
owner-occupancy in order to avoid paying occupancy tax.
Of course, this research does not come without limitations. First, we must recognize that our
Airbnb data is imperfect: While we observe properties listed on Airbnb, we do not observe exact
entry and exit of these properties. However, using Airbnb proprietary data, Farronato and Fradkin
(2018) obtain very similar elasticity estimates to Zervas et al. (2017) who use a similar approach
to ours to obtain Airbnb data and measure Airbnb supply. This, along with our extensive set of
robustness checks, reassures us about the validity of our results.
Second, we need to keep in mind that in settings where the effects are likely to be heterogeneous,
a 2SLS estimate does not represent the Average Treatment Effect (ATE) but instead a Local
32
For example, Airbnb disputed the findings of a recent report on the effects of the platform on the housing
market in New York City. See: https://www.citylab.com/equity/2018/03/what-airbnb-did-to-new-york-city/
552749/.
33
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Average Treatment Effect (LATE) or the effect of Airbnb on the subset of “complier” zipcodes–those
zipcodes that are induced by the instrument to change the value of the endogenous regressor. Thus,
our estimates do not necessarily reflect the average effect of Airbnb on any zipcodes. Despite this
limitation, however, we estimate magnitudes that are similar to those obtained by Horn and Merante
(2017) for the city of Boston. Finally, our results do not take into account possible spillover effects
the neighboring zipcodes can have on each other.
To summarize the state of the literature on home-sharing, research (including this paper) has
found that home-sharing: 1) raises local rental rates by causing a reallocation of the housing stock,
2) raises house prices through both the capitalization of rents and the increased ability to use
excess capacity, and 3) induces market entry by small suppliers of short-term housing who compete
with traditional suppliers (Zervas et al., 2017). More research is needed, however, in order to
achieve a complete welfare analysis of home-sharing. For example, home-sharing may have positive
spillover effects on local businesses if it drives a net increase in tourism demand (Alyakoob and
Rahman, 2018). On the other hand, home-sharing may have negative spillover effects if tourists
create negative externalities such as noise or congestion for local residents (Filippas and Horton,
2018). Moreover, home-sharing introduces an interesting new mechanism for rapidly scaling down
the local housing supply in response to negative long-term demand shocks and a mechanism for
rapidly scaling up the short-term accommodations supply in response to a short-term demand serge
(Farronato and Fradkin, 2018). Understanding the full impact of such a mechanism on the housing
market is an open question to date. We leave these research questions for future work.
References
Alyakoob, Mohammed and Mohammad Rahman, “The Sharing Economy as a Local Eco-
nomic Engine: The Heterogeneous Impact of Airbnb on Restaurant Employment Growth,” Work-
ing Paper, Purdue University 2018.
Angrist, Josh, Sydnee Caldwell, and Jonathan Hall, “Uber versus taxi: A driver’s eye view,”
2017.
34
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Bartik, Timothy J., Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies?, Kala-
mazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 1991.
Chen, M. Keith, Judith A. Chevalier, Peter E. Rossi, and Emily Oehlsen, “The Value
of Flexible Work: Evidence from Uber Drivers,” Working Paper 23296, NBER 2017.
Choi, Hyunyoung and Hal Varian, “Predicting the present with Google Trends,” Economic
Record, 2012, 88, 2–9.
Christian, Paul and Christopher P. Barrett, “Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict:
A Methodological Caution,” Working Paper 8171, World Bank 2017.
Coles, Peter A., Michael Egesdal, Ingrid Gould Ellen, Xiaodi Li, and Arun Sundarara-
jan, “Airbnb Usage Across New York City Neighborhoods: Geographic Patterns and Regulatory
Implications,” Working Paper 3048397, SSRN 2017.
Diamond, Rebecca, “The Determinants and Welfare Implications of US WOrkers’ Diverging
Location Choices by Skill: 1980-2000,” American Economic Review, 2016, 106 (3), 479–524.
Dube, Oeindrila and Juan F Vargas, “Commodity price shocks and civil conflict: Evidence
from Colombia,” The Review of Economic Studies, 2013, 80 (4), 1384–1421.
Edelman, Benjamin G and Michael Luca, “Digital discrimination: The case of airbnb.com,”
Working Paper, Harvard Business School 2014.
Edelman, Benjamin, Michael Luca, and Dan Svirsky, “Racial discrimination in the sharing
economy: Evidence from a field experiment,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics,
2017, 9 (2), 1–22.
Einav, Liran, Chiara Farronato, and Jonathan Levin, “Peer-to-Peer Markets,” Annual Re-
view of Economics, October 2016, 8, 615–635.
Farronato, Chiara and Andrey Fradkin, “The welfare effects of peer entry in the accommo-
dation market: The case of airbnb,” Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research
2018.
35
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Filippas, Apostolos and John J. Horton, “The Tragedy of Your Upstairs Neighbors: Exter-
nalities of Home-Sharing,” Working Paper 2018.
Fradkin, Andrey, “Search frictions and the design of online marketplaces,” Working Paper,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology 2015.
, Elena Grewal, and David Holtz, “The determinants of online review informativeness:
Evidence from field experiments on Airbnb,” Technical Report, Working Paper 2017.
Ghose, Anindya, “Internet exchanges for used goods: An empirical analysis of trade patterns
and adverse selection,” Mis Quarterly, 2009, pp. 263–291.
Gong, Jing, Brad N. Greenwood, and Yiping Song, “Uber Might Buy Me a Mercedez Benz:
An Empirical Investigation of the Sharing Economy and Durable Goods Purchase,” Working
Paper, SSRN 2017.
Gyourko, Joseph and Raven Molloy, “Regulation and Housing Supply,” in Gilles Duranton,
J. Vernon Henderson, and William C. Strange, eds., Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics,
Vol. 5 of Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Elsevier, 2015, pp. 1289 1337.
Hall, Jonathan V. and Alan B. Krueger, “An Analysis of the Labor Market for Uber’s Driver-
Partners in the United States,” ILR Review, 2017.
Hanna, Rema and Paulina Oliva, “The effect of pollution on labor supply: Evidence from a
natural experiment in Mexico City,” Journal of Public Economics, 2015, 122, 68–79.
Horn, Keren and Mark Merante, “Is Home Sharing Driving Up Rents? Evidence from Airbnb
in Boston,” Journal of Housing Economics, 2017.
Horton, John J. and Richard J. Zeckhauser, “Owning, Using and Renting: Some Simple
Economics of the “Sharing Economy”,” Working Paper 22029, NBER 2016.
Kleibergen, Frank and Richard Paap, “Generalized Reduced Rank Tests Using the Singular
Value Decomposition,” Journal of Econometrics, 2006, 133 (1), 97–126.
36
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Kroft, Kory and Devin G Pope, “Does online search crowd out traditional search and improve
matching efficiency? Evidence from Craigslist,” Journal of Labor Economics, 2014, 32 (2), 259–
303.
Lee, Dayne, “How Airbnb Short-Term Rentals Exacerbate Los Angeles’s Affordable Housing
Crisis: Analysis and Policy Recommendations,” Harvard Law & Policy Review, 2016, pp. 229–
254.
Li, Hui and Kannan Srinivasan, “Competitive Dynamics in the Sharing Economy: An Analysis
in the Context of Airbnb and Hotels,” Marketing Science, 2019.
Li, Ziru, Yili Hong, and Zhongju Zhang, “An empirical analysis of on-demand ride sharing
and traffic congestion,” in “Proc. International Conference on Information Systems” 2016.
Martin, Gregory J. and Ali Yurukoglu, “Bias in Cable News: Persuasion and Polarization,”
American Economic Review, 2017, 107 (9), 2565–2599.
Nunn, Nathan and Nancy Qian, “US food aid and civil conflict,” American Economic Review,
2014, 104 (6), 1630–66.
Peri, Giovanni, “The effect of immigration on productivity: Evidence from US states,” Review
of Economics and Statistics, 2012, 94 (1), 348–358.
Poterba, James M., “Tax Subsidies to Owner-Occupied Housing: An Asset-Market Approach,”
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1984, 99 (4), 729–752.
Proserpio, Davide and Gerard Tellis, “Baring the Sharing Economy: Concepts, Classification,
Findings, and Future Directions,” Working Paper, 2017.
, Wendy Xu, and Georgios Zervas, “You Get What You Give: Theory and Evidence of
Reciprocity in the Sharing Economy,” 2017.
Seamans, Robert and Feng Zhu, “Responses to entry in multi-sided markets: The impact of
Craigslist on local newspapers,” Management Science, 2013, 60 (2), 476–493.
Zervas, Georgios, Davide Proserpio, and John Byers, “A first look at online reputation on
Airbnb, where every stay is above average,” 2015.
37
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
, , and John W. Byers, “The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating the Impact of
Airbnb on the Hotel Industry,” Journal of Marketing Research, 2017, 54 (5), 687–705.
38
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 1: Google Trends Search Index for Airbnb (Worldwide, 2008-2017)
0 20 40 60 80 100
Google Trends Index
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Google Trends Seasonally adjusted
Note: Monthly Google Trends index for the single English search term “Airbnb”, from any searches
worldwide. Google Trends data are normalized so that the date with the highest search volume is
given the value of 100. Seasonal adjustment is done using a local polynomial smoother.
39
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 2: Map of Airbnb Listings by Zipcode, 2011-2016
Note: The figure shows the spatial distribution of Airbnb listings in June 2011 and June 2016,
where the number of listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. Listings are reported in logs,
and log listings is set to zero if there are zero listings. Geographic areas without zipcode boundary
information are colored white.
40
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 3: Total Number of Airbnb Listings (US, 2008-2016)
100,000
200,000
300,000
Jan 2008 Jan 2010 Jan 2012 Jan 2014 Jan 2016
Airbnb Supply
250,000
500,000
750,000
1,000,000
Jan 2008 Jan 2010 Jan 2012 Jan 2014 Jan 2016
Airbnb Supply
(a) (b) (a)
Note: This figure plots the number of Airbnb listings over time, using each of the 3 methods
described in Table 1: (a) method 1 cumulative supply, (b) method 2 TTL = 3 months, (c)
method 3 TTL = 6 months.
Figure 4: Testing the IV Operating Assumption
0
50
100
0 25 50 75 100
Google trends
Difference in Airbnb listings between
high− and low−touristness zipcodes
Note: This figure plots the difference in the number of Airbnb listings for high- and low-touristiness
zipcodes over the Google trend values. We use the sample median value of touristiness to create
two equally sized groups of high- and low-touristiness zipcodes.
41
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 5: Trends in Zillow Home Value Index by “Touristiness” of Zipcode
-.1 0 .1 .2 .3
log ZHVI (Baseline: Jan 2011)
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
1 2 3 4
Quartile for touristiness in 2010
Zillow Home Value Index
-.02 -.01 0 .01 .02
Residuals (Baseline: Jan 2011)
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
1 2 3 4
Quartile for touristiness in 2010
Zillow Home Value Index (residuals)
Note: The top panel plots the ZHVI index, normalized to January 2011=0, averaged within different groups
of zipcodes based on their level of “touristiness” in 2010. Touristiness is measured as the number of estab-
lishments in the food services and accommodations sector (NAICS code 72) in 2010, and the zipcodes are
separated into four equally sized groups. The bottom panel plots the residuals from a regression of the ZHVI
on zipcode fixed effects and CBSA-month fixed effects.
42
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 6: Christian and Barrett (2017) Exercise Results
-20 -10 0 10 20 30
coefficient
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
density
DV: ln ZRI
Main Effect (coefficient)
CB coefs 2SLS coef = 0.044
-100 -50 0 50 100
coefficient
0
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
density
DV: ln ZHVI
Main Effect (coefficient)
CB coefs 2SLS coef = 0.077
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2
coefficient
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
density
DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
Main Effect (coefficient)
CB coefs 2SLS coef = 0.032
0 5 10 15
t-stat
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
density
DV: ln ZRI
Main Effect (t-stat)
CB t-stat 2SLS t-stat = 14.7
0 5 10 15
t-stat
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
density
DV: ln ZHVI
Main Effect (t-stat)
CB t-stat 2SLS t-stat = 15.4
0 2 4 6 8 10
t-stat
0
0.5
1
1.5
density
DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
Main Effect (t-stat)
CB t-stat 2SLS t-stat = 8.0
Note: This figure shows the distribution of the t-statistics for both the main coefficient on Airbnb and the
coefficient on the interaction term Airbnb × oorate for our three dependent variables using the Christian and
Barrett (2017) randomized regressors described in Section 5.1.
43
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 7: Google Trends Index for Related Websites (Worldwide, 2008-2019)
0 20 40 60 80 100
Google Trends Index
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
Airbnb VRBO
HomeAway TripAdvisor
Expedia
Note: Monthly Google Trends index for various tourism related websites, from any searches world-
wide. Google Trends data are normalized so that the highest search volume over all the compared
terms and time-periods is equal to 100.
44
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 2: Size of Airbnb Relative to the Housing Stock (zipcodes, 100 largest CBSAs)
p10 p25 p50 p75 p90
June 2011
Airbnb Listings 0 0 0 2 7
Housing Units 1,058 2,813 7,437 12,829 18,037
Airbnb Listings as a Percentage of
Total Housing Units .00 .00 .00 .02 .09
Renter-occupied Units .00 .00 .00 .06 .33
Vacant Units .00 .00 .00 .20 .92
Vacant-for-rent Units .00 .00 .00 1.01 5.06
June 2016
Airbnb Listings 1 4 13 44 144
Housing Units 1,097 2,926 7,610 13,219 18,443
Airbnb Listings as a Percentage of
Total Housing Units .03 .08 .21 .60 1.88
Renter-occupied Units .13 .33 .87 2.50 7.31
Vacant Units .37 .99 2.63 7.19 20.00
Vacant-for-rent Units 1.72 4.65 13.70 42.80 129.00
Note: This table reports the size of Airbnb relative to the housing stock by zipcodes for the 100 largest
CBSAs as measured by 2010 population. The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in
Table 1. Data on housing stocks, occupancy characteristics, and vacancies come from ACS zipcode level
5-year estimates.
45
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 3: IV Validity Check: Correlation Between Instrument and Rents/Prices in Zipcodes Without
Airbnb
Sample: Zipcodes Sample: Zipcodes Sample: Propensity-Score
w/o Airbnb ever w/ some Airbnb matched sample w/ Airbnb
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI
g
t
× h
i,2010
1.63E06 3.92E06 3.17E06*** 5.38E06*** 9.88E06*** 8.77E06*
(3.17E06) (4.48E06) (2.22E07) (3.43E07) (3.46E06) (4.52E06)
ln Population 0.011 0.045*** 0.055*** 0.087*** 0.052*** 0.077***
(0.013) (0.016) (0.007) (0.011) (0.019) (0.029)
ln Median HH Income 0.002 0.001 0.027*** 0.017* 0.013 0.008
(0.011) (0.016) (0.006) (0.009) (0.015) (0.023)
College Share 0.054* 0.120*** 0.057*** 0.058*** 0.052 0.053
(0.032) (0.038) (0.014) (0.020) (0.034) (0.063)
Employment Rate 0.045 0.017 0.044*** 0.126*** 0.011 0.133**
(0.031) (0.033) (0.015) (0.023) (0.036) (0.060)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 61854 50875 587141 520797 51800 42082
R
2
0.979 0.994 0.992 0.996 0.982 0.993
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: This table reports regression results when outcomes of interest are regressed on the instrumental variable
directly for three samples of zipcodes: 1) zipcodes that were never observed to have any Airbnb listings, 2) zipcodes
that were observed at some point to have Airbnb listings, and 3) zipcodes that had Airbnb listings and were propensity-
score matched to zipcodes that did not have Airbnb listings. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not
available at a monthly frequency, zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and
employment rate are interpolated from the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the
zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
46
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 4: Comparing Airbnb and Non-Airbnb Zipcodes
Sample: Zipcodes Sample: Zipcodes Sample: Propensity-Score
w/o Airbnb w/ some Airbnb matched sample w/ Airbnb
Touristiness 7.40 43.73*** 7.34
ln Median Income 10.90 11.05*** 10.90
ln Population 8.25 9.44*** 8.28
College Share 0.19 0.34*** 0.19
Employment Rate 0.72 0.73*** 0.72
# Zipcodes 999 9356 999
Note: This table reports mean zipcode characteristics from three samples: 1) zipcodes that were never observed to
have any Airbnb listings, 2) zipcodes that were observed at some point to have Airbnb listings, and 3) zipcodes that
had Airbnb listings and were propensity-score matched to zipcodes that did not have Airbnb listings. *** indicates
that the difference in means compared to the non-Airbnb sample is statistically significant with p<0.01.
Table 5: The Effect of Airbnb on Rental Rates
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.098*** 0.008*** 0.022*** 0.021*** 0.046*** 0.044***
(0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.003) (0.003)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.023*** 0.022*** 0.038*** 0.036***
(0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)
ln Population 0.050*** 0.042***
(0.007) (0.007)
ln Median HH Income 0.021*** 0.017***
(0.005) (0.006)
College Share 0.063*** 0.057***
(0.013) (0.013)
Employment Rate 0.048*** 0.036***
(0.014) (0.014)
Zipcode FE No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable No No No No Yes Yes
Observations 649841 649841 649841 649697 649841 649697
R
2
0.169 0.991 0.991 0.991 0.991 0.991
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 820.0 807.0
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. To avoid taking the log of a zero,
one is added to the number of Airbnb listings before taking logs. The instrumental variables are g
t
× h
i,2010
and
g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
47
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 6: The Effect of Airbnb on House Prices
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.175*** 0.009*** 0.040*** 0.038*** 0.080*** 0.077***
(0.004) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.005) (0.005)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.048*** 0.046*** 0.074*** 0.071***
(0.003) (0.003) (0.006) (0.006)
ln Population 0.077*** 0.063***
(0.010) (0.010)
ln Median HH Income 0.012 0.005
(0.008) (0.008)
College Share 0.073*** 0.061***
(0.018) (0.018)
Employment Rate 0.099*** 0.070***
(0.020) (0.020)
Zipcode FE No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable No No No No Yes Yes
Observations 572858 572858 572858 572805 572858 572805
R
2
0.188 0.996 0.996 0.996 0.996 0.996
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 661.9 646.7
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. To avoid taking the log of a zero,
one is added to the number of Airbnb listings before taking logs. The instrumental variables are g
t
× h
i,2010
and
g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
48
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 7: The Effect of Airbnb on Price-to-Rent Ratio
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.077*** 0.002** 0.016*** 0.015*** 0.032*** 0.032***
(0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004) (0.004)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.022*** 0.022*** 0.032*** 0.032***
(0.003) (0.003) (0.005) (0.005)
ln Population 0.030*** 0.025**
(0.010) (0.010)
ln Median HH Income 0.013 0.016*
(0.009) (0.009)
College Share 0.011 0.006
(0.019) (0.019)
Employment Rate 0.046** 0.034
(0.022) (0.022)
Zipcode FE No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable No No No No Yes Yes
Observations 537157 537142 537142 537089 537142 537089
R
2
0.154 0.979 0.979 0.979 0.979 0.979
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 629.8 616.9
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. To avoid taking the log of a zero,
one is added to the number of Airbnb listings before taking logs. The instrumental variables are g
t
× h
i,2010
and
g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
49
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 8: Controlling for Measures of Tourism Demand
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.040*** 0.044*** 0.044*** 0.044*** 0.044*** 0.071*** 0.078*** 0.077*** 0.085*** 0.046***
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.006) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.008)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.034*** 0.035*** 0.036*** 0.036*** 0.036*** 0.069*** 0.071*** 0.071*** 0.076*** 0.056***
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006)
ln Population 0.043*** 0.044*** 0.041*** 0.042*** 0.042*** 0.069*** 0.071*** 0.063*** 0.062*** 0.073***
(0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010)
ln Median HH Income 0.018*** 0.018*** 0.018*** 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.003 0.004 0.005 0.005 0.006
(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008)
College Share 0.052*** 0.055*** 0.056*** 0.057*** 0.057*** 0.053*** 0.057*** 0.061*** 0.060*** 0.066***
(0.014) (0.014) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.018) (0.019) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018)
Employment Rate 0.038*** 0.038*** 0.037*** 0.036*** 0.036** 0.079*** 0.078*** 0.071*** 0.067*** 0.087***
(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020)
Food & Accommodations Estabs. 3.48E04*** 5.83E04***
(7.15E05) (1.25E04)
ln Hotel Occupancy 4.83E04*** 4.31E04
(1.83E04) (2.77E04)
ln Airport Travelers (arrivals) 3.36E04*** 1.37E04
(1.18E04) (1.79E04)
# Trip Advisor Reviews 1.38E07 3.58E05***
(3.55E06) (1.08E05)
t × h
i,2010
7.94E08 3.58E06***
(9.31E07) (1.07E06)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 639400 639400 648905 649697 649697 564157 564157 572085 572805 572805
R
2
0.991 0.991 0.991 0.991 0.991 0.996 0.996 0.996 0.996 0.996
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 650.0 761.5 802.8 791.9 167.1 516.1 611.9 642.5 579.2 218.3
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. To avoid taking the log of a zero,
one is added to the number of Airbnb listings before taking logs. The instrumental variables are g
t
× h
i,2010
and
g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
50
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 9: Effect Magnitudes for 10 Largest CBSAs
Year-over-Year Airbnb Year-over-Year
Contribution Growth
CBSA Rent Price Rent Price
Top 100 CBSAs 0.59% 0.82% 3.18% 5.70%
New York-Newark-Jersey City, NY-NJ-PA 0.60% 0.83% 3.64% 3.55%
Los Angeles-Long Beach-Anaheim, CA 1.14% 1.79% 4.92% 9.66%
Chicago-Naperville-Elgin, IL-IN-WI 0.34% 0.44% 2.25% 3.98%
Dallas-Fort Worth-Arlington, TX 0.70% 1.01% 4.18% 8.21%
Miami-Fort Lauderdale-West Palm Beach, FL 1.02% 1.51% 4.51% 11.72%
Philadelphia-Camden-Wilmington, PA-NJ-DE-MD 0.54% 0.73% 1.94% 2.05%
Houston-The Woodlands-Sugar Land, TX 0.95% 1.37% 4.67% 8.34%
Washington-Arlington-Alexandria, DC-VA-MD-WV 0.70% 0.96% 1.28% 4.41%
Atlanta-Sandy Springs-Roswell, GA 0.75% 1.07% 3.11% 8.42%
Detroit-Warren-Dearborn, MI 0.16% 0.21% 2.41% 8.54%
Note: Airbnb contribution is calculated as
ˆ
β + ˆγoorate
ic,2010
multiplied by the median year-over-year growth
in log Airbnb listings for each zipcode, and then taken at the median zipcode. Estimates from columns 6 of
Tables 5 and 6 are used.
51
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 10: The Effect of Airbnb on Housing Supply
(1) (2) (3) (4)
ln Vacant Seasonal ln Vacant For-Rent ln Rental Stock ln Housing Stock
ln Airbnb Listings 0.078*** 0.048* 0.036*** 0.002
(0.025) (0.025) (0.006) (0.002)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.018 0.045* 0.053*** 0.002
(0.032) (0.027) (0.005) (0.003)
ln Population 0.212*** 0.225*** 0.871*** 0.547***
(0.055) (0.079) (0.032) (0.019)
ln Median HH Income 0.051 0.151*** 0.457*** 0.074***
(0.046) (0.055) (0.026) (0.011)
College Share 0.016 0.052 0.177*** 0.100***
(0.116) (0.152) (0.066) (0.024)
Employment Rate 0.093 0.465*** 0.315*** 0.146***
(0.123) (0.152) (0.068) (0.033)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 49282 49580 61435 61720
R
2
0.913 0.927 0.993 0.999
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 742.4 587.2 1082.9 1099.4
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: Definitions of the dependent variables are given in Section 6.4. The number of Airbnb listings is calculated
using method 1 in Table 1. To avoid taking the log of a zero, one is added to the number of Airbnb listings before
taking logs. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parentheses.
52
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
For Online Publication: Appendix
A Monte Carlo Simulation of Placebo Test
In Section 5.1, we describe the test proposed by Christian and Barrett (2017) (CB exercise) in
which a randomized regressor is constructed by keeping the identity of which zipcodes had non-zero
Airbnb listings but swapping the actual number of Airbnb listings across zipcodes. The randomized
regressor preserves the overall time trends in the number of Airbnb listings but randomizes the
intensive margin of Airbnb growth experienced by each zipcode, thus eliminating the impact of
touristiness on the intensive margin of Airbnb listings. If the results are primarily driven by
spurious time trends that interact with the extensive margin of Airbnb listings, then the exercise
will produce 2SLS estimates that continue to be positive and statistically significant. This is what
happens when Christian and Barrett (2017) apply their exercise to the Nunn and Qian (2014)
instrument for U.S. Food Aid, which they were critiquing. In our case, if the effect of touristiness
on the intensive margin of Airbnb listings is what really matters, then the first-stage will become
very weak when regressing the randomized regressor on the instrument. The weak first stage results
in a high variance of second stage estimates when performing 2SLS using the randomized regressor
and statistically insignificant estimates.
Here, we demonstrate using a Monte Carlo simulation with an instrument that is known to
be valid. We will show that the CB exercise leads to a large variance of point estimates that are
statistically insignificant. Consider a model in which X
it
is our endogenous explanatory regressor
and Y
it
is our outcome of interest. The causal relation is:
Y
it
= βX
it
+
it
(3)
and X
it
is a non-negative regressor given by:
X
it
=
γ
0
+ γ
1
H
i
× G
t
+ ν
it
if c
it
= 0
0 if c
it
= 1
(4)
The censoring indicator, c
it
, controls whether X
it
is zero. For simplicity, we assume that γ
0
is large
53
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
enough so that X
it
> 0 when c
it
= 0. Crucially, we assume that:
P (c
it
= 1) =
1
1 + exp(3 + ν
it
)
(5)
so that c
it
, which controls the extensive margin of X
it
, is exogenous to H
i
× G
t
but endogenous to
ν
it
. c
it
is analogous to whether the zipcode i had zero Airbnb listings in time t.
To induce correlation between X
it
and
it
, which necessitates an instrument, we introduce a
spurious time trend D
t
, which interacts with H
i
, that simultaneously affects ν
it
and
it
:
ν
it
= θD
t
× H
i
+ ξ
it
(6)
it
= φD
t
× H
i
+ η
it
(7)
We simulate the above system using β = 1, γ
0
= 10, γ
1
= θ = φ = 1 . We draw H
i
, G
i
, D
t
, ξ
it
,
and η
it
from iid standard normal distributions, which implies that E [
it
|H
i
× G
t
] = 0 and thus
Z
it
= H
i
× G
t
is a valid instrument for X
it
.
To summarize this model, Y
it
is analogous to rent, X
it
is analogous to Airbnb, H
i
is analogous
to touristiness, and G
t
is analogous to the Google trends. In the Monte Carlo, X
it
is endogenous
through the correlation between ν
it
and
it
, which is driven by a spurious time trend that interacts
with touristiness: D
t
× H
i
.
OLS estimation of equation (3) results in a biased estimate of
ˆ
β
OLS
= 1.151
∗∗∗
(0.002). 2SLS
estimation of equation (3) using Z
it
= H
i
× G
t
as the instrument for X
it
results in an estimate of
ˆ
β
IV
= 0.993
∗∗∗
(0.007). The true parameter, β = 1, is contained in the 95% confidence interval of
the 2SLS estimate, which is expected since Z
it
is known to be a valid instrument.
We then perform the CB exercise using the simulated data, which essentially amounts to ran-
domly swapping X
it
among the i’s with c
it
= 0, without changing any other variables. We do this
500 times. The top left panel of Figure 8 plots the density of the resulting estimates along with
the baseline 2SLS estimate from the non-randomized Monte-Carlo data. The variance of the CB
estimates is very large and the 2SLS estimate for β as well as the true parameter are well within
the 5th-95th-percentile-range of the CB estimates. For comparison, in the top right panel of Figure
8, we reproduce the same plot using the data from our paper when the dependent variable is ln
54
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
ZRI. We can observe that the results of the CB exercise using our data and our instrument are
very similar to those obtained with a valid simulated instrument.
The bottom left panel of Figure 8 then shows the density of the t-statistics of the CB estimates
using the Monte Carlo data along with the t-stat of the baseline 2SLS estimate. In the bottom
right panel, we reproduce the same plot using the data from our paper. As before, we observe that
the results of the CB exercise using the data from our paper is very simlar to those obtained in the
Monte Carlo with a valid simulated instrument; that is, the t-stats in the CB exercise are small and
centered around zero, whereas the t-stat of the main 2SLS estimate is large and implies statistical
significance.
Finally, we use our Monte Carlo simulation to explore what happens when we use an invalid
instrument. We note that
˜
Z
it
= D
t
× H
i
will be correlated with
it
through a spurious time trend
and is thus not a valid instrument. Indeed, when we perform 2SLS using
˜
Z
it
as an instrument for
X
it
, we estimate
ˆ
β
invalidIV
= 1.671
∗∗∗
(0.006), which is not close to the true parameter. Moreover,
˜
Z
it
, by design, affects the extensive margin of X
it
, and therefore we expect to find statistically
significant estimates when we perform the CB randomization. The top left panel of Figure 9 shows
the resulting coefficient estimates from the CB exercise, and indeed they are shifted to the right of
main estimate with non-randomized data. Moreover, the bottom left panel shows the t-stats of the
CB exercise and shows that all of the CB estimates are statistically significant. These results are
consistent with what Christian and Barrett (2017) show in Figure 6 of their paper (reproduced in
the top right panel of Figure 9), which they use as an argument for the invalidity of the instrument
they are critiquing.
Given these results, our conclusion is that, given a valid instrument, the CB exercise should
produce estimates with a very large variance that encompasses the baseline estimate, and such
estimates should be statistically insignificant. These are exactly the results we obtain using our
data and instrument.
55
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
B Robustness Checks
Alternative measures of Airbnb supply
In this Appendix, we show that our results are robust to a number of specification and sensitivity
checks. First, we show that our main results are robust to alternative methods of calculating Airbnb
supply. As discussed in Section 4, we can never know the exact number of active Airbnb listings at
any given point in time, and we therefore construct Airbnb supply using the three methods of Table
1. In Table 11, we report regression results when methods 2 and 3 are used to measure Airbnb
supply instead of method 1. The results are barely changed, which is not surprising given the high
correlation between the three measures, despite level differences.
In our main results, we use a log-log specification to measure the effect of Airbnb listings
on house prices and rental rates because such specification provides us with easily interpretable
coefficients in the form of elasticity that is often used in competitive settings and has been used
in the past in the context of Airbnb (Zervas et al., 2017; Farronato and Fradkin, 2018). However,
as Zervas et al. (2017) observe, the log-log specification implies constant elasticity, an assumption
that might not hold in our setting. To make sure that our results are not driven by the log-log
choice, we use an alternative specification in which Airbnb
ict
in equation (2) is measured as the
number of Airbnb listings divided by the total occupied housing stock.
33
We call this measure
“Airbnb density. One of the downsides of the log-density specification is that Airbnb density is
extremely skewed
34
, and using g
t
× h
i,2010
as the instrument, the first stage becomes very weak
and we fail to reject underidentification.
35
We therefore report results using an augmented set of
instruments. First, we try g
t
× h
i,2010
/stock
i,2010
interacted with oorate
i,2010
, where stock
i,2010
is
the total occupied housing stock in 2010. Second, we try a third order polynomial of g
t
× h
i,2010
(our original instrument), interacted with oorate
i,2010
. Third, we try fully interacted second order
polynomials of g
t
, h
i,2010
, and oorate
i,2010
. We report the results in Table 12. The main results hold
qualitatively: (i) higher Airbnb density leads to higher house prices and rental rates, (ii) the effect
is higher for house prices than for rental rates, and (iii) the effect is decreasing in owner-occupancy
33
Data on total occupied housing stock is from ACS 5-year estimates from 2011 to 2016.
34
The skewness is 129.58 compared to a mean of 0.007 and variance of 0.06.
35
In the rent regression, an underidentification test using the Kleibergen and Paap (2006) rk LM statistic fails to
reject underidentification with a p-value of 0.6650.
56
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
rate. However, the coefficients are somewhat sensitive to the choice of instruments. Thus, the
log-log specification, which has proven to be very robust, remains our preferred specification.
Finally, recall that in our main specification we added one to the number of Airbnb listings to
avoid taking logs of zero. We now show that the results are robust to this choice. Table 13 reports
regression results when instead of adding one to the number of listings, we instead simply drop
all zipcode-year-month observations in which the number of listings is zero. We also try dropping
all observations where the number of listings is less than 5. The results remain qualitatively and
quantitatively similar to the main results, suggesting both that adding one to the number of Airbnb
listings does not affect the results but also that the results are not primarily being driven by zipcodes
with very few Airbnb listings.
Heterogeneous effects across subsamples
We now test whether the results are heterogeneous or homogeneous across various subsamples of
our data. We find that the effects may be heterogeneous but that the main qualitative result that
Airbnb has a positive effect on prices and rents and is moderated by the owner-occupancy rate
holds across subsamples.
First, we test whether Airbnb has different effects by distance to the city-center. We run the
2SLS regressions for two subsamples: the sample of zipcodes below the median distance to the city
center, and the sample of zipcodes above the median distance to the city center, where the median
is taken within CBSA. The results are reported in Table 14. The qualitative results hold in both
the near and far samples, though it seems that the effects are actually larger in the far group. This
confirms that the results are not being solely driven by a few zipcodes close to downtown areas and
that home-sharing is having an impact even on zipcodes that are further from the city center.
Second, we test whether Airbnb has different effects in two time periods: 2011-2013 and 2014-
2016. The results are reported in Table 15. Again, the main qualitative results can be seen in
both time periods though the effect of owner-occupancy rate seems to be a lot weaker in the earlier
period than in the later period, and the results on price-to-rent ratio are not significant in the
earlier period. We speculate that this could be due to the possibility that Airbnb first attracted
those users with spare rooms or houses not in the long-term market (i.e., vacation homes) and that
only recently did Airbnb become an attractive option for landlords that previously rented in the
57
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
long-term market.
Third, we repeat the regressions separately for the 30 largest CBSAs and for the CBSAs ranked
31-100 in terms of 2010 population. Table 16 reports the results. The qualitative results hold for
both samples, though the results are not statistically significant in the rank 31-100 sample when
the dependent variable is price-to-rent ratio. The effects of Airbnb appear to be stronger in the
larger cities, which could be driven by a number of factors, including differences in housing demand
and the tightness of the rental market.
Effects on subsegments of the housing market
Now we test whether Airbnb has different effects on different subsegments of the housing market.
In our main regressions, we used the ZRI and the ZHVI for our dependent variables, both of which
measure the median rent/home value for the stock of homes in a zipcode. Thus, the results do
not speak to whether or not Airbnb can have differential effects on different quality segments of
the housing market. To test this, we now run the regressions using six additional rent and price
measures. For rents, Zillow provides a separate index for rentals of multifamily and single-family
units. For prices, Zillow provides a separate house price index for homes with 1, 2, 3, and 4
bedrooms (including both condos and single-family detached units.) The results are reported in
Table 17. The results show that the effects are not too different across different subsegments of the
housing market.
Additional tests
Now we show that our results are robust to the inclusion of the Google Trends index for other
tourism-based websites interacted with baseline touristiness. This is an extension of the controls
for tourism discussed in Section 6.2 and also addresses the extent to which our results reflect home-
sharing in total or primarily the effect of Airbnb (though it is hard to fully separate as many listings
are cross-listed across multiple platforms and Google searches are not a perfect proxy for actual
usage.) Table 18 shows these results and shows that our results are robust to the inclusion of any
of these controls.
Finally, we show that our results are robust to using forward-looking measures of zipcode
demographics. This addresses the concern that house prices and rental rates adjust more quickly
58
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
than demographic composition. In Table 19, we control for contemporaneous, 1-year ahead, and
2-year ahead measures of demographic characteristics. The results are robust to either choice. Note
that when we use the 2-year ahead demographic variables, the results look more like the results
from the 2011-2013 sample in Table 15 because we only use data up to 2014 since our demographic
variables are only measured until 2016. Thus, the differences in controlling for 1-year ahead and
2-year ahead demographic variables can be attributed more to changes to the sample than the
choice of when to measure the demographics.
59
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 8: Monte Carlo Results for CB Exercise Using Valid Instrument, Compared with Our Paper
-2000 -1000 0 1000 2000 3000
coefficient
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
density
10
-3
MC Simulation w Valid Instrument
Estimated Coefficients
CB values Baseline value = 0.9928
-30 -20 -10 0 10 20 30 40
coefficient
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
density
Our data and instrument
DV:ZRI, Main Effect Coefficients
CB values Baseline value = 0.0440
0 50 100 150
t-stat
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
density
MC Simulation w Valid Instrument
t-stats
CB values Baseline value = 135.9055
-5 0 5 10 15
t-stat
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
density
Our data and instrument
DV:ZRI, Main Effect t-stats
CB values Baseline value = 14.6667
Note: The Christian and Barrett (2017) exercise is described in Section 5.1 of the paper and Appendix A.
The top left panel shows the distribution of CB estimates along with the main 2SLS estimate using the
non-randomized Monte Carlo data. The top right panel reproduces this using the data from the paper when
ln ZRI is the dependent variable. The bottom left panel shows the distribution of the t-stats of the CB
estimates along with the t-stat of the main 2SLS estimate using the non-randomized Monte Carlo data. The
bottom right panel reproduces this using data from the paper.
60
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Figure 9: Monte Carlo Results for CB Exercise Using Invalid Instrument, Compared with Christian
and Barrett (2017)
1.6 1.8 2 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3 3.2 3.4
coefficient
0
5
10
15
density
MC Simulation w Invalid Instrument
Estimated Coefficients
CB values Baseline value= 1.6712
50 100 150 200 250 300
t-stat
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
density
MC Simulation w Invalid Instrument
t-stats
CB values Baseline value= 292.1381
Christian and Barret (2017)
Figure 6 (Invalid Instrument)
Note: The Christian and Barrett (2017) exercise is described in Section 5.1 of the paper and Appendix A.
The top left panel shows the distribution of CB estimates along with the main 2SLS estimate using the non-
randomized Monte-Carlo data, when the instrument is not valid (the Monte Carlo simulation is described
in Appendix A). The bottom left panel shows the distribution of the t-stats. The top right panel shows the
distribution of CB estimates from Christian and Barrett (2017) produced using data from Nunn and Qian
(2014). The red line labeled “NQ” is the main 2SLS estimate from Nunn and Qian (2014).
61
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 11: 2SLS Results with Alternative Measures of Airbnb Supply
Airbnb Measure: Method 2 Airbnb Measure: Method 3
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
ln Airbnb Listings 0.048*** 0.088*** 0.037*** 0.049*** 0.088*** 0.036***
(0.003) (0.006) (0.005) (0.003) (0.006) (0.005)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.040*** 0.083*** 0.038*** 0.041*** 0.085*** 0.038***
(0.004) (0.008) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.006)
ln Population 0.045*** 0.067*** 0.026** 0.044*** 0.066*** 0.026**
(0.007) (0.010) (0.010) (0.007) (0.010) (0.010)
ln Median HH Income 0.015*** 0.000 0.018** 0.016*** 0.002 0.017*
(0.006) (0.008) (0.009) (0.006) (0.008) (0.009)
College Share 0.053*** 0.052*** 0.002 0.055*** 0.056*** 0.004
(0.013) (0.018) (0.019) (0.013) (0.018) (0.019)
Employment Rate 0.035** 0.065*** 0.032 0.035** 0.066*** 0.032
(0.014) (0.020) (0.022) (0.014) (0.020) (0.022)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 649697 572805 537089 649697 572805 537089
R
2
0.991 0.996 0.979 0.991 0.996 0.979
Kleibergen-Paap F Statistic 916.3 718.8 704.4 893.7 700.2 686.5
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using either method 1 or method 2 in Table 1. To avoid taking
the log of a zero, one is added to the number of Airbnb listings before taking logs. The instrumental variables
are g
t
× h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a
monthly frequency, zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate
are interpolated from the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are
reported in parenthesis. All variables are seasonally adjusted.
62
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 12: 2SLS Results for Log-Density Specifications
Instrument Set 1 Instrument Set 2 Instrument Set 3
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
Airbnb Density 1.003*** 2.525*** 1.520*** 1.891*** 3.606*** 1.685*** 1.569*** 2.658*** 1.058***
(0.219) (0.310) (0.330) (0.218) (0.373) (0.284) (0.185) (0.322) (0.270)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 1.102* 3.874*** 3.070*** 3.894*** 6.693*** 3.134*** 2.549*** 3.440*** 1.644**
(0.605) (0.888) (0.989) (0.698) (1.118) (0.731) (0.555) (0.906) (0.679)
ln Population 0.054*** 0.064*** 0.010 0.034*** 0.041** 0.011 0.045*** 0.070*** 0.023*
(0.008) (0.013) (0.015) (0.011) (0.016) (0.012) (0.008) (0.013) (0.012)
ln Median HH Income 0.014** 0.002 0.016* 0.008 0.006 0.018** 0.010* 0.005 0.016*
(0.006) (0.008) (0.010) (0.008) (0.009) (0.009) (0.006) (0.009) (0.009)
College Share 0.053*** 0.045** 0.002 0.068*** 0.039* 0.001 0.058*** 0.042** 0.001
(0.015) (0.018) (0.019) (0.019) (0.021) (0.019) (0.014) (0.020) (0.019)
Employment Rate 0.044*** 0.097*** 0.053** 0.053*** 0.111*** 0.049** 0.046*** 0.087*** 0.044**
(0.015) (0.021) (0.023) (0.016) (0.022) (0.022) (0.015) (0.022) (0.022)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 613245 538990 504260 613245 538990 504260 613245 538990 504260
R
2
0.991 0.996 0.979 0.990 0.996 0.979 0.991 0.996 0.979
Kleibergen-Paap F Statistic 15.26 10.75 9.347 5.797 5.813 5.666 9.369 10.27 10.19
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1, and is then divided by the total occupied
housing stock to calculate “Airbnb Density”. “Instrument Set 1” is g
t
× h
i,2010
/stock
i,2010
interacted with oorate
i,2010
.
“Instrument Set 2” is a third order polynomial of g
t
× h
i,2010
(our original instrument), interacted with oorate
i,2010
.
“Instrument Set 3” is a fully interacted second order polynomial of g
t
, h
i,2010
, and oorate
i,2010
. Clustered standard
errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis. All variables are seasonally adjusted.
63
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 13: 2SLS Results When Dropping Observations with Low Listings
Drop obs w/ 0 listings Drop obs w/ <5 listings
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
ln Airbnb Listings 0.049*** 0.092*** 0.041*** 0.034** 0.080*** 0.045**
(0.006) (0.010) (0.009) (0.014) (0.022) (0.020)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.041*** 0.085*** 0.040*** 0.043*** 0.097*** 0.050***
(0.004) (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.009) (0.008)
ln Population 0.037*** 0.046*** 0.006 0.006 0.012 0.011
(0.010) (0.015) (0.016) (0.013) (0.021) (0.020)
ln Median HH Income 0.035*** 0.011 0.021 0.039*** 0.023 0.009
(0.008) (0.012) (0.013) (0.009) (0.015) (0.016)
College Share 0.069*** 0.044 0.019 0.095*** 0.073* 0.018
(0.018) (0.028) (0.027) (0.024) (0.041) (0.040)
Employment Rate 0.011 0.071** 0.044 0.029 0.102** 0.029
(0.020) (0.031) (0.031) (0.030) (0.045) (0.044)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 444992 396821 380148 272298 245181 236996
R
2
0.993 0.996 0.983 0.995 0.997 0.986
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 150.3 119.4 119.6 44.82 38.44 38.97
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. The instrumental variables are g
t
×h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
64
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 14: 2SLS Results by Distance to City Center
Zipcodes near city center Zipcodes far from city center
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
ln Airbnb Listings 0.030*** 0.058*** 0.027*** 0.059*** 0.098*** 0.036***
(0.003) (0.006) (0.006) (0.005) (0.008) (0.006)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.022*** 0.048*** 0.024*** 0.052*** 0.098*** 0.041***
(0.004) (0.007) (0.007) (0.005) (0.009) (0.007)
ln Population 0.036*** 0.056*** 0.017 0.051*** 0.068*** 0.029**
(0.010) (0.013) (0.014) (0.010) (0.014) (0.015)
ln Median HH Income 0.014** 0.002 0.016 0.021** 0.018 0.011
(0.007) (0.010) (0.011) (0.009) (0.012) (0.014)
College Share 0.046*** 0.037 0.014 0.070*** 0.086*** 0.002
(0.017) (0.024) (0.027) (0.020) (0.028) (0.029)
Employment Rate 0.036** 0.050** 0.003 0.042** 0.073** 0.051
(0.018) (0.024) (0.028) (0.021) (0.032) (0.033)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 317636 275627 255794 331959 297034 281079
R
2
0.991 0.996 0.977 0.991 0.996 0.981
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 465.1 376.2 365.5 322.0 265.6 252.4
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. “Near” is defined as zipcodes that are
below the median distance to CBD, and “far” is defined as zipcodes that are above the median distance where the
median is taken within CBSA. The instrumental variables are g
t
× h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode
demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency, zipcode-month measures for household income,
population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates.
Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis. All variables are seasonally adjusted.
65
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 15: 2SLS Results by Time Period
Time Period: 2011-2013 Time Period: 2014-2016
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
ln Airbnb Listings 0.034*** 0.047*** 0.005 0.035*** 0.097*** 0.067***
(0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.006) (0.010) (0.010)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.005 0.004 0.012* 0.036*** 0.140*** 0.105***
(0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) (0.011) (0.012)
ln Population 0.044*** 0.094*** 0.050*** 0.016* 0.002 0.021*
(0.009) (0.012) (0.015) (0.009) (0.010) (0.013)
ln Median HH Income 0.013 0.005 0.013 0.020*** 0.012 0.009
(0.010) (0.010) (0.014) (0.007) (0.009) (0.011)
College Share 0.025 0.097*** 0.067** 0.035** 0.016 0.008
(0.021) (0.023) (0.030) (0.017) (0.021) (0.023)
Employment Rate 0.038* 0.094*** 0.064** 0.002 0.008 0.018
(0.022) (0.025) (0.032) (0.018) (0.023) (0.027)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 319757 286104 264100 329940 286701 272989
R
2
0.992 0.998 0.984 0.995 0.998 0.988
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 586.8 478.4 463.9 356.1 269.3 255.9
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. The instrumental variables are g
t
×h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
66
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 16: 2SLS Results by City Size
Population Rank 1-30 Population Rank 31-100
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
ln Airbnb Listings 0.055*** 0.097*** 0.040*** 0.022*** 0.032*** 0.009
(0.004) (0.007) (0.005) (0.003) (0.006) (0.006)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.041*** 0.084*** 0.040*** 0.016*** 0.025*** 0.004
(0.004) (0.008) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008)
ln Population 0.031*** 0.058*** 0.043*** 0.052*** 0.060*** 0.009
(0.009) (0.014) (0.013) (0.011) (0.013) (0.016)
ln Median HH Income 0.022*** 0.024** 0.002 0.015 0.015 0.033**
(0.007) (0.011) (0.011) (0.009) (0.011) (0.015)
College Share 0.077*** 0.023 0.028 0.019 0.096*** 0.047*
(0.017) (0.025) (0.025) (0.020) (0.025) (0.028)
Employment Rate 0.036* 0.054* 0.012 0.027 0.082*** 0.062*
(0.019) (0.028) (0.028) (0.021) (0.027) (0.033)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 403927 369158 351216 245770 203647 185873
R
2
0.991 0.996 0.980 0.987 0.996 0.973
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 410.0 346.6 339.6 413.1 333.9 309.6
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. The instrumental variables are g
t
×h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
67
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 17: 2SLS Results by Housing Subsegment
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DV: ln ZRI (MF) DV: ln ZRI (SF) DV: ln ZHVI (1BR) DV: ln ZHVI (2BR) DV: ln ZHVI (3BR) DV: ln ZHVI (4BR)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.033*** 0.048*** 0.032 0.043*** 0.046*** 0.048***
(0.005) (0.004) (0.025) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.028*** 0.043*** 0.019* 0.030*** 0.046*** 0.072***
(0.003) (0.005) (0.011) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)
ln Population 0.053*** 0.040*** 0.102** 0.056*** 0.058*** 0.031**
(0.011) (0.007) (0.043) (0.016) (0.011) (0.013)
ln Median HH Income 0.034*** 0.017*** 0.048* 0.028** 0.019* 0.016
(0.009) (0.006) (0.028) (0.013) (0.010) (0.011)
College Share 0.027 0.060*** 0.014 0.048 0.048** 0.054**
(0.021) (0.014) (0.068) (0.032) (0.024) (0.022)
Employment Rate 0.087*** 0.037** 0.252*** 0.111*** 0.063*** 0.073***
(0.023) (0.015) (0.085) (0.033) (0.023) (0.026)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 451934 645025 103716 381042 471714 431394
R
2
0.986 0.990 0.993 0.994 0.996 0.996
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 202.4 777.7 29.71 368.0 567.0 463.7
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. ZRI (MF) is the Zillow Rent Index
for multifamily rentals while ZRI (SF) is the Zillow Rent Index for single family rentals. ZHVI (XBR) is the Zillow
Home Value Index for X bedroom homes (including both condos and single-family). The instrumental variables
are g
t
× h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a
monthly frequency, zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate
are interpolated from the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are
reported in parenthesis. All variables are seasonally adjusted.
68
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 18: 2SLS Results with Controls for Other Websites
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.044*** 0.040*** 0.043*** 0.054*** 0.091*** 0.084*** 0.084*** 0.095***
(0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.006) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.009)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.035*** 0.033*** 0.035*** 0.041*** 0.078*** 0.075*** 0.075*** 0.080***
(0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.008)
ln Population 0.042*** 0.043*** 0.042*** 0.039*** 0.060*** 0.062*** 0.061*** 0.058***
(0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010)
ln Median HH Income 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.004
(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008)
College Share 0.057*** 0.058*** 0.057*** 0.056*** 0.059*** 0.060*** 0.060*** 0.058***
(0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019)
Employment Rate 0.036*** 0.037*** 0.036*** 0.032** 0.064*** 0.066*** 0.067*** 0.060***
(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.021)
V RBO
t
× h
i,2010
4.75E07 3.83E05***
(7.77E06) (9.73E06)
HomeAway
t
× h
i,2010
1.79E05** 2.58E05***
(7.01E06) (9.76E06)
T ripAdvisor
t
× h
i,2010
2.45E07 1.84E06***
(4.78E07) (5.92E07)
Expedia
t
× h
i,2010
6.10E06*** 9.68E06***
(2.32E06) (2.59E06)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 649697 649697 649697 649697 572805 572805 572805 572805
R
2
0.991 0.991 0.991 0.991 0.996 0.996 0.996 0.996
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 336.0 486.6 487.3 237.2 289.4 373.4 385.6 199.1
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. The instrumental variables are g
t
×h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
69
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832
Table 19: 2SLS Results with Forward-Looking Demographic Variables
DV: ln ZRI DV: ln ZHVI DV: ln ZHVI/ZRI
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
ln Airbnb Listings 0.049*** 0.045*** 0.070*** 0.059*** 0.019*** 0.009**
(0.003) (0.003) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004)
. . . × Owner-occupancy Rate (2010) 0.038*** 0.026*** 0.050*** 0.023*** 0.008* 0.009*
(0.004) (0.004) (0.006) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005)
Zipcode FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
CBSA-year-month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Instrumental Variable Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
1-year Ahead Demographics Yes No Yes No Yes No
2-year Ahead Demographics No Yes No Yes No Yes
Observations 539717 429737 477288 381696 446140 355120
R
2
0.991 0.991 0.997 0.997 0.980 0.982
Kleinbergen-Paap F Statistic 790.7 700.7 646.0 572.2 616.9 546.5
Significance levels: * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Note: The number of Airbnb listings is calculated using method 1 in Table 1. The instrumental variables are g
t
×h
i,2010
and g
t
× h
i,2010
× oorate
ict
. Because zipcode demographic characteristics are not available at a monthly frequency,
zipcode-month measures for household income, population, college share, and employment rate are interpolated from
the 2011 thru 2016 ACS 5-year estimates. Clustered standard errors at the zipcode level are reported in parenthesis.
All variables are seasonally adjusted.
70
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006832