A
NTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS:
Promoting Innovation and Competition
ISSUED BY THE
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
AND THE
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
APRIL 2007
ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS:
Promoting Innovation and Competition
ISSUED BY THE
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
AND THE
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
APRIL 2007
This Report should be cited as:
U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMMN, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY R IGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION (2007).
This Report can be accessed electronically at:
www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf
www.ftc.gov/reports/index.shtm
iii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION ................................................................. 1
CHAPTER 1: THE STRATEGIC USE OF LICENSING: UNILATERAL REFUSALS TO
LICENSE PATENTS ................................................. 15
I. Introduction ......................................................... 15
II. The Kodak and CSU Decisions .......................................... 16
A. The Basic Facts and Holdings of the Cases .................. 16
B. Panelist Views on Kodak .................................. 17
C. Panelist Views on CSU ................................... 18
D. Ambiguity as to the Scope of the Patent Grant .............. 19
III. Policy Issues Relating to Unilateral Refusals to License ................... 20
A. Should Antitrust Law Accord Special Treatment to Patents? .. 21
B. Should Market Power Be Presumed with Patents? ........... 22
C. If an Antitrust Violation Were Found, Would There
Be Workable Remedies for Unconditional, Unilateral
Refusals to License Patents? .............................. 22
D. What Would Be the Effect of Liability for Refusals to
License Patents on Incentives to Innovate? .................. 23
E. Competitive Effects of Refusals to License Patents ........... 24
IV. Legal Analysis of Unilateral Refusals to License Patents ................... 25
A. Does Section 271(d)(4) of Title 35 of the U.S. Code Create
an Immunity for Unilateral Refusals to License Patents? ...... 25
B. When Do Refusals to License Patents Violate the
Antitrust Laws? ......................................... 27
V. Conclusion .......................................................... 31
CHAPTER 2: COMPETITION CONCERNS WHEN PATENTS ARE INCORPORATED
INTO COLLABORATIVELY SET STANDARDS ....................... 33
I. Background and Introduction .......................................... 33
TABLE OF CONTENTSiv
II. Hold Up in the Context of Joint Standard Setting ......................... 37
III. Factors Other Than SSO Rules That May Mitigate Hold Up ................ 40
IV. Current SSO Methods to Avoid or Mitigate Hold Up ...................... 42
A. Use of Disclosure Rules to Deter Hold Up .................. 42
1. Benefits and Costs of SSO Disclosure
Policies ................................... 42
2. FTC Challenges to Hold Ups Based on the
Failure to Disclose IP Rights ................. 43
B. Use of Licensing Rules to Deter Hold Up ................... 45
1. Use of RAND Licensing ..................... 46
2. Royalty-Free Licensing Standards ............ 47
V. Using Ex Ante Licensing Negotiations to Mitigate Hold Up ................ 49
A. Practical Reasons for the Lack of Ex Ante Licensing
Negotiations ............................................ 50
B. Antitrust Concerns About Ex Ante Licensing Negotiations .... 50
1. Naked Restraints of Trade by Intellectual
Property Holders or SSO Members ........... 50
2. Group Buying Power ....................... 52
VI. Agency Policy Conclusions About Antitrust Concerns Associated with
Ex Ante Licensing Negotiations ........................................ 53
CHAPTER 3: ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF PORTFOLIO CROSS-LICENSING
AGREEMENTS AND PATENT POOLS ................................ 57
I. Introduction ......................................................... 57
II. Portfolio Cross Licenses .............................................. 59
A. Efficiencies ............................................. 59
B. Competitive Concerns ................................... 61
C. Analysis ............................................... 62
III. Patent Pools ......................................................... 64
A. Efficiencies ............................................. 64
B. Competitive Concerns ................................... 66
C. Existing Agency Guidance on Patent Pools ................. 66
1. U.S. Department of Justice Business
Review Letters ............................. 68
2. The Summit-VISX Pool ..................... 73
D. Specific Issues of Competitive Concern ..................... 74
1. Substitutes Within a Patent Pool ............. 74
2. Exclusive and Nonexclusive Licensing ........ 78
3. Grantbacks ................................ 80
4. Access to Information ...................... 81
TABLE OF CONTENTS v
5. Royalties for the Pool’s Patents ............... 82
6. Requests for Partial-Pool Licenses ............ 83
IV. Conclusion .......................................................... 84
CHAPTER 4: VARIATIONS ON INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY
LICENSING PRACTICES ............................................ 87
I. Introduction ......................................................... 87
II. Non-Assertion Clauses ................................................ 88
A. Efficiencies of Non-Assertion Clauses ...................... 89
B. Competitive Concerns Regarding Non-Assertion Clauses .... 90
III. Grantbacks .......................................................... 91
A. Efficiencies of Grantbacks ................................ 92
B. Competitive Concerns Associated with Grantbacks .......... 92
IV. Reach-Through Licensing Agreements .................................. 93
A. Efficiencies of Reach-Through Licensing Agreements ........ 94
B. Competitive Concerns About Reach-Through
Licensing Agreements ................................... 95
V. Perspectives on Antitrust Analysis of Licensing Practices .................. 97
VI. The Agencies’ Competitive Concerns and Analyses ....................... 99
VII. Conclusion ......................................................... 102
CHAPTER 5: ANTITRUST ISSUES IN THE TYING AND BUNDLING OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS ............................... 103
I. Introduction ........................................................ 103
II. Legal Analyses of Tying and Bundling ................................ 105
III. Tying and Bundling Involving Intellectual Property ..................... 106
A. The Economics of Bundling Involving Intellectual
Property .............................................. 107
B. Legal Issues Relevant to Intellectual Property Bundling ..... 108
C. Practical Issues Regarding Intellectual Property Bundling ... 111
D. Suggested Approaches to Improving the Law on
Intellectual Property Bundling ........................... 112
IV. Conclusion ......................................................... 114
TABLE OF CONTENTSvi
CHAPTER 6: COMPETITIVE ISSUES REGARDING PRACTICES THAT
EXTEND THE MARKET POWER CONFERRED BY A PATENT
BEYOND ITS STATUTORY TERM ................................... 115
I. Collecting Royalties Beyond the Statutory Term ......................... 116
II. Long Term Contracts Involving Exclusivity ............................. 119
III. Bundling Patents with Trade Secrets ................................... 120
IV. The Agencies’ Analysis .............................................. 122
APPENDICES
A. Hearings Participants ................................................ 125
B. Hearings Submissions ............................................... 147
C. Public Comments ................................................... 161
D. Hearings Transcripts ................................................ 167
E. United States Code .................................................. 171
F. Cited Cases and Supporting Documents ................................ 179
G. Publications Cited ................................................... 187
INDEX ......................................................................... 199
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ......................................................... 210
1
INTRODUCTION
Over the past several decades,
antitrust enforcers and the courts have
come to recognize that intellectual
property laws and antitrust laws share
the same fundamental goals of enhancing
consumer welfare and promoting
innovation. This recognition signaled a
significant shift from the view that
prevailed earlier in the twentieth century,
when the goals of antitrust and
intellectual property law were viewed as
incompatible: intellectual property law’s
grant of exclusivity was seen as creating
monopolies that were in tension with
antitrust law’s attack on monopoly
power. Such generalizations are
relegated to the past. Modern
understanding of these two disciplines is
that intellectual property and antitrust
laws work in tandem to bring new and
better technologies, products, and
services to consumers at lower prices.
Intellectual property laws create
exclusive rights that provide incentives
for innovation by “establishing
enforceable property rights for the
creators of new and useful products,
more efficient processes, and original
works of expression.”
1
These property
rights promote innovation by allowing
intellectual property owners to prevent
others from appropriating much of the
value derived from their inventions or
original expressions. These rights also
can facilitate the commercialization of
these inventions or expressions and
encourage public disclosure, thereby
enabling others to learn from the
protected property.
Antitrust laws, in turn, ensure that
new proprietary technologies, products,
and services are bought, sold, traded, and
licensed in a competitive environment. In
today’s dynamic marketplace, new
technological improvements are
constantly replacing those that came
before, as competitors are driven to
improve their existing products or
introduce new products in order to
maintain their market share. Antitrust
laws foster competition by prohibiting
anticompetitive mergers, collusion, and
exclusionary uses of monopoly power.
Yet, it is well understood that exercise of
monopoly power, including the charging
of monopoly prices, through the exercise
of a lawfully gained monopoly position
will not run afoul of the antitrust laws.
2
1
U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY § 1 (1995), reprinted in 4
Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132, available at
http://www.usdoj. gov/atr/ public/guidelines/
0558.pdf[hereinafter ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES].
2
Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION2
The same principle applies to monopoly
power that is based on intellectual
property rights. As Judge Posner has
explained, “It is not a violation of [the
antitrust] laws to acquire a monopoly by
lawful means, and those means include
innovations protected from competition
by the intellectual property laws.
3
Although some intellectual property
rights may create monopolies, intellectual
property rights do not necessarily (and
indeed only rarely) create monopolies
because consumers may be able to
substitute other technologies or products
for the protected technologies or
products. Therefore, antitrust doctrine
does not presume the existence of market
power from the mere presence of an
intellectual property right.
4
Consequently, antitrust and
intellectual property are properly
perceived as complementary bodies of
law that work together to bring
innovation to consumers: antitrust laws
protect robust competition in the
marketplace, while intellectual property
laws protect the ability to earn a return on
the investments necessary to innovate.
Both spur competition among rivals to be
the first to enter the marketplace with a
desirable technology, product, or service.
Although there is broad consensus
that the basic goals of antitrust and
intellectual property law are aligned,
difficult questions can arise when
antitrust law is applied to specific
activities involving intellectual property
rights that do create market power. That
may happen when, for instance, a
standard of manufacture for an entire
industry or the only treatment for a
particular disease incorporates patented
technology, or when the research and
development (“R&D”), invention,
manufacture, or distribution of a product
or process without good substitutes
involves the licensing of protected
technology. The Antitrust Division of the
U.S. Department of Justice and the U.S.
Federal Trade Commission (the
“Agencies”) frequently address complex
antitrust questions related to conduct
involving the exercise of intellectual
property rights in enforcement actions,
reports, testimony, reviews of proposed
business conduct, and amicus curiae or
“friend of the court” briefs filed in the
federal courts of appeals and the Supreme
Court. In doing so, the Agencies must
apply antitrust principles to identify
illegal collusive or exclusionary conduct
while at the same time supporting the
incentives to innovate created by
intellectual property rights. Condemning
efficient activity involving intellectual
property rights could undermine that
incentive to innovate, and thus slow the
engine that drives much economic growth
in the United States. However, failure to
challenge illegal collusive or exclusionary
conduct, involving intellectual property
as well as other forms of property, can
have substantial negative consequences
for consumers.
Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004).
3
Richard A. Posner, Antitrust in the New Economy, 68
ANTITRUST L.J. 925, 930-31 (2001).
4
Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281,
1284 (2006) (“[T]he mere fact that a tying product is
patented does not support [a market power]
presumption.”); ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.2 (“The
Agencies will not presume that a patent, copyright, or
trade secret necessarily confers market power upon
its owner.”).
3
Introduction
Recognizing that both robust
competition and intellectual property
rights are crucial to a well-functioning
market economy, the Agencies conducted
a series of Hearings, beginning in
February 2002, designed to develop a
better understanding of the questions that
arise when antitrust law is applied to
conduct involving intellectual property
rights and to examine the Agencies’
approach toward analyzing such conduct.
The Hearings, entitled “Competition and
Intellectual Property Law and Policy in
the Knowledge-Based Economy,
assembled business people from large
and small firms, academics, and legal
practitioners. During the Hearings, the
Agencies heard a wide range of views
from more than 300 panelists and
received more than 100 written
comments.
5
In conjunction with the
Hearings, the Agencies also reviewed the
scholarly literature addressing issues on
the cutting edge of legal doctrine and
economic theory, concerning how best to
reward innovation while encouraging
competition.
6
This Report synthesizes
many of the views expressed during the
Hearings, in the written submissions, and
in the literature, and draws conclusions
where appropriate on the proper analysis
for evaluating certain activities involving
intellectual property rights, as well as the
key considerations that should inform the
Agencies’ analysis.
7
Many of these key considerations are
found within the framework of the
Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of
Intellectual Property (“Antitrust-IP
Guidelines”). The Agencies’ review of
intellectual property and antitrust law
and policy illustrates that the Antitrust-IP
Guidelines remain an integral part of the
Agencies’ analysis of intellectual property
and antitrust issues. For over a decade,
the Agencies have relied on the sound
principles of these guidelines to aid their
analysis of complex licensing agreements.
Those principles will continue to guide
the Agencies as they consider new and
challenging antitrust questions that
involve intellectual property rights.
The general principles articulated in
section 2 of these Guidelines provide a
solid foundation for this analysis. First,
the Guidelines state that agreements
involving intellectual property can be
analyzed using the same antitrust rules
applied to agreements involving any
other property.
8
During the Hearings,
former Deputy Assistant Attorney
General Richard J. Gilbert explained that
5
Hearings information and materials can be accessed
on the Agencies’ websites. DOJ/Antitrust,
Competition and Intellectual Property Law in the
Knowledge-Based Economy,
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/hearing.htm; Federal
Trade Commission, Competition and Intellectual
Property Law in the Knowledge-Based Economy,
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/ intellect.
6
For a complete list of the scholarly literature cited
by the Agencies, see Appendix G.
7
In October 2003, the FTC issued a report, based on a
portion of the Hearings record, which made a series
of recommendations for reform of the patent system
designed to maintain a proper balance between
competition and intellectual property policies.
FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, TO PROMOTE INNOVATION:
THE PROPER BALANCE OF COMPETITION AND PATENT
LAW AND POLICY Executive Summary, at I-V (2003),
available at http://www.ftc.gov/ os/2003/10/
innovationrpt.pdf.
8
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.1 (“The Agencies
apply the same general antitrust principles to conduct
involving intellectual property that they apply to
conduct involving any other form of tangible or
intangible property.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION4
“[w]hat this mean[s is] not that
intellectual property is the same as other
forms of property. It clearly is not the
same. . . . [B]ut in terms of how to analyze
intellectual property issues, the same
[antitrust] principles apply.”
9
Second, the
Guidelines state that an intellectual
property right does not necessarily create
market power. Rather, the Agencies
determine whether substitutes for the
protected technology or product prevent
the intellectual property right holder from
exercising market power.
10
Third, the
Guidelines state that intellectual property
licensing is generally procompetitive
because it allows firms to combine
intellectual property rights with other
complementary factors of production
such as manufacturing and production
facilities and workforces.
11
As the Antitrust-IP Guidelines
suggest, many of the difficult questions
that the Agencies encounter in the
application of antitrust principles to
intellectual property stem from
differences between the characteristics of
intellectual property and other forms of
property. Intellectual property is more
easily misappropriated than many other
forms of property in that it is often easier
to copy and may be used without
interfering with the ability of others also
to use it. The fixed costs of creating
intellectual property can be high, while
the marginal costs of using intellectual
property are often low. Moreover, the
boundaries of intellectual property rights
are often uncertain and difficult to define,
so that neither the intellectual property
holder nor competitors know the precise
extent of protection afforded by the
intellectual property right without a
decision from a court or binding arbiter.
The value of intellectual property
typically depends more on its
combination with other factors of
production, such as manufacturing and
distribution facilities, workforces, or
complementary intellectual property,
than does tangible property. Finally, the
duration of some, but not all, intellectual
property rights is limited.
12
The
application of antitrust law to intellectual
property requires careful attention to
these differences.
This Report discusses how these
principles are applied to particular
activities involving intellectual property
rights. The first two chapters of this
Report focus on certain methods that an
9
Feb. 6, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Welcome and Overview of
Hearings at 85 (Gilbert), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020206ftc.pdf [hereinafter Feb. 6 Tr.]. For
example, the Agencies analyze acquisitions of
intellectual property pursuant to the Horizontal
Merger Guidelines, examining whether the
acquisitions are likely to substantially lessen
competition. U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE
COMMN, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES (1992, rev.
ed. 1997), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶
13,104, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/
public/guidelines/hmg.pdf.
10
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.1.
11
Id. § 2.3.
12
Patents are valid for a term of twenty years from
the date on which the application for the patent was
filed. 35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(2) (2000). Most copyrights
are valid for the life of the author plus seventy years
or ninety-five years after the work is first published if
the creator is a corporation. 17 U.S.C. § 302(a), (c)
(2000). Trade secrets enjoy perpetual protection
provided the secret information is not disclosed. 1
ROGER M. MILGRIM, MILGRIM ON TRADE SECRETS §
1.05[1], at 1-197 (2005). Trademarks are protected as
long as the mark continues to indicate a specific
source or quality and is not abandoned by the owner.
1 J. THOMAS MCCARTHY, MCCARTHY ON TRADEMARKS
AND UNFAIR COMPETITION § 6.8, at 6-11 to -12 (4th ed.
2005).
5
Introduction
individual holder of intellectual property
rights might employ to maximize the
benefits it receives from its intellectual
property. Chapter 1 addresses the
antitrust consequences for a patent holder
that unilaterally and unconditionally
refuses to license its patent. Chapter 2
addresses collaboratively set standards
and “hold up,” or the ability of an
intellectual property holder to extract
more favorable licensing terms after a
standard is set.
The remaining chapters of this
Report focus directly on intellectual
property licensing practices. Chapter 3
addresses patent pools and cross-
licensing arrangements and analyzes
licensing structures used to lower the risk
that patent-pooling agreements will cause
competitive harm. Chapter 4 considers
the procompetitive and anticompetitive
effects of specific types of restrictions in
intellectual property licenses, including
non-assertion clauses, grantbacks, and
reach-through royalty agreements. The
antitrust consequences of tying and
bundling of intellectual property rights
are assessed in Chapter 5. Finally, in
Chapter 6, the Report addresses the
competitive significance of restrictions
that attempt to extend the temporal reach
of patents. The Agencies’ conclusions
regarding these topics are summarized in
this introduction.
CHAPTER 1: THE STRATEGIC USE OF
LICENSING: U NILATERAL
REFUSALS TO LICENSE
PATENTS
Although intellectual property law
and antitrust law are complementary, two
divergent appellate decisions, Image
Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co.
(“Kodak”)
13
and In re Independent Service
Organizations Antitrust Litigation (CSU),
14
illustrate the potential for conflict
regarding unilateral refusals to license
patents. Panelists explored the
circumstances, if any, under which courts
should impose antitrust liability for a
refusal to license a patent. Panelists
agreed that neither Kodak nor CSU
provide sufficient guidance on potential
antitrust liability for a refusal to license.
Most panelists rejected the approach of
the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth
Circuit in Kodak, which impracticably
focused on the subjective intent of the
patent holder that had refused to license
its patent. As one panelist noted, Kodak
presents a standard that is out of step
with the modern focus of antitrust
analysis, which is on objective economic
evidence. Panelists also criticized the
decision of the U.S. Court of Appeals for
the Federal Circuit in CSU, which, in
dictum, narrowly construed the
circumstances in which antitrust liability
can arise for a refusal to license. These
circumstances—illegal tying, fraud on the
U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, and
sham litigation—provided little guidance,
according to panelists, because they are
independent bases for antitrust liability.
13
125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997).
14
203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION6
Other panelists feared the CSU decision
would be interpreted broadly to
encompass conduct beyond the unilateral
refusal to license, to instances in which
the patentee attaches conditions to a
license.
Most panelists concluded, consistent
with the Antitrust-IP Guidelines, that
antitrust laws should be applied in the
same manner to intellectual property as
they are to other property. Panelists
offered differing views on other issues,
however, such as whether challenging
refusals to license would have significant
chilling effects on innovation, the possible
competitive effects of refusals to license,
and whether compulsory licensing is a
workable remedy for an antitrust
violation. Although some panelists
favored the possibility of antitrust
liability for refusals to license in narrow
circumstances, others favored a
categorical exemption from antitrust
liability for unilateral, unconditional
refusals to license. Panelists agreed that
conditional refusals to license, which have
the potential to cause competitive harm,
can and should be treated as an antitrust
violation in appropriate circumstances.
The Agencies’ Conclusions:
Section 271(d)(4) of the Patent Act
does not create antitrust immunity
for unilateral refusals to license
patents.
Statements in Supreme Court
jurisprudence support the
traditional understanding that the
unilateral right to refuse to grant a
patent license is a core part of the
patent grant.
Antitrust liability for mere
unilateral, unconditional refusals to
license patents will not play a
meaningful part in the interface
between patent rights and antitrust
protections. Antitrust liability for
refusals to license competitors
would compel firms to reach out
and affirmatively assist their rivals,
a result that is “in some tension
with the underlying purpose of
antitrust law.”
15
Moreover, liability
would restrict the patent holder’s
ability to exercise a core part of the
patent—the right to exclude.
Conditional refusals to license that
cause competitive harm are subject
to antitrust liability.
CHAPTER 2: COMPETITION CONCERNS
WHEN PATENTS ARE
INCORPORATED INTO
COLLABORATIVELY SET
S TANDARDS
Industry standards are widely
acknowledged to be one of the engines of
the modern economy. Standards can
make products less costly for firms to
produce and more valuable to consumers.
They can increase innovation, efficiency,
and consumer choice; foster public health
and safety; and serve as a “fundamental
building block for international trade.”
16
Standards make networks, such as the
Internet and telecommunications, more
15
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407-08 (setting forth three
sources of that tension).
16
Amy A. Marasco, Standards-Setting Practices:
Competition, Innovation and Consumer Welfare (Apr. 18,
2002 Hr’g R.) at 3-4, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020418marasco.pdf.
7
Introduction
valuable to consumers by allowing
products to interoperate.
Businesses can collaborate to
establish industry standards by working
though standard-setting organizations
(“SSOs”). During the standard-setting
process, SSO members often jointly
evaluate and choose between substitute
technologies. This process can raise
antitrust concerns, and indeed, some
collaborative standard-setting activities
have been challenged under the antitrust
laws. Unique antitrust issues arise when
the standards adopted involve, as they
frequently do, intellectual property rights.
If a technology lacks effective substitutes
because an SSO chose to include it in a
standard, and the costs associated with
switching to an alternative standard are
high, the owner of patents on that
technology may be able to hold up firms
wishing to implement the standard by
setting higher royalties and less favorable
licensing terms than it could have done
before the standard was set.
To mitigate the potential for hold up,
many SSOs have required participants to
disclose the existence of intellectual
property rights that may be infringed by
a standard and to commit to licensing on
reasonable and nondiscriminatory
(“RAND”) terms. Panelists agreed that
intellectual property disclosure rules can
help avoid hold up by informing SSO
members early about relevant intellectual
property rights that may be asserted by
those participating in the standard-setting
process. Those rules can be successful in
preventing hold up, however, only if
participants comply. At the Hearings,
panelists also noted the potential costs
associated with disclosure requirements,
including slowing the adoption of a
standard and deterring wide-spread
participation in the SSO.
Some SSOs and SSO members would
like to further mitigate the potential for
hold up by requiring patent owners to
commit to licensing terms before the SSO
will select the patented technology as part
of a standard. Panelists addressed how ex
ante licensing discussions could alleviate
hold up. There was general consensus
among panelists that a more transparent
process for setting licensing terms would
be desirable, but many expressed concern
that such discussions could increase the
risk of an antitrust challenge. Further, the
increased administrative costs and delays
associated with that transparency led
many panelists to disfavor including ex
ante discussions in the standard-setting
process for practical reasons that were
independent of antitrust concerns.
The Agencies’ Conclusions:
Ex ante consideration of licensing
terms by SSO participants can be
procompetitive.
Joint ex ante consideration of
licensing terms by SSO participants
is unlikely to constitute a per se
antitrust violation. The Agencies
will usually apply the rule of
reason when evaluating joint
activities that mitigate hold up by
allowing potential licensees of the
standard to negotiate licensing
terms with IP holders. Such ex ante
negotiations of licensing terms are
most likely to be reasonable when
the adoption of a standard will
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION8
create or enhance market power for
a patent holder.
An intellectual property owner’s
unilateral announcement of
licensing terms does not violate
section 1 of the Sherman Act.
An intellectual property owner’s
unilateral announcement of price
terms, without more, does not
violate section 2 of the Sherman
Act.
Bilateral ex ante negotiations about
licensing terms that take place
between an individual SSO
member and an individual
intellectual property holder outside
the auspices of the SSO are unlikely
(without more) to require any
special antitrust scrutiny because
intellectual property rights holders
are merely negotiating individual
terms with individual buyers.
The Agencies take no position as to
whether SSOs should engage in
joint ex ante discussion of licensing
terms.
CHAPTER 3: ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF
P ORTFOLIO CROSS-
LICENSING AGREEMENTS
AND PATENT POOLS
In many industries, the patent rights
necessary to commercialize a product are
frequently controlled by multiple rights
holders. This fragmentation of rights can
increase the costs of bringing products to
market due to the transaction costs of
negotiating multiple licenses, and greater
cumulative royalty payments. Portfolio
cross licenses and patent pools can help
solve the problems created by these
overlapping patent rights, or patent
thickets, by removing the need for patent-
by-patent licensing, thus reducing
transaction costs for licensees. In
addition, patent-pooling agreements may
mitigate royalty stacking and hold-up
problems that can occur when multiple
patent holders individually demand
royalties from a licensee. At the same
time, portfolio cross licenses and patent
pools preserve the financial incentives for
inventors to commercialize their existing
innovations and undertake new,
potentially patentable R&D.
Although both cross-licensing and
patent-pooling agreements have the
potential to generate significant
efficiencies, they also may generate
anticompetitive effects if the
arrangements result in price fixing,
coordinated output restrictions among
competitors, or foreclosure of innovation.
For instance, horizontal coordination
among the pool’s licensors could lead to
a reduction in price competition between
technologies or downstream products.
Moreover,
a pooling arrangement that
requires members to grant licenses
to each other for current and
future technology at minimal cost
may reduce the incentives of its
members to engage in research
and development because
members of the pool have to share
their successful research and
development and each of the
members can free ride on the
9
Introduction
accomplishments of other pool
members.
17
Pooling agreements typically warrant
greater antitrust scrutiny than do cross-
licensing agreements due to the collective
pricing of pooled patents, greater
possibilities for collusion, and generally a
larger number of market participants.
Hearing panelists discussed several
topics, including the similarities and
differences between pooling and cross-
licensing agreements, the potential
procompetitive benefits and
anticompetitive effects of pools and cross
licenses, and the safeguards that have
been proposed through the Department’s
business review procedures to help
ensure that patent pools do not harm
competition. Panelists generally agreed
that the Agencies existing guidance in
this area has been instructive and helpful.
The Agencies’ Conclusions:
The Agencies will continue to
evaluate the competitive effects of
cross licenses and patent pools
under the framework of the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines. Given the
cognizable benefits and potential
anticompetitive effects associated
with both of these licensing
practices, the Agencies typically
will analyze both types of
agreements under the rule of
reason.
Combining complementary patents
within a pool is generally
procompetitive.
Including substitute patents in a
pool does not make the pool
presumptively anticompetitive;
competitive effects will be
ascertained on a case-by-case basis.
The competitive significance of a
pool’s licensing terms will be
analyzed on a case-by-case basis
considering both their
procompetitive benefits and
anticompetitive effects.
The Agencies will not generally
assess the reasonableness of
royalties set by a pool. The focus of
the Agencies’ analysis is on the
pool’s formation and whether its
structure would likely enable pool
participants to impair competition.
CHAPTER 4: V ARIATIONS ON
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY
LICENSING PRACTICES
Because the Agencies recognize that
most business transactions involving the
use, distribution, transfer, or exchange of
intellectual property rights are
procompetitive, they most commonly
evaluate the competitive impact of such
transactions under the rule of reason. For
restraints in intellectual property licenses,
this approach means inquiring “whether
the restraint is likely to have
anticompetitive effects, and, if so,
whether the restraint is reasonably
necessary to achieve procompetitive
benefits that outweigh those
anticompetitive effects.”
18
The analysis of
a particular licensing restraint inquires
17
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5.
18
Id. § 3.4.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION10
whether the restraint “harms competition
among entities that would have been
actual or likely potential competitors” in
the absence of the license.
19
Restraints
that encourage licensees to develop and
market the licensed technology or that
reduce the transaction costs of licensing
the technology are more likely to be
found reasonable. When assessing
licensing restraints, the Agencies will not
search for unrealistic least restrictive
alternatives for the restraint.
20
The
Agencies will, however, treat as unlawful
per se those restraints that courts have
found plainly anticompetitive, such as
price fixing and market division among
horizontal competitors, because they
always, or almost always, tend to raise
prices or reduce output.
21
Hearings panelists discussed several
specific licensing practices that are
analyzed using the framework of the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines: non-assertion
clauses, grantbacks, and reach-through
royalty agreements. Panelists considered
when these practices might be
procompetitive, under what
circumstances they might be
anticompetitive, and whether the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines provide adequate
guidance for evaluating the antitrust
implications of these arrangements.
Panelists generally agreed that the basic
principles set forth in the Antitrust-IP
Guidelines are preferable to bright line,
per se rules that affirmatively approve or
condemn a specific licensing practice
without regard to the circumstances in
which these rules are applied.
The Agencies’ Conclusion:
The Agencies will continue to apply
the flexible rule of reason analysis
of the Antitrust-IP Guidelines to
assess intellectual property
licensing agreements, including
non-assertion clauses, grantbacks,
and reach-through royalty
agreements.
CHAPTER 5: ANTITRUST ISSUES IN THE
TYING AND BUNDLING OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY
RIGHTS
A tying arrangement occurs when,
through a contractual or technological
requirement, a seller conditions the sale
or lease of one product or service on the
customer’s agreement to take a second
product or service. A “requirements tie-
in” sale occurs when a seller requires
customers who purchase one product
from the seller (e.g., a printer) also to
make all their purchases of another
product from the seller (e.g., ink
cartridges). Such tying allows the seller
to, for example, charge customers
different amounts depending on their
product usage. A bundled sale typically
refers to a sale in which the products are
sold only in fixed proportions (e.g., one
pair of shoes and one pair of shoe laces, or
a newspaper, which can be viewed as a
bundle of sections, some of which may
not be read at all by individual
customers).
Intellectual property bundling can
take various forms and labels, depending
19
Id. § 3.1.
20
Id. § 4.2.
21
Id. § 3.4.
11
Introduction
on whether the product linked to the
intellectual property also embodies
intellectual property, whether one price
or separate prices are charged, and
whether the linkage is accomplished
contractually or technologically. Classic
“contractual” patent tying occurs when
the tying product is patented (such as a
mimeograph machine), the tied product is
a commodity used as an input for the
tying product (such as ink or paper), and
the sale of the patented product is
conditioned on the purchase of the
unpatented product. A “technological
tie” may be defined as one in which “the
tying and tied products are bundled
together physically or produced in such a
way that they are compatible only with
each other.”
22
Multiple intellectual
property rights may themselves be
combined into bundles or licensed in
packages, such as the “block booking” of
motion pictures or television shows.
Economic theory can identify both
procompetitive and anticompetitive
effects when two or more products are
tied or bundled together and at least one
of these products involves intellectual
property rights. In spite of this, under
current antitrust case law, tying
arrangements, including those involving
intellectual property, continue to be per se
illegal if the seller has market power in
the tying product and certain other
conditions are met.
23
However, the
application of the per se rule to tying has
evolved to incorporate a market
analysis.
24
One Hearing panel discussed how
the Agencies and the courts could best
analyze IP tying and bundling, both to
reach the right answers in particular cases
and to give private parties a reasonable
ability to predict how their licensing
practices will be treated under the
antitrust laws. Several panelists
recognized the efficiencies potentially
associated with the tying and bundling of
intellectual property rights and panelists
were generally in favor of a more flexible
application of the antitrust laws to
intellectual property tying and bundling.
The Agencies’ Conclusion:
The Antitrust-IP Guidelines will
continue to guide the Agencies’
analysis of intellectual property
tying and bundling. Pursuant to
the Antitrust-IP Guidelines, the
Agencies consider both the
anticompetitive effects and the
efficiencies attributable to a tie, and
would be likely to challenge a tying
arrangement if: “(1) the seller has
market power in the tying product,
(2) the arrangement has an adverse
effect on competition in the
relevant market for the tied
product, and (3) efficiency
justifications for the arrangement
do not outweigh the
22
1 HERBERT HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS & MARK A.
LEMLEY, IP AND ANTITRUST: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST
PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW §
21.5b2, at 21-104 (2002). An example would be a
razor and razor blade cartridge.
23
Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2,
9 (1984); Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1284.
24
Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of the
Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 104 n.26 (1984) (“[W]hile
the Court has spoken of a ‘per se’ rule against tying
arrangements, it has also recognized that tying may
have procompetitive justifications that make it
inappropriate to condemn without considerable
market analysis.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION12
anticompetitive effects.”
25
If a
package license constitutes tying,
26
the Agencies will evaluate it
pursuant to the same principles
they use to analyze other tying
arrangements.
CHAPTER 6: C OMPETITIVE ISSUES
R EGARDING PRACTICES
THAT EXTEND THE MARKET
POWER CONFERRED BY A
PATENT BEYOND ITS
STATUTORY TERM
A portion of the Hearings focused on
the competitive impact of practices that
firms may use to extend the reach of a
patent beyond the expiration of a patent’s
statutory term, such as collecting royalties
beyond the statutory term, the use of
exclusive contracts that deprive rivals or
potential entrants of a source of supply or
access to customers, or bundling trade
secrets with patents. Of course, these
efforts do not have the potential to cause
competitive concern unless the patent in
question is associated with market power,
i.e., when the patent holder can profitably
“maintain prices above, or output below,
competitive levels for a significant period
of time.”
27
Moreover, although some of
these practices may have the potential to
extend the ability to exercise the market
power conferred by a patent, many
practices do not actually do so, and as
panelists observed, they may, in fact, offer
efficiencies. Accordingly, panelists
identified the fundamental question for
assessing competitive harm that may
result from such practices to be whether
the patent holder is exercising market
power arising from the patent beyond its
statutory term to prevent expansion by
those already in the market or to deter the
entry of substitute products or processes
into the market.
The Agencies’ Conclusions:
The starting point for evaluating
practices that extend beyond a
patent’s expiration is analyzing
whether the patent in question
confers market power.
Standard antitrust analysis applies
to practices that have the potential
to extend the market power
conferred by a patent beyond its
expiration.
Collecting royalties beyond a
patent’s statutory term can be
efficient. Although there are
limitations on a patent owner’s
ability to collect royalties beyond a
patent’s statutory term,
28
that
practice may permit licensees to pay
lower royalty rates over a longer
period of time, which reduces the
deadweight loss associated with a
patent monopoly and allows the
patent holder to recover the full
value of the patent, thereby
preserving innovation incentives.
25
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.3 (footnotes omitted).
26
The Antitrust-IP Guidelines describe package
licensing as “the licensing of multiple items of
intellectual property in a single license or in a group
of related licenses,” which “may be a form of tying
arrangement if the licensing of one product is
conditioned upon the acceptance of a license for
another, separate product.” Id.
27
Id. § 2.2.
28
See Brulotte v. Thys Co., 379 U.S. 29 (1964).
13
Introduction
Holding the Hearings and
developing this Report has improved the
understanding of the Agencies regarding
issues at the intersection of antitrust and
intellectual property law. Listening to the
differing perspectives of the panelists,
and reviewing the submissions and the
literature, has helped hone the Agencies’
analysis of compelling issues at the
intellectual property-antitrust interface
that will continue to arise as we move
further into the twenty-first century. The
Hearings confirmed that the rigorous
economic analysis introduced into
competition law in the 1980s, which the
Agencies continue to apply today, is
robust enough to tackle unexplored
questions that lie ahead. This analysis
focuses on preserving incentives for
creativity and innovation, and avoids
applying intellectual property-specific
rules that may undermine creativity and
innovation. The Hearings further
confirmed the continuing vitality of the
principles espoused in the Antitrust-IP
Guidelines in guiding the Agencies’
consideration of challenging antitrust
questions in this area. The Agencies will
continue to identify those circumstances
under which it may be necessary for the
Agencies to intervene in order to prevent
practices that are harmful to competition
or innovation. Using our improved
understanding of intellectual property,
the Agencies better can ensure that
intellectual property and antitrust laws
continue to achieve their common goals
of “encouraging innovation, industry and
competition.”
29
29
See Atari Games Corp. v. Nintendo of Am., Inc., 897
F.2d 1572, 1576 (Fed. Cir. 1990); Feb. 6 Tr. at 11-12
(James).
15
CHAPTER 1
THE STRATEGIC USE OF LICENSING:
UNILATERAL REFUSALS TO LICENSE PATENTS
I. INTRODUCTION
The appropriate application of the
antitrust laws to unilateral refusals to
license patents is the subject of much
debate. Differing resolutions of that
debate at this particular intersection of
antitrust and patent law may explain
divergent decisions from the courts of
appeals. In Image Technical Services, Inc. v.
Eastman Kodak Co. (“Kodak”),
1
the United
States Court of Appeals for the Ninth
Circuit affirmed Sherman Act liability
relating to a unilateral refusal to license
intellectual property. Yet in In re
Independent Service Organizations Antitrust
Litigation (CSU),
2
the United States Court
of Appeals for the Federal Circuit
affirmed summary judgment for a
defendant under similar circumstances.
As a part of the Hearings, attorneys
and economists explored the
circumstances, if any, under which courts
should impose antitrust liability for a
refusal to license patents.
3
Panelists
critiqued the Kodak and CSU decisions;
discussed the likely economic effects of
permitting, and prohibiting, antitrust
liability for unilateral refusals to license
patents; and debated the proper legal
1
125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997).
2
203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
3
The May 1, 2002 Hearing panelists included:
Ashish Arora, Visiting Associate Professor of
Economics, Stanford University, Associate Professor
of Economics and Public Policy, Carnegie Mellon
University; Jonathan I. Gleklen, Partner, Arnold &
Porter; Paul F. Kirsch, Partner, Townsend and
Townsend and Crew LLP; Benjamin Klein, Professor
of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles;
Jeffrey K. MacKie-Mason, Arthur W. Burks Professor
of Information and Computer Science, Professor of
Economics and Public Policy, University of Michigan;
A. Douglas Melamed, Partner, Wilmer, Cutler &
Pickering; Carl Shapiro, Transamerica Professor of
Business Strategy, Haas School of Business; Director
and Professor of Economics, Institute of Business and
Economic Research, University of California,
Berkeley; Christopher J. Sprigman, Counsel, King &
Spalding; Mark D. Whitener, Antitrust and General
Counsel, General Electric; John Shepard Wiley, Jr.,
Professor of Law, University of California, Los
Angeles. This session was moderated by then-
Deputy Assistant Attorney General R. Hewitt Pate,
Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice; Pam
Cole, Attorney, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department
of Justice; Suzanne Majewski, Economist, Antitrust
Division, U.S. Department of Justice; Gail Levine,
then-Deputy Assistant General Counsel for Policy
Studies, Federal Trade Commission; and C. Edward
Polk, Jr., then-Associate Solicitor, U.S. Patent and
Trademark Office. May 1, 2002 Hr’g Tr., The
Strategic Use of Licensing: Is There Cause for
Concern About Unilateral Refusals to Deal? at 2-3,
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020501xscript.pdf
[hereinafter May 1 Tr.].
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION16
analysis of unilateral refusals to license.
II. THE KODAK AND CSU
DECISIONS
Panelists indicated that neither Kodak
nor CSU provides sufficient guidance on
potential antitrust liability for unilateral
refusals to license patents. Moreover, the
divergence in approaches taken by the
two decisions makes it difficult to
determine the contours of potential
liability for refusals to license patents and
thereby creates uncertainty for licensors
and licensees.
A. The Basic Facts and Holdings of the
Cases
The panelists framed the debate
about imposing antitrust liability for
unilateral refusals to license patents
around the Kodak and CSU opinions,
which raise many of the key issues.
Plaintiffs in both cases were independent
service organizations (“ISOs”) that sued
original equipment manufacturers
(“OEMs”), alleging the OEMs violated
section 2 of the Sherman Act by refusing
to sell patented parts and to license
patented and copyrighted software.
4
Plaintiffs’ theory in both cases was that
section 2 was violated because the
defendants each had a monopoly in a
relevant parts market and, by refusing to
supply parts to the ISOs, they were
extending their monopolies into the
servicing of their equipment.
In Kodak, the Ninth Circuit held that
a “reluctance to sell . . . patented or
copyrighted parts was a presumptively
legitimate business justification,” but the
“presumption may also be rebutted by
evidence of pretext.”
5
The court also held
that there was sufficient evidence of
pretext because the defendant refused to
sell both patented and unpatented parts
and was not even thinking about its
patent rights when it did so.
6
In contrast, the Federal Circuit in
CSU declined to consider the “patentee’s
subjective motivation for refusing to sell
or license its patented products,” in effect
making the presumption of a legitimate
business justification conclusive.
7
In
much discussed dictum, the court added
that a “patent holder may enforce the
statutory right to exclude others . . . free
from liability under the antitrust laws” in
4
In Kodak, the defendant’s refusal to deal did not
distinguish among parts on the basis of patent rights.
The Kodak court found that the defendant had
monopoly power in an “all parts” market, including
many parts not protected by patent rights. Kodak, 125
F.3d at 1219-20. In CSU, plaintiffs likewise alleged
refusals to deal extending to items not protected by
patent rights. The district court initially granted
summary judgment for the defendant for the refusal
to license patented parts, while explicitly reserving
judgment on the refusal to sell unpatented parts. In re
Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 964 F. Supp. 1479,
1490 & n.8 (D. Kan. 1997). Before the case went to the
Federal Circuit, plaintiffs conceded that they could
not prove antitrust injury only from the refusal to sell
unpatented parts, so the court granted summary
judgment on all antitrust claims. Order, In re Indep.
Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., No. MDL-1021 (D. Kan.
Jan. 8, 1999). Consequently, the only issue before the
Federal Circuit was whether the unilateral refusal to
sell or license patented parts could violate the
antitrust laws.
5
Kodak, 125 F.3d at 1219.
6
Id. at 1219-20.
7
CSU, 203 F.3d at 1327; May 1 Tr. at 19-26 (Gleklen);
Jonathan I. Gleklen, Antitrust Liability for Unilateral
Refusals to License Intellectual Property: Xerox and Its
Critics (May 1, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 2-4,
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020501gleklen.
pdf [hereinafter Gleklen Submission].
17
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
the “absence of any indication of illegal
tying, fraud in the Patent and Trademark
Office, or sham litigation.”
8
B. Panelist Views on Kodak
Panelists almost uniformly found
problematic Kodak’s subjective intent
standard. One panelist found it
“fundamentally flawed” because it would
permit a refusal to deal motivated by a
desire to protect return on research and
development (“R&D”) investment but
prohibit a refusal to deal motivated by the
practically indistinguishable desire to
maximize profit by excluding
competition.
9
This panelist also argued,
and others agreed, that there is no
limiting principle to the subjective
motivation inquiry.
10
Another panelist
argued that Kodak’s focus on subjective
motivation is out of step with modern
antitrust analysis’s focus on objective
economic aspects of conduct, rather than
on motive.
11
Yet another noted the
practical problems associated with an
intent-based test: “From a counseling
standpoint, the Ninth Circuit’s distinction
between legitimate and ‘pretextual’
assertions of patent rights is both
unworkable in practice and very difficult
to explain to business people who want to
know how to ensure that their activities
are lawful.”
12
And one panelist asserted
that the subjective motivation standard
would dramatically increase the costs of
enforcing intellectual property rights,
because intellectual property holders
facing refusal to license claims would not
be able to win motions to dismiss.
13
One panelist suggested reading the
Kodak decision to reject Kodak’s proffered
business justification as feeble and
belated.
14
Kodak’s staunchest defender on
the panel noted that other predatory
conduct is often associated with refusals
to license.
15
He argued that the Kodak
rule, augmented by a detailed analysis of
the market, is better than that in CSU,
because the Kodak rule does not immunize
patentees from antitrust liability when
they act anticompetitively; rather, it
balances the patent owner’s interests in
getting a return on innovation and the
public interest in competition. Moreover,
he asserted, refusal to license claims
would not wreak havoc in the business
world because it is difficult to prove
market power and anticompetitive
intent.
16
8
203 F.3d at 1327.
9
May 1 Tr. at 152-53 (Shapiro).
10
Id. at 152-54 (Shapiro); see also id. at 181-82
(MacKie-Mason); id. at 223-24, 228-31 (Whitener).
11
A. Douglas Melamed & Ali M. Stoeppelwerth, The
CSU Case: Facts, Formalism and the Intersection of
Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law, 10 GEO. MASON
L. REV. 407, 426-27 (2002); see also May 1 Tr. at 246-47
(Melamed) (proposing objective test for analyzing
refusals to deal that examines whether conduct made
“economic sense” but for its tendency to exclude a
rival).
12
Mark D. Whitener, Statement (May 1, 2002 Hr’g R.)
at 6, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020501whitener.pdf [hereinafter Whitener
Submission].
13
See May 1 Tr. at 38 (Gleklen).
14
Id. at 201-02 (Sprigman).
15
Paul F. Kirsch, Refusals to License IP – The
Perspective of the Private Plaintiff (May 1, 2002 Hr’g R.)
(slides) at 3, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020501kirsch.pdf [hereinafter Kirsch Presentation].
16
May 1 Tr. at 134-35, 137, 200-01 (Kirsch); see also
Kirsch Presentation at 7.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION18
As noted above, some have read
Kodak as giving undue weight to
defendant-patentees’ subjective intent. To
be sure, reliance on a defendant’s
subjective intent to determine whether a
refusal to license violates antitrust law
establishes a framework that is difficult to
administer.
17
Some commentators state
that finding a firm’s motive or intent
through employees’ statements is “both
impossible and meaningless, for the
documentary evidence of every large firm
will almost always provide ample
examples suggesting both kinds of
intent,” i.e., the intent to protect
intellectual property rights and the intent
to create or maintain a monopoly.
18
Such
a situation would be untenable, and the
Agencies do not believe the Ninth Circuit
should be read to have reached this
result. Accordingly, the Agencies’ “focus
is upon the effect of [the] conduct, not
upon the intent behind it.”
19
“[K]nowledge of intent may help [courts]
to interpret facts and to predict
consequences.”
20
C. Panelist Views on CSU
Two panelists interpreted CSU to
stand for the proposition that a refusal to
license is the exercise of the statutory
right to exclude others from making,
using, or selling a patented invention and
therefore cannot be deemed exclusionary
conduct.
21
Nevertheless, these panelists
were uneasy about the Federal Circuit’s
opinion.
22
They interpreted the dictum
quoted above
23
to identify three
exceptions to the purported general right
of a patent owner unilaterally to refuse to
license—illegal tying, fraud on the Patent
and Trademark Office, and sham
litigation.
24
One panelist criticized these
exceptions as providing insufficient
guidance because they identify potential
sources of antitrust liability that are
unrelated to unconditional, unilateral
refusals to license.
25
Another panelist argued that CSU’s
holding could protect anticompetitive
refusals to deal, citing a hypothetical
17
See, e.g., May 1 Tr. at 152 (Shapiro); id. at 181
(MacKie-Mason); id. at 229-30 (Whitener); R. Hewitt
Pate, Acting Assistant Attorney Gen., U.S. Dep’t of
Justice, Antitrust and Intellectual Property, Remarks
at the American Intellectual Property Law
Association 2003 Mid-Winter Institute 14 (Jan. 24,
2003) (criticizing the Ninth Circuit’s decision to
permit subjective inquiry into the intellectual
property holder’s motivations for refusing to deal),
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/ public/
speeches/200701.pdf. But see May 1 Tr. at 133-35
(Kirsch) (endorsing Ninth Circuit’s intent test).
18
3 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP,
ANTITRUST LAW: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST
PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION ¶ 709b2, at 222
(2d ed. 2002).
19
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 59 (D.C.
Cir. 2001) (en banc); see also R. Hewitt Pate, Refusals to
Deal and Intellectual Property Rights, 10 GEO. MASON L.
REV. 429, 440 (2002); Michelle M. Burtis & Bruce H.
Kobayashi, Why an Original Can Be Better than a Copy:
Intellectual Property, the Antitrust Refusal to Deal, and
ISO Antitrust Litigation, 9 SUPREME CT. ECON. REV.
143, 166 (2001) (noting the relevance of a patent
holder’s intent in certain refusal to deal cases
involving patented and unpatented parts).
20
Chi. Bd. of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238
(1918).
21
May 1 Tr. at 29-30 (Gleklen); id. at 231-35
(Whitener).
22
Id. at 25-26 (Gleklen); Gleklen Submission at 8-9,
15; Whitener Submission at 7-9 & n.14.
23
Supra note 8 and accompanying text.
24
May 1 Tr. at 25-26 (Gleklen); see id. at 232
(Whitener); CSU, 203 F.3d at 1327 n.7.
25
See May 1 Tr. at 25-27 (Gleklen); Gleklen
Submission at 8-9.
19
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
based on AT&T’s attempt to prevent MCI
from connecting to its network in the
1970s. He argued that, had AT&T
patented an interface necessary for its
competitors to interconnect with its
network, AT&T might not have been
obliged to open its network under CSU.
26
In this panelist’s view, CSU is inconsistent
with the trend of antitrust laws’ “move[]
away from the rigidities of formalism . . .
in favor of a fact-based analysis that
applies rigorous economic principles to
distinguish anticompetitive from
procompetitive conduct.”
27
A panelist also expressed concern
that CSU might be applied too broadly,
allowing a patent holder to attach
conditions to a license on the theory that
doing so was less restrictive than not
licensing at all.
28
A source of such
concerns was Townshend v. Rockwell
International Corp., a patent infringement
case involving the technology for the 56K
modem.
29
In assessing the defendant’s
antitrust counterclaim, the court reasoned
that “[b]ecause a patent owner has the
legal right to refuse to license his or her
patent on any terms, the existence of a
predicate condition to a license agreement
cannot state an antitrust violation.”
30
Concerns about such a lesser-included
rights rationale were expressed by many
panelists, including some who thought it
appropriate to grant antitrust immunity
to unconditional refusals to license.
31
Panelists also argued that conditional
refusals to license deserve antitrust
scrutiny because they can create
anticompetitive incentives that cannot be
created through unconditional refusals to
license.
32
Consequently, they argued, the
CSU decision combined with such a
lesser-included rights analysis could
effectively extend antitrust immunity to
all manner of restrictions, such as
exclusive dealing, cross-licensing
requirements, exclusive grantbacks, tying,
selective licensing, or even price-
fixing—clearly an undesirable result.
33
D. Ambiguity as to the Scope of the
Patent Grant
The Kodak and CSU opinions
recognized that the application of
antitrust law to unilateral refusals to
license sometimes requires a
determination of the scope of those
intellectual property rights. As the Ninth
Circuit put it, “the right of exclusion [does
not] protect an attempt to extend a lawful
monopoly beyond the grant of a patent.”
34
26
May 1 Tr. at 248-52 (Melamed); see also Melamed &
Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO. MASON L. REV. at 424.
27
Melamed & Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO. MASON L. REV.
at 425; see also May 1 Tr. at 252 (Melamed).
28
May 1 Tr. at 45 (Sprigman).
29
2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,890, 2000 WL 433505
(N.D. Cal. 2000).
30
Id. ¶ 72,890, at 87,634, 2000 WL 433505, at *8.
31
May 1 Tr. at 66-67 (Gleklen) (identifying price
fixing as beyond the statutory grant); see also id. at
232-34 (Whitener) (acknowledging that conduct other
than “pure” unilateral, unconditional refusals to deal
should not be treated as categorically legal).
32
Id. at 155 (Shapiro); see also id. at 204 (MacKie-
Mason) (asserting that distinguishing between
conditional and unconditional refusals is not always
easy).
33
See id. at 154-57 (Shapiro); id. at 45 (Sprigman); see
also 3 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 709c,
at 232-34 (identifying price-fixing, market division,
exclusive dealing, and reciprocity as categories of
suspect conditional refusals).
34
Kodak, 125 F.3d at 1216; see also CSU, 203 F.3d at
1327. But see Melamed & Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION20
The Kodak and CSU courts agreed that the
scope of the patent grant is not
coterminous with the bounds of the
relevant market, so the right to exclude
may permit a patent holder to maintain a
monopoly over not just the market for the
patented parts but possibly also over
closely related markets.
35
Neither court,
however, defined the scope of the patent
grant.
36
This omission led some panelists
to speculate about the appropriate
definition.
One panelist suggested that “outside
the statutory patent grantmay mean
that the refusal to license has innovation
effects that would prevent competition
after the patent has expired.
37
Another
suggested that so long as there is only a
refusal to allow others to make, use, offer
to sell, or sell something within the claims
of the patent, the patentee acts within the
statutory grant.
38
A third panelist
asserted that formal definitions are not
particularly illuminating and that the
phrase should mean nothing more than
that the patent owner can exploit
whatever power is lawfully obtained
through the intellectual property laws so
long as the owner does not sacrifice
profits for the strategic objective of
gaining more than the lawfully obtained
power.
39
Another panelist responded that
to make this determination someone
would have to decide how much return
firms should be able to get on their
intellectual property, but economics
provides no basis for doing so.
40
III. POLICY ISSUES RELATING TO
UNILATERAL REFUSALS TO
LICENSE
Panelists at the Hearing frequently
addressed four basic policy issues relating
to antitrust liability in the context of the
licensing of patents: Should antitrust law
accord special treatment to patents, or is
conventional antitrust analysis
sufficiently sensitive to the issues raised
by patents? Should a patent holder be
MASON L. REV. at 425-26 (arguing that there are “a
number of problems” with using the scope of the
patent grant to define a safe harbor for unilateral
refusals to license, e.g., making it difficult to define a
market involving a patented product and its
components, creating incentives to avoid otherwise
efficient vertical integration, and being inconsistent
with the contributory infringement patent doctrine).
35
Kodak, 125 F.3d at 1217 (“Parts and service here
have been proven separate markets in the antitrust
context, but this does not resolve the question [of]
whether the service market falls reasonably within
the patent . . . grant for the purpose of determining
the extent of the exclusive rights conveyed.”) (internal
quotation marks omitted); CSU, 203 F.3d at 1327 (“[A]
patent may confer the right to exclude competition
altogether in more than one antitrust market.”); id. at
1328 (“We answer the threshold question of whether
Xerox’s refusal to sell its patented parts exceeds the
scope of the patent grant in the negative.”); see also
May 1 Tr. at 179 (MacKie-Mason) (“[T]here is no
really good reason to believe the patent scope is the
same as the relevant antitrust market.”); Pate, 10 GEO.
MASON L. REV. at 441 (“A patent holder can lawfully
acquire more than one economic monopoly by
exercising the exclusionary power of a single patent,
and should not be found liable for exercising its
unilateral right to refuse to license or use its invention
in the markets where he holds these monopolies.
There is no unlawful extension of monopoly power
when a patent holder merely exercises its rights
inherent in the patent grant.”).
36
See May 1 Tr. at 25 (Gleklen) (“The Federal
Circuit’s decision focuses on whether [intellectual
property] was used to obtain monopoly power
outside the statutory grant without actually saying
. . . what is the statutory grant.”); Kodak, 125 F.3d at
1217 (discussing, but not defining, the concept of
patent scope).
37
May 1 Tr. at 65 (Sprigman).
38
Id. at 66 (Gleklen).
39
Id. at 69-70 (Melamed).
40
Id. at 180 (MacKie-Mason).
21
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
presumed to possess market power? Is
compulsory licensing a workable remedy
for a unilateral refusal to license patents?
And would prohibiting unilateral refusals
to license have a significant ill effect on
incentives to invest in innovation?
Panelists also offered some new
perspectives on the possible competitive
effects of unilateral refusals to license.
A. Should Antitrust Law Accord
Special Treatment to Patents?
Most panelists concluded that the
antitrust laws should be applied in the
same manner to intellectual and other
property.
41
One panelist noted that the
essence of a patent is the right to exclude
competitors, which he believed
distinguishes patents from other
property.
42
Others countered that the
right to exclude is an essential part of all
forms of property.
43
As one panelist
explained, “all forms of [commercial]
property . . . involve some investment to
create or protect the property . . . with the
hope of some financial return that has to
be based in some significant part on the
ability to exclude others.”
44
In this
panelist’s view there is no economic
reason to treat intellectual property
differently from other forms of property.
45
Courts have recognized that patents,
similar to other property rights, have
limits, and these limits are “narrowly and
strictly confined to the precise terms of
the grant.”
46
Courts have also held that
certain types of conduct involving patent
rights can result in antitrust liability. For
example, attempting to enforce a patent
obtained through fraud on the Patent and
Trademark Office may constitute
monopolization in violation of section 2
of the Sherman Act,
47
and the
demonstration of an objectively baseless
assertion of infringement can overcome a
Noerr defense.
48
Patent licensing terms
may constitute tying or price fixing in
violation of section 1 of the Sherman
Act.
49
41
“The Agencies apply the same general antitrust
principles to conduct involving intellectual property
that they apply to conduct involving any other form
of tangible or intangible property.” U.S. DEPT OF
JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, ANTITRUST
GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY § 2.1 (1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep.
(CCH) ¶ 13,132, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/
atr/public/guidelines/0558.pdf [hereinafter
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES]. Special characteristics of
intellectual property, “such as ease of
misappropriation” can “distinguish it from many
other forms of property” and “can be taken into
account by standard antitrust analysis.” Id.
42
See May 1 Tr. at 30 (Gleklen).
43
E.g., id. at 47 (Sprigman).
44
Id. at 143-44 (Shapiro).
45
Id. at 143-46 (Shapiro).
46
Mercoid Corp. v. Mid-Continent Inv. Co., 320 U.S.
661, 665 (1944).
47
See Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem.
Corp., 382 U.S. 172, 177-80 (1965).
48
See Prof’l Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia
Pictures Indus., Inc., 508 U.S. 49 (1993) (construing E.
R.R. Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc.,
365 U.S. 127 (1961)).
49
See United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287,
308-15 (1948) (price fixing); Int’l Salt Co. v. United
States, 332 U.S. 392, 395-96 (1947) (tying); United States
v. Masonite Corp., 316 U.S. 265, 274-80 (1942) (price
fixing); United States v. Univis Lens Co., 316 U.S. 241,
250-54 (1942) (price fixing); Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v.
United States, 309 U.S. 436, 452-59 (1940) (price fixing).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION22
B. Should Market Power Be Presumed
with Patents?
With respect to many violations of
the antitrust laws, the possession of
market or monopoly power is an element
of the offense. When analyzing the
defendant OEMs’ refusals to license their
patents, neither Kodak nor CSU presumed
the defendants had market power on the
basis of the patents.
50
Similarly, the
Agencies have stated that, when
analyzing agreements to license, they do
not presume that a patent owner has
market power.
51
And the U.S. Supreme
Court recently agreed.
52
Although a
patent gives the patent owner the right to
exclude others from making, using, or
selling a particular product or process, the
existence of close substitutes for the
product or process may prevent the
patent owner from exercising market
power. As the Solicitor General recently
explained: “[T]he Patent and Trademark
Office has issued scores of patents for
items such as bottle openers,
toothbrushes, and paper clips. It would
be implausible to presume that the owner
of such a patent possesses market power
merely by virtue of the patent.”
53
If a patent does result in market
power, that alone does not necessarily
create a violation. The Supreme Court
has made clear that “[t]he mere
possession of monopoly power, and the
concomitant charging of monopoly
prices,” is not unlawful “unless it is
accompanied by an element of
anticompetitive conduct.”
54
C. If an Antitrust Violation Were
Found, Would There Be Workable
Remedies for Unconditional,
Unilateral Refusals to License
Patents?
If a unilateral refusal to license
patents were found to violate the antitrust
laws, one appropriate remedy likely
would entail compulsory licensing. Some
panelists argued that the courts and
Agencies are not well-equipped to
determine appropriate licensing terms
and conditions and, as a result,
compulsory licensing would be
problematic.
55
Another panelist noted
50
CSU, 203 F.3d at 1325 (“A patent alone does not
demonstrate market power.”); see also Kodak, 125 F.3d
at 1202-08, 1219 (stating that Kodak possessed
monopoly power in “all parts” market).
51
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.2.
52
Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281,
1284 (2006) (“[T]he mere fact that a tying product is
patented does not support [a market power]
presumption.”).
53
Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae
Supporting Petitioners at 12, Ill. Tool Works Inc., 126 S.
Ct. 1281 (No. 04-1329) (citation omitted), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2005/3mer/1ami
/2004-1329.mer.ami.pdf.
54
Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004); see also Blue Cross
& Blue Shield United v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406,
1413 (7th Cir. 1995) (Posner, C.J.) (“[A lawful
monopolist may] charge any price that it wants, for
the antitrust laws are not a price-control statute or a
public-utility or common-carrier rate-regulation
statute.”) (citations omitted); Kartell v. Blue Shield of
Mass., Inc., 749 F.2d 922, 927 (1st Cir. 1984) (Breyer, J.)
(“[E]ven a monopolist is free to exploit whatever
market power it may possess when that exploitation
takes the form of charging uncompetitive prices.”).
55
May 1 Tr. at 146-47 (Shapiro); Whitener
Submission at 10; see also May 1 Tr. at 149 (Shapiro)
(urging the Agencies not to impose a regulatory
scheme through the antitrust laws in lieu of dealing
with the underlying issue of reforming the patent
system, if the patents at issue are perceived to be “bad
patents”). A licensor’s moral or ethical objections to
licensing a specific potential licensee would add to
the difficulties of determining appropriate
compensation for a compulsory license.
23
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
that compulsory licensing might not work
because transfer of some technologies
requires not only a patent license, but also
the transfer of related know-how, and it
may be difficult for courts to enforce a
requirement that this know-how be
transferred.
56
Moreover, if compulsory
licensing is a generally available remedy
for unconditional, unilateral refusals to
license patents, this panelist argued, firms
may shift their strategies away from filing
patents and toward reliance on trade
secrets. Such an outcome would be
unfortunate, he said, because patents
enable more effective disclosure of
knowledge and therefore make licensing
easier.
57
Some panelists thought these
concerns were overstated and that courts,
which set licensing rates in other contexts
(such as infringement suits), could do so
in this context as well or, alternatively,
could send the parties back to the
bargaining table.
58
In response, other
panelists objected to this analogy, arguing
that trying to calculate a forward-looking
price is more difficult than what courts
currently do—i.e., make the plaintiff
whole for past actions.
59
One panelist
noted that markets for voluntary licensing
typically arise when intellectual property
rights are well defined, and that when
these markets for technology exist, courts
could observe a market price of the
technology for the purpose of compulsory
licensing.
60
Most panelists appeared to take for
granted that court-ordered licensing
would occur at royalty rates far less than
those a monopolist would charge. The
Supreme Court has made clear, however,
that—consistent with the view of the
Agencies—the mere possession of lawful
monopoly power, and the concomitant
charging of monopoly prices, is not only
lawful, it is an important element of the
free-market system.
61
D. What Would Be the Effect of
Liability for Refusals to License
Patents on Incentives to
Innovate?
Some participants argued that
innovation is reduced by the risk of
compulsory licensing at royalties far
below monopoly levels, royalties which
may not be sufficient to cover the research
and development expenses that led to the
patented invention.
62
By contrast, those
who favored liability for some refusals to
license patents were not convinced that
antitrust liability would have a negative
56
May 1 Tr. at 101 (Arora); see also id. at 125
(Shapiro).
57
Id. at 102 (Arora).
58
Id. at 184-85 (Sprigman); id. at 55 (Sprigman)
(suggesting the imposition of the same rates as those
for similarly situated licensees); id. at 187 (Melamed)
(explaining that precision is not terribly important
when converting a property rule into a liability rule).
59
May 1 Tr. at 188 (Gleklen); see also id. at 189
(Whitener).
60
See id. at 94-102 (Arora); Ashish Arora, Refusal to
License: A Transaction Approach (May 1, 2002 Hr’g R.)
(slides) at 3, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020501arora.pdf.
61
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407.
62
May 1 Tr. at 228 (Whitener); see also Carl Shapiro,
Competition Policy and Innovation 13 (Organisation for
Econ. Co-operation and Dev., STI Working Paper No.
2002/11, 2002) (submitted as part of the May 1, 2002
Hr’g R.), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020501carlshapiro.pdf [hereinafter Shapiro
Submission].
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION24
effect on innovation
63
or were skeptical of
society’s ability to determine the
appropriate balance between innovation
and exclusion. One panelist asked
“whether innovation incentives are
sufficiently sensitive at the kinds of
margins we’re talking about of narrow
refusal to deal liability [such] that we can
reliably say across industries that there is
going to be any significant incentive
diminution at all.”
64
E. Competitive Effects of Refusals to
License Patents
Two panelists argued that
apparent refusals to license intellectual
property may really be attempts to license
it at high prices and to engage in price
discrimination.
65
They observed that
price discrimination can be good for
consumers, allowing markets or
consumers to be served that otherwise
would not have been.
66
Therefore, they
contended, imposing antitrust liability for
a refusal to license may prevent socially
beneficial price discrimination.
67
Another panelist responded to the
argument that only “one monopoly rent”
can be extracted by pointing out that an
intellectual property monopolist may
have difficulty exploiting its monopoly
unless it restricts competition
downstream by making a credible
commitment to restrict or refuse
licenses.
68
Without such commitments, he
suggested, the potential licensees would
know that the intellectual property owner
would have the incentive to sell
additional licenses and thus continue to
create competition, and erode profits, in
the downstream market. Knowing this,
potential licensees would be willing to
pay less for a license and invest less in the
licensed invention. This panelist
observed that, if the intellectual property
holder is able credibly to commit to
selling a limited number of licenses, and
thus to limiting competition in the
downstream market, each potential
licensee will be willing to pay more for a
license.
69
The licensee also may be willing
to invest more in the licensed invention as
a result of the intellectual property
holder’s restriction on the number of
licenses sold.
70
The intellectual property
holder maximizes its return by choosing
its licensing terms optimally,
71
and “the
upstream monopolist in practice will find
it difficult to fully exploit its market
power without some form of exclusion.
72
63
May 1 Tr. at 136-37 (Kirsch); Kirsch Presentation at
9.
64
May 1 Tr. at 56-57 (Sprigman) (emphasis added).
65
Id. at 80-81 (Wiley); id. at 81-94 (Klein).
66
Id. at 89-90 (Klein); see also id. at 81 (Wiley).
67
See Benjamin Klein & John Shepard Wiley Jr.,
Competitive Price Discrimination as an Antitrust
Justification for Intellectual Property Refusals to Deal, 70
ANTITRUST L.J. 599, 640-42 (2003).
68
May 22 Hr’g Tr., Refusals to License and
Compulsory Licensing in the European Union,
Canada, and Australia (Morning Session) at 33-37
(Rey), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020522trans.pdf.
69
Id. at 36-37 (Rey).
70
See also ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.3 (recognizing
that licensing arrangements involving exclusivity can
encourage licensees to invest in the products
embodying the licensed IP and to engage in follow-on
innovation).
71
See May 22 Tr. at 34, 36-38 (Rey); Patrick Rey &
Jean Tirole, A Primer on Foreclosure (May 22 Hr’g R.) at
7-8, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020522reydoc.pdf.
72
May 22 Tr. at 32 (Rey).
25
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
The panelist argued that the ability to
exploit an intellectual property bottleneck
may generate important incentives to
innovate and cautioned that regulating
the exploitation of intellectual property
amounts to regulating the return on R&D
investment and is a very difficult
economic exercise.
73
IV. LEGAL ANALYSIS OF
UNILATERAL REFUSALS TO
LICENSE PATENTS
Imposing antitrust liability for
unilateral refusals to deal raises a variety
of legal issues. A threshold question is
whether a 1988 amendment to the Patent
Act impliedly created an immunity when
it restricted misuse defenses to
infringement claims. More fundamental
is the question of how the basic statutory
right to exclude relates to unilateral
refusal to deal claims and to other
antitrust claims involving patent
licensing.
A. Does Section 271(d)(4) of Title 35
of the U.S. Code Create an
Immunity for Unilateral Refusals
to License Patents?
Panelists extensively discussed the
import of section 271(d)(4) of Title 35 of
the U.S. Code, added by a 1988
amendment to the Patent Act, which
provides that “[n]o patent owner
otherwise entitled to relief for
infringement or contributory
infringement of a patent shall be denied
relief or deemed guilty of misuse or
illegal extension of the patent right by
reason of his having . . . refused to license
or use any rights to the patent . . . .”
74
One panelist argued that the 1988
amendment granted antitrust immunity
for refusals to license patents.
75
Other
panelists concluded that the amendment
on its face does not apply to antitrust
claims.
76
In Illinois Tool Works Inc. v.
Independent Ink, Inc., for example, the
Supreme Court stated that “the 1988
amendment does not expressly refer to
the antitrust laws.”
77
Under this view, the
provision does not govern whether
antitrust claims challenging the patentee’s
refusal to license are viable.
Proponents of a broader reading of
section 271(d)(4) sometimes note that the
provision refers to both “misuse” and
“illegal extension of the patent right.” To
73
See id. at 41-42 (Rey) (stating it is prudent to be
“more tolerant” when a bottleneck “is the result of
innovation” as opposed to economies of scale or
historical accident).
74
35 U.S.C. § 271(d) (2000).
75
May 1 Tr. at 33-35 (Gleklen); Jonathan I. Gleklen,
Unilateral Refusals to License IP (May 1, 2002 Hr’g R.)
(slides) at 11, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020501gleklenppt.pdf.
76
May 1 Tr. at 51-52 (Sprigman); Melamed &
Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO. MASON L. REV. at 410-12.
77
126 S. Ct. at 1290-91; Scheiber v. Dolby Labs., Inc., 293
F.3d 1014, 1019 (7th Cir. 2002) (Posner, C.J.)
(construing language of section 271(d) to govern only
actions based on infringement); Kodak, 125 F.3d at
1214 n.7 (“[The provision at best] indicate[s]
congressional intent to protect the core patent right of
exclusion.”); see also Brief for the United States as
Amicus Curiae at 12 n.6, CSU, 531 U.S. 1143 (2001)
(No. 00-62) (“On its face [section 271(d)] does not
address antitrust liability for monopolization or
attempted monopolization by refusal to deal.”),
denying cert. to 203 F.3d 1322, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2000/2pet/6invit
/2000-0062.pet.ami.inv.pdf. But cf. CSU, 203 F.3d at
1326 (citing section 271(d) as support for a “patentee’s
right to exclude”); Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195
F.3d 1346, 1362 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (citing section
271(d)(4)).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION26
save the latter phrase from being
“surplusage,” they read that language to
“refer to unlawfulness other than misuse,
and the obvious extension is to antitrust
violations.”
78
But Congress might have
used the phrases “illegal extension of the
patent right” and “misuse” to describe
different aspects of the doctrine of patent
misuse.
79
This would be consistent with
the notion that, had Congress intended to
refer to antitrust violations or claims, it
could have done so explicitly.
80
Moreover, courts have held that section
271(d)(4)’s companion provision, section
271(d)(5), does not immunize patentees
from antitrust liability for the conduct it
governs—conditioning a license, or sale
of a patented product, on the purchase of
some other product or the taking of some
other license
81
—and it would seem
anomalous to read the phrase “illegal
extension of the patent right” to
immunize patentees from antitrust
liability for their refusals to license, but
not for such conditioning of licenses.
Others who read section 271(d)(4)
to grant antitrust immunity contend that
it would “make[] little sense to preclude
an infringer from asserting a misuse
defense based on a patent holder’s refusal
to deal while simultaneously allowing the
infringer to recover treble damages under
the antitrust laws for the very same
conduct.”
82
But nothing precludes a
reading of the statute to permit treble
damages but not the rather different
consequences of a misuse holding (i.e.,
barring enforcement of the patent against
anyone until the misuse is purged).
The Agencies weigh these
opposing arguments against the backdrop
of the well-established principle that
immunity from antitrust laws is both
exceptional and disfavored.
83
Absent
78
3 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 709c, at
234 n.71; see also May 1 Tr. at 34-35 (Gleklen); CSU,
203 F.3d at 1326 (emphasizing the phrase “illegal
extension of the patent right” in section 271(d) in
arguing that the provision supports “patentee’s right
to exclude”); Sharon Brawner McCullen, The Federal
Circuit and Ninth Circuit Face-Off: Does a Patent Holder
Violate the Sherman Act by Unilaterally Excluding Others
from a Patented Invention in More than One Relevant
Market?, 74 TEMP. L. REV. 469, 494 & n.254 (2001)
(“The Supreme Court has repeatedly used the
language of whether the patent holder’s actions have
‘expanded’ or ‘enlarge[d]’ the patent grant to analyze
allegations of antitrust violations.”).
79
“The reference to ‘illegal extension of the patent
right’ as well as ‘misuse’ recognizes the differing
formulations of activity deemed to be ‘misuse’ and
that misuse is often characterized as illegal extension
of the patent right.” S. REP. No. 100-492, at 19 (1988).
(No committee report on the 1988 amendment exists.
The cited report describes an earlier bill containing
the “illegal extension” language now appearing in
section 271(d)(4)). See also USM Corp. v. SPS Techs.,
Inc., 694 F.2d 505, 510-12 (7th Cir. 1982) (discussing
how the patent misuse doctrine could go beyond the
specific practices thought to extend the patent right).
80
Cf. Scheiber, 293 F.3d at 1019-21 (construing another
provision of section 271(d) in light of this principle).
81
See, e.g., id. at 1019-20 (finding section 271(d)(5)
inapplicable because the provision “merely limits
defenses to infringement suits”); Grid Sys. Corp. v.
Tex. Instruments Inc., 771 F. Supp. 1033, 1037 n.2 (N.D.
Cal. 1991) (rejecting argument that section 271(d)(5)
affects antitrust claims, noting that the provision
“relates only to the defense of patent misuse as a
defense to an infringement claim”).
82
In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 989 F. Supp.
1131, 1136 (D. Kan. 1997); see also May 1 Tr. at 35
(Gleklen); Peter M. Boyle, Penelope M. Lister & J.
Clayton Everett, Jr., Antitrust Law at the Federal Circuit:
Red Light or Green Light at the IP-Antitrust Intersection?,
69 ANTITRUST L.J. 739, 749 (2001).
83
Oversight of Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws Before
the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Business Rights, and
Competition of the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 107th
Cong. 134 (2002) (statement of the Federal Trade
Commission), available at
27
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
“clear, express Congressional intent to
immunize conduct or . . . repugnancy
between some other body of law and
antitrust,” a finding of immunity is
unwarranted.
84
The United States Court
of Appeals for the First Circuit, rejecting
antitrust immunity for copyright holders’
refusals to license, noted that “the
Sherman Act does not explicitly exempt
[the protection of original works of
authorship] from antitrust scrutiny and
courts should be wary of creating implied
exemptions.”
85
The Agencies approach
the interpretation of section 271(d)(4)
with the same wariness. Nothing in
section 271(d)(4) expressly addresses
whether a unilateral and unconditional
refusal to license could give rise to
antitrust liability.
86
The section can
perhaps be said to shed some light on
Congress’s view of the nature of the
patent right. But the Agencies do not
read the statute to create antitrust
immunity for such refusals to license.
B. When Do Refusals to License
Patents Violate the Antitrust
Laws?
As a threshold matter, antitrust
liability for refusal to assist
competitors—whether by licensing
patents or otherwise—is a rare exception
to the ordinary rules of antitrust. As
expressed in United States v. Colgate & Co.,
the Sherman Act generally “does not
restrict the long recognized right of [a]
trader or manufacturer engaged in an
entirely private business, freely to
exercise [its] own independent discretion
as to parties with whom [it] will deal.”
87
Although this right to refuse to deal is not
unqualified,
88
the Supreme Court stated
in Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law
Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP that it has
“been very cautious in recognizing such
exceptions, because of the uncertain
virtue of forced sharing and the difficulty
of identifying and remedying
anticompetitive conduct by a single
firm.”
89
The Trinko Court articulated three
reasons why requiring firms to “share the
source of their advantage” with rivals is
“in some tension with the underlying
purpose of antitrust law.”
90
First,
compelling firms to share “may lessen the
incentive for the monopolist, the rival, or
both to invest in . . . economically
http://a257.g.akamaitech.net/7/257/2422/03jul2003
1230/www.access.gpo.gov/congress/senate/pdf/10
7hrg/87867.pdf; May 1 Tr. at 237 (Melamed); see also
Square D Co. v. Niagara Frontier Tariff Bureau, Inc., 476
U.S. 409, 421 (1986) (“[E]xemptions from the antitrust
laws are strictly construed and strongly disfavored.”).
84
May 1 Tr. at 238 (Melamed).
85
Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp., 36
F.3d 1147, 1185 (1st Cir. 1994).
86
Cf. Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1290 (recognizing that “[35
U.S.C. § 271(d)(5)] does not expressly refer to the
antitrust laws”).
87
250 U.S. 300, 307 (1919).
88
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472
U.S. 585, 601 (1985).
89
540 U.S. at 408 (concluding that Verizon’s alleged
failure to provide adequate assistance to its rivals did
not state an antitrust claim). The case involved a
regulatory scheme that required incumbent local
telephone companies to give certain forms of access to
their networks to competitors. Id. at 401, 412-13. In
reaching its decision, the Court stated that it had
“never recognized [the essential facilities] doctrine”
created by lower courts and had no need to decide
the issue in this case. Id. at 411.
90
Id. at 407-08; see also id. at 399 (“Traditional
antitrust principles do not justify adding [Trinko] to
the few existing exceptions from the proposition that
there is no duty to aid competitors.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION28
beneficial facilities.”
91
Second, “[e]nforced
sharing also requires antitrust courts to
act as central planners, identifying the
proper price, quantity, and other terms of
dealing—a role for which they are ill-
suited.”
92
Finally, “compelling
negotiation between competitors may
facilitate the supreme evil of antitrust:
collusion.”
93
Indeed, imposing liability
for such refusals arguably would go
beyond requiring firms to refrain from
anticompetitive conduct that harms rivals
and would instead compel firms to reach
out and affirmatively assist their rivals.
The Trinko Court’s description of
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing
Corp.
94
as being “at or near the outer
boundary of [section] 2 liability”
95
confirms that unilateral refusals to deal
are rarely anticompetitive, whether or not
they involve patents.
96
This suggests that
Aspen Skiing will not support liability for
unilateral refusals to license patents to
rivals, except, perhaps, when a patent
owner refuses to continue to license
under circumstances paralleling those
presented in Aspen.
97
91
Id. at 407-08.
92
Id. at 408.
93
Id.
94
472 U.S. 585 (1985). The facts of Aspen are
described in Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408-09 (“The Aspen
ski area consisted of four mountain areas. The
defendant, who owned three of those areas, and the
plaintiff, who owned the fourth, had cooperated for
years in the issuance of a joint, multiple-day, all-area
ski ticket. After repeatedly demanding an increased
share of the proceeds, the defendant canceled the
joint ticket. The plaintiff, concerned that skiers would
bypass its mountain without some joint offering, tried
a variety of increasingly desperate measures to re-
create the joint ticket, even to the point of in effect
offering to buy the defendant’s tickets at retail price.
The defendant refused even that. We upheld a jury
verdict for the plaintiff, reasoning that ‘[t]he jury may
well have concluded that [the defendant] elected to
forgo these short-run benefits because it was more
interested in reducing competition . . . over the long
run by harming its smaller competitor.’ Aspen Skiing
is at or near the outer boundary of [section] 2
liability.”) (citations omitted).
95
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409.
96
See Brief for the United States and the Federal
Trade Commission as Amici Curiae Supporting
Petitioner at 15, Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (No. 02-682)
(noting that section 2 of the Sherman Act is violated
only by conduct properly considered “exclusionary
or predatory,” and proposing that, when “the
plaintiff asserts that the defendant was under a duty
to assist a rival, . . . conduct is not exclusionary or
predatory unless it would make no economic sense for
the defendant but for its tendency to eliminate or
lessen competition”), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f201000/201048.p
df. In Trinko, the Supreme Court did not adopt a
specific standard, but it stressed the very facts in
Aspen Skiing that suggest a section 2 violation under
the Agencies’ proposed standard. Trinko, 540 U.S. at
409 (“The unilateral termination of a voluntary (and
thus presumably profitable) course of dealing suggested
a willingness to forsake short-term profits to achieve
an anticompetitive end. Similarly, the defendant’s
unwillingness to renew the ticket even if compensated
at retail price revealed a distinctly anticompetitive
bent.”) (citation omitted).
97
One panelist articulated possible reasons for
imposing a duty to continue to license: (1) the
licensing arrangement has been shown to be feasible,
(2) there is an existing template for the terms and
conditions of the license, and (3) licensees have relied
on the expectation of such dealing. May 1 Tr. at 158
(Shapiro) (listing arguments for (and against)
imposing liability for a refusal to license intellectual
property in the context of a historical course of
dealing). That same panelist, however, along with
others, raised several arguments against imposing
liability for terminating a prior course of conduct.
Some noted that relying on a prior course of conduct
might unfairly punish licensors who legitimately
desire to change their licensing practices. Id. at 117-18
(Whitener); id. at 118-20 (Gleklen); see also id. at 158-60
(Shapiro). In addition, one panelist noted that there
can be countervailing legitimate reasons to refuse to
license, e.g., protecting a trade secret. Melamed &
Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO. MASON L. REV. at 420.
Furthermore, as one panelist mentioned, rather than
counting on broad antitrust protection, which might
have adverse effects on competition by significantly
constraining the dealings of the patent holder, third
29
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
A central question is whether “the
few existing exceptions [to] the
proposition that there is no duty to aid
competitors”
98
should include an antitrust
limitation on unilateral, unconditional
refusals to offer a patent license to a
competitor. Some panelists favored a
categorical exemption from antitrust
liability for unilateral, unconditional
refusals to license.
99
One panelist noted
that the essence of a patent is the right to
exclude competitors, which he believed
distinguishes patents from other
property.
100
Other panelists favored
allowing liability for unilateral,
unconditional refusals to license under
narrow circumstances, with such refusals
assessed on a case-specific, fact-intensive
basis, without safe harbors.
101
Panelists
who favored antitrust liability for
unilateral refusals to license suggested a
liability rule based on Aspen Skiing,
102
or
broad antitrust principles for identifying
anticompetitive conduct.
103
The owner of a patent has the
statutory “right to exclude others from
making, using, offering for sale, or selling
the invention.”
104
That right has been
described as “the essence” of a patent
grant,
105
and a line of Supreme Court and
courts of appeals cases extending back a
century suggests that exercising that right
by refusing to license a patent, without
more, would not violate the antitrust
laws.
106
None of the Supreme Court cases
parties should seek explicit commitments before
making investments in reliance on a continuing duty
to deal. May 1 Tr. at 157-59 (Shapiro).
98
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411.
99
May 1 Tr. at 41-42 (Gleklen); id. at 233-35
(Whitener); Whitener Submission at 14-15.
100
See May 1 Tr. at 30 (Gleklen). But see supra Part
III.A.
101
Melamed & Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO. MASON L.
REV. at 423-27; May 1 Tr. at 134-35, 200 (Kirsch); id. at
163, 168, 172-73 (MacKie-Mason); id. at 242
(Melamed); id. at 59, 202, 206-07 (Sprigman).
102
May 1 Tr. at 51 (Sprigman).
103
Melamed & Stoeppelwerth, 10 GEO. MASON L.
REV. at 419 (“[A]nticompetitive conduct is conduct
that serves no legitimate purpose, or is itself
unprofitable, and is undertaken in order to exclude or
weaken competitors in anticipation of increased
market power and resulting supracompetitive
recoupment.”); May 1 Tr. at 242-46 (Melamed); id. at
121-22 (Sprigman). Another panelist questioned how
the concept of recoupment would apply when the
conduct at issue is a decision not to give up patented
property, asking: “Is it recoupment if I make more
money in servicing equipment because I didn’t sell
my patented parts to ISOs?” Id. at 208-09 (Whitener).
104
35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(1) (2000).
105
Dawson Chem. Co. v. Rohm & Haas Co., 448 U.S. 176,
215 (1980) (“[T]he essence of a patent grant is the
right to exclude others from profiting by the patented
invention.”); cf. eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126
S. Ct. 1837, 1840 (2006) (“[T]he creation of a right is
distinct from the provision of remedies for violations
of that right.”).
106
Hartford-Empire Co. v. United States, 323 U.S. 386,
432 (1945) (“A patent owner is not in the position of a
quasi-trustee for the public or under any obligation to
see that the public acquires the free right to use the
invention. He has no obligation either to use it or to
grant its use to others.”); Mercoid, 320 U.S. at 666
(“The fact that the patentee has the power to refuse a
license does not enable him to enlarge the monopoly
. . . .”); United States v. United Shoe Mach. Co. of N.J.,
247 U.S. 32, 57 (1918) (“[A patent’s] strength is in the
restraint, the right to exclude others from the use of
the invention . . . . Its exertion within the field . . . is
not an offense against the Anti-Trust Act.”); Bement v.
Nat’l Harrow Co., 186 U.S. 70, 90 (1902) (“[A
patentee’s] title is exclusive, and so clearly within the
constitutional provisions in respect of private
property that he is neither bound to use his discovery
himself nor permit others to use it.” (quoting Heaton-
Peninsular Button-Fastener Co. v. Eureka Specialty Co.,
77 F. 288, 295 (6th Cir. 1896))); see also Intergraph, 195
F.3d at 1362 (“[T]he antitrust laws do not negate the
patentee’s right to exclude others from patent
property.”); Data Gen. Corp., 36 F.3d at 1186 (“[In the
context of a unilateral refusal to license copyrights,]
[t]he courts appear to have partly settled an
analogous conflict between the patent laws and the
antitrust laws, treating the former as creating an
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION30
squarely holds that the unilateral refusal
to license a patent could never violate the
antitrust laws, or that the antitrust laws
should be applied in a different manner to
intellectual and other property,
107
but the
strong statements in these cases are
indicative of the traditional
understanding that the unilateral right to
decline the grant of a license is a core part
of the patent grant. Prior to Kodak, no
reported federal antitrust decision had
imposed liability for the refusal to license
a patent.
108
Even in the controversial
Kodak case itself, the outcome might be
explained as a result of Kodak’s refusal to
sell thousands of unpatented parts.
109
Taking all of the relevant factors
together—including the fact that no case
supported this type of antitrust liability
before Kodak, and the silence of section
271(d)(4) on the issue, the Agencies
conclude that liability for mere
unconditional, unilateral refusals to
license will not play a meaningful part in
the interface between patent rights and
antitrust protections. Of course, there are
numerous imaginable scenarios that
involve conduct that goes beyond a mere
refusal to license a patent and could give
rise to antitrust liability.
110
In Motion
Picture Patents Co. v. Universal Film
Manufacturing Co.,
111
the Supreme Court
implied limited exception to the latter.”); Miller
Insituform, Inc. v. Insituform of N. Am., Inc., 830 F.2d
606, 609 (6th Cir. 1987) (“A patent holder who
lawfully acquires a patent cannot be held liable under
Section 2 of the Sherman Act for maintaining the
monopoly power he lawfully acquired by refusing to
license the patent to others.”); United States v.
Westinghouse Elec. Corp., 648 F.2d 642, 647 (9th Cir.
1981) (“The right to license [a] patent, exclusively or
otherwise, or to refuse to license at all, is ‘the
untrammeled right’ of the patentee.”); SCM Corp. v.
Xerox Corp., 645 F.2d 1195, 1204 (2d Cir. 1981)
(“Where a patent holder . . . merely exercises his
‘right to exclude others from making, using, or selling
the invention’ by refusing unilaterally to license his
patent . . . such conduct is expressly permitted by the
patent laws.”(quoting 35 U.S.C. § 154)) (citation
omitted); id. at 1206 (“[W]here a patent has been
lawfully acquired, subsequent conduct permissible
under the patent laws cannot trigger any liability
under the antitrust laws.”). The most widely quoted
dictum may be that of Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of Cal.,
which indicated that “[t]he patent laws which give a
[temporary] monopoly on ‘making, using, or selling
the invention’ are in pari materia with the antitrust
laws and modify them pro tanto.” 377 U.S. 13, 24
(1964). The apparent meaning of this statement is
that the patent laws effectively modify the antitrust
laws to the extent, and only to the extent, of
precluding liability for the mere exclusion of others
from making, using, or selling the patented invention.
107
See supra notes 46-49 and accompanying text.
108
See Herbert Hovenkamp, Mark D. Janis, & Mark
A. Lemley, Unilateral Refusals to License, 2 J.
COMPETITION L. & ECON. 1, 42 (2006) (“Courts are
properly extremely reluctant to find liability on the
basis of a company’s unilateral refusal to deal, even if
that company is a monopolist. That reluctance is
even stronger when a refusal to license intellectual
property rights is at stake, because the ability to
exclude others from using the right is at the heart of
IP policy.”).
109
Although Kodak might be read to suggest that the
Ninth Circuit was consciously departing from the line
of cases indicating that the refusal to license a patent
would not violate the antitrust laws, that
interpretation may be mistaken. Technically, the
Kodak court addressed whether it was harmless error
for the district court’s instructions to the jury to have
given no weight to Kodak’s patents on sixty-five of
the thousands of parts at issue. 125 F.3d at 1214,
1218-20. In light of the court’s remarks concerning
the plaintiffs’ claimed “all parts” market, id. at 1220, it
is not clear that Kodak is properly described as
imposing antitrust liability for a refusal to license
patents. Moreover, as noted above, the Kodak
decision has been criticized, even by those who
would prefer to depart from those cases indicating
that the mere refusal to license does not support
antitrust liability. See supra Part II.B.
110
See, e.g., Cont’l Ore Co. v. Union Carbide & Carbon
Corp., 370 U.S. 690, 698-99 (1962) (stating that a jury
must be allowed to consider evidence of alleged
collusive conduct by defendants, including concerted
refusal to deal).
111
243 U.S. 502 (1917).
31
Unilateral Refusals to License Patents
rejected the theory that “since the
patentee may withhold his patent
altogether from public use he must
logically and necessarily be permitted to
impose any conditions which he chooses
upon any use which he may allow of
it.”
112
The Court explained that the
“defect in this thinking springs from the
substituting of inference and argument
for the language of the statute and from
failure to distinguish between the rights
which are given to the inventor by the
patent law and which he may assert
against all the world through an
infringement proceeding, and rights
which he may create for himself by
private contract which, however, are
subject to the rules of general [law] as
distinguished from those of the patent
law.”
113
Conduct going beyond a mere
refusal thus may merit scrutiny under the
antitrust laws.
114
As noted above, the
terms of a license agreement are subject to
section 1 of the Sherman Act, which
“reaches unreasonable restraints of trade
effected by a ‘contract, combination . . . or
conspiracy.’”
115
V. CONCLUSION
Whether, and if so when, to impose
antitrust liability for unconditional,
unilateral refusals to license patents has
been a subject of much debate among
antitrust and patent law practitioners and
policymakers. At the Hearing, panelists
offered widely differing views on the
relevant economic, policy, and legal
issues. Some panelists favored antitrust
liability for unilateral, unconditional
refusals to license under narrow
circumstances, with such refusals
assessed on a case-specific, fact-intensive
basis, without formalistic rules or safe
harbors.
116
Others favored a categorical
exemption from antitrust liability for
unilateral, unconditional refusals to
license.
117
Panelists agreed that
conditional refusals to license could cause
competitive harm and should not be
immune from antitrust liability. Panelists
also agreed that the judicial decisions do
not provide satisfactory guidance. All but
one panelist found the subjective
112
Id. at 514.
113
Id.
114
Hovenkamp et al., 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. at
37-38 (“The maker of a product is generally free to
decide to whom it will sell, and to terminate its
buyers at will, but this right does not include the right
to impose certain types of conditions on those
buyers—notably, but not exclusively, tying
arrangements and resale price restrictions.”) (footnote
omitted).
115
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467
U.S. 752, 768 (1984) (quoting section 1 of the Sherman
Act). The applicability of section 1 to agreements
related to patents was made clear by Motion Picture
Patents, 243 U.S. at 514. Moreover, no provision of
the Patent Act on its face grants patentees
untrammeled rights to do as they wish with patented
inventions. The basic right of patentees is the right to
exclude others from making, using, offering to sell, or
selling the patented invention. This is not a right of
the patentee to make, use, offer to sell, or sell the
patented invention. Whether and on what terms the
patentee may make, use, offer to sell, or sell are
governed by other bodies of law. Moreover, practices
designed to create legal rights to exclude extending
beyond the invention described by the patent claims,
or beyond the temporal limits of the patent—i.e.,
practices that seek to extend the legal monopoly
granted in the patent—are disfavored in patent law
and are fully subject to the antitrust laws. See infra
Chapter 4, Variations on Intellectual Property Licensing
Practices; infra Chapter 6, Competitive Issues Regarding
Practices That Extend the Market Power Conferred by a
Patent Beyond Its Statutory Term.
116
May 1 Tr. at 134-35, 200-01 (Kirsch); id. at 163, 168,
172-73 (MacKie-Mason); id. at 242 (Melamed); id. at
59, 202, 206-08 (Sprigman).
117
Id. at 41-42 (Gleklen); id. at 233-36 (Whitener);
Whitener Submission at 14-15.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION32
motivation test for refusals to license
articulated in Kodak to be unsound and
unworkable, and panelists agreed that the
CSU decision is difficult to parse and so
broadly drafted that it creates
uncertainty.
The panel discussion provided the
Agencies with significant guidance on
many of the concerns associated with
potential liability for refusals to license.
The Supreme Court in Trinko has since
provided important guidance on the
fundamental principles underlying
claimed duties to assist competitors. The
Agencies agree with the panel that there
are circumstances in which imposing
conditions for a license may be
anticompetitive, and that view is
consistent with a long line of antitrust
cases. The Agencies also conclude that
antitrust liability for mere unilateral,
unconditional refusals to license patents
will not play a meaningful part in the
interface between patent rights and
antitrust protections.
33
CHAPTER 2
COMPETITION CONCERNS WHEN PATENTS ARE INCORPORATED
INTO COLLABORATIVELY SET STANDARDS
I. BACKGROUND AND
INTRODUCTION
Industry standards are widely
acknowledged to be one of the engines
driving the modern economy. Standards
can make products less costly for firms to
produce and more valuable to
consumers.
1
They can increase
innovation, efficiency, and consumer
choice; foster public health and safety;
and serve as a “fundamental building
block for international trade.”
2
Standards
make networks, such as the Internet and
wireless telecommunications, more
valuable by allowing products to
interoperate.
3
The most successful
standards are often those that provide
timely, widely adopted, and effective
solutions to technical problems.
4
The process by which industry
standards are set varies. Commonly,
businesses collaborate to establish
standards by working through standard-
setting organizations (“SSOs”) to develop
a standard that all firms, regardless of
whether they participate in the process,
then can use in making products.
5
1
The two primary types of standards are (1)
interoperability standards, which guarantee that
products made by different firms can interoperate,
and (2) performance standards, which set minimum
requirements for all products in a general product
category. Gregory Tassey, Standardization in
Technology-Based Markets, 29 RES. POLY 587, 589-90
(2000).
2
Amy A. Marasco, Standards-Setting Practices:
Competition, Innovation and Consumer Welfare (Apr. 18,
2002 Hr’g R.) at 3-4, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020418marasco.pdf [hereinafter Marasco
Submission]; see also Janice M. Mueller, Patent Misuse
Through the Capture of Industry Standards, 17 BERKELEY
TECH. L.J. 623, 631-32 (2002).
3
Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Systems Competition
and Network Effects, J. ECON. PERSP., Spring 1994, at 93,
109 [hereinafter Katz & Shapiro, Systems Competition];
see also Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Standard-Setting
Practices: Competition, Innovation and Consumer
Welfare at 85-86 (Cargill), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020418trans.pdf [hereinafter Apr. 18 Tr.].
4
See Andrew Updegrove, Standard Setting and
Consortium Structures (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 1-2,
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020418updegrove
2.pdf [hereinafter Updegrove Submission I].
5
Hundreds of collaborative standard-setting groups
operate worldwide, with diverse organizational
structures and rules. See Apr. 18 Tr. at 63-64
(Deutsch); Scott K. Peterson, Patents and Standard-
Setting Processes (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 9,
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020418scottkpete
rson.pdf [hereinafter Peterson Submission I]; Mark A.
Lemley, Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-
Setting Organizations, 90 CAL. L. REV. 1889, 1904-06
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION34
However, standards also may be set in
the marketplace where firms vigorously
compete in a winner-take-all standards
war
6
to establish their own technology as
the de facto standard.
7
Firms that choose to work through
an SSO to develop and adopt standards
may be competitors within their
particular industry. Thus, agreement
among competitors about which standard
is best suited for them replaces consumer
choice and the competition that otherwise
would have occurred in the market to
make their product the consumer-chosen
standard. In many contexts, this process
can produce substantial benefits. By
agreeing on an industry standard, firms
may be able to avoid many of the costs
and delays of a standards war, thus
substantially reducing transaction costs to
both consumers and firms.
8
Recognizing that collaboratively
set standards can reduce competition and
consumer choice and have the potential to
prescribe the direction in which a market
will develop,
9
courts have been sensitive
to antitrust issues that may arise in the
context of collaboratively set standards.
They have found antitrust liability in
(2002) (discussing the wide variation in policies
among standard-setting organizations (“SSOs”)).
They may be called standard development
organizations, promoter’s groups, joint ventures,
special interest groups, or consortia. For ease of
discussion, this Report will refer to all these standard-
setting groups as SSOs, recognizing that standard-
setting organizations vary widely in size, formality,
operation, and scope.
6
In a “standards war,” substitute products with
incompatible designs are introduced into a market,
and users’ purchase decisions ultimately establish
one design as the dominant design or de facto
standard, in what can effectively be a winner-take-all
competition. See Carl Shapiro & Hal R. Varian, The
Art of Standards War, CAL. MGMT. REV., Winter 1999, at
8 [hereinafter Shapiro & Varian, The Art of Standards
War]. A well-known war occurred between Sony’s
Betamax format Video Cassette Recorder (“VCR”)
and Matsushita’s VHS format VCR, which ultimately
resulted in VHS becoming the de facto standard.
However, not all competition among incompatible
designs results in the establishment of a de facto
standard. For example, multiple competing
standards for video game consoles exist, including
Sony’s PlayStation
®
3, Microsoft’s Xbox 360
TM
, and
Nintendo’s Wii
TM
. Markets in which standards wars
result in a single standard are typically those in
which the network effects are the greatest—i.e., those
markets in which there are substantial benefits if all
customers have compatible products. Id. at 14.
7
Mueller, 17 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. at 633-34; Daniel J.
Gifford, Standards and Intellectual Property: Licensing
Terms: Some Comments (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 1
(discussing the Windows operating system as an
example of a de facto standard chosen by the market),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020418danieljgiff
ord.pdf [hereinafter Gifford Submission].
8
Standards wars offer consumers a choice of
products that incorporate alternative potential
standards. During a standards war, however, some
consumers may delay purchasing until the de facto
standard is chosen because they do not want to be
stuck with the costs of moving from a losing standard
to the winning standard. Jeffrey Church & Roger
Ware, Network Industries, Intellectual Property Rights
and Competition Policy, in COMPETITION POLICY AND
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE-
BASED ECONOMY 230-39 (Robert D. Anderson &
Nancy T. Gallini eds., 1998); see also Katz & Shapiro,
Systems Competition at 105-08 (discussing the concept
of consumers tipping toward a de facto standard). To
win a standards war, a firm may have to incur
significant costs or limit its assertion of market power
in order to establish an installed base of users. The
winner of a standards war, however, may have
significant market power, often because it can enforce
its patent rights to prevent others from making
products that conform to the standard. See, e.g.,
David Balto & Robert Pitofsky, Antitrust and High-
Tech Industries: The New Challenge, 43 ANTITRUST
BULL. 583, 599 (1998).
9
See Standard Sanitary Mfg. Co. v. United States, 226
U.S. 20, 41 (1912); BUREAU OF CONSUMER PROTECTION,
FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, STANDARDS AND
CERTIFICATION: FINAL STAFF REPORT 28, 34 (1983);
Katz & Shapiro, Systems Competition at 105-06;
Richard Gilbert, Symposium on Compatibility:
Incentives and Market Structure, 40 J. INDUS. ECON. 1
(1992).
35
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
circumstances involving the manipulation
of the standard-setting process or the
improper use of the resulting standard to
gain competitive advantage over rivals.
10
This Chapter focuses on antitrust
issues that may arise from collaborative
standard setting when standards
incorporate technologies that are
protected by intellectual property (“IP”)
rights. These issues involve the potential
for “hold up” by the owner of patented
technology after its technology has been
chosen by the SSO as a standard and
others have incurred sunk costs which
effectively increase the relative cost of
switching to an alternative standard.
11
Before, or ex ante,
12
multiple technologies
10
See Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc.,
486 U.S. 492, 509-11 (1988) (affirming court of
appeals’ reinstatement of a jury verdict awarding
damages for a Sherman Act violation where
producers and sellers of steel conduit had packed a
meeting with new members whose sole function was
to vote against a proposal to allow the use of equally
viable plastic conduit in the building industry); Am.
Soc’y of Mech. Eng’rs v. Hydrolevel Corp., 456 U.S. 556,
574 (1982) (finding SSO liable for actions of its agents
acting with apparent authority to discourage
customers from purchasing one competitor’s water
boiler safety device, stating that it did not comply
with the SSO’s safety code, even though it did); see
also Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke
Co., 364 U.S. 656, 659-60 (1961) (holding that
complaint alleging agreement by American Gas
Association members to refuse to sell gas to
customers using a non-Association certified product
states a claim of a per se violation of section 1 of the
Sherman Act).
11
This type of hold up is a variant of the classical
“hold-up problem.” The hold-up problem pertains to
problems of relationship-specific investment, whereas
the hold up contemplated here pertains to standards-
specific investment. The hold-up problem indicates
the prospect of under-investment in collaborations in
which parties must sink investments that are specific
to the collaboration, investments that may be costly to
redeploy or have a significantly lower value if
redeployed outside of the collaboration. The
potential for one party to hold up another party that
has sunk investments specific to the relationship may
discourage that other party from investing efficiently
in the collaboration in the first place. For further
discussion of the hold-up problem, see generally
Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford & Armen A.
Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the
Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297
(1978); OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC
INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS,
RELATIONAL CONTRACTING 52-56 (1985); Sanford J.
Grossman & Oliver D. Hart, The Costs and Benefits of
Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,
94 J. POL. ECON. 691, 692, 716-18 (1986); Suzanne E.
Majewski & Dean V. Williamson, Incomplete
Contracting and the Structure of R&D Joint Venture
Contracts, in 15 ADVANCES IN THE STUDY OF
ENTREPRENEURSHIP, INNOVATION, AND ECONOMIC
GROWTH: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND
ENTREPRENEURSHIP 201-28 (Gary D. Libecap ed.,
2004).
In the standard-setting context, firms may
make sunk investments in developing and
implementing a standard that are specific to
particular intellectual property. To the extent that
these investments are not redeployable using other
IP, those developing and using the standard may be
held up by the IP holders. See Nov. 6, 2002 Hr’g Tr.,
Standard Setting Organizations: Evaluating the
Anticompetitive Risks of Negotiating Intellectual
Property Licensing Terms and Conditions Before a
Standard Is Set at 15-16 (Shapiro) (“In addition to the
word ‘hold-up,’ opportunism is a word that’s
commonly used in the relevant economic literature, at
least, which is [i]n transaction cost economics, the
notion that somebody might wait, perhaps, until
commitments were made and then seek to extract a
high royalty or might try to steer things in a direction
so that they would have an essential patent but not
have made a firm commitment ex ante on the terms
on which it would be licensed.”),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/021106ftctrans.pd
f [hereinafter Nov. 6 Tr.]; see also Timothy J. Muris,
The FTC and the Law of Monopolization, 67 ANTITRUST
L.J. 693, 704-06 (2000) (describing factual
considerations as to whether a company could
engage in a hold up); cf. Benjamin Klein, Market Power
in Franchise Cases in the Wake of Kodak: Applying Post
Contract Hold-Up Analysis to Vertical Relationships, 67
ANTITRUST L.J. 283 (1999). Moreover, this hold up
may cause firms to sink less investment in developing
and implementing standards.
12
Whether and at what point hold up can occur will
vary, depending on a variety of factors. For hold up
to occur, the cost of switching to the best alternative
standard must be greater than the benefits of
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION36
may compete to be incorporated into the
standard under consideration.
13
Afterwards, or ex post, the chosen
technology may lack effective
substitutes
14
precisely because the SSO
chose it as the standard.
15
Thus, ex post,
the owner of a patented technology
necessary to implement the standard may
have the power to extract higher royalties
or other licensing terms that reflect the
absence of competitive alternatives.
16
Consumers of the products using the
standard would be harmed if those higher
royalties were passed on in the form of
higher prices.
17
To mitigate this type of hold up,
some SSOs require participants to disclose
the existence of IP rights that may be
infringed by the potential users of a
standard in development. SSOs also may
require SSO members to commit to
license any of their IP that is essential to
an SSO standard on “reasonable and
nondiscriminatory” (“RAND”) terms.
18
Some SSOs and SSO members would like
to further mitigate hold up by requiring
IP holders to commit to specific licensing
terms before selecting a particular
technology as part of a standard.
Two questions that can arise from
these efforts to mitigate hold up involve
quite different competition concerns. The
first question involves unilateral conduct.
It asks whether an SSO member harms
competition by failing to disclose, or by
engaging in deceptive conduct regarding,
the existence of intellectual property
rights during the standard-setting process
and later alleging that implementation of
the standard infringes that member’s IP,
and thus, requires a license and the
payment of royalties. The FTC has alleged
violations of section 5 of the Federal
Trade Commission Act in three matters
involving such conduct in different
factual settings,
19
and the Commission
switching to the best alternative standard.
13
Daniel G. Swanson, Evaluating Market Power in
Technology Markets when Standards Are Selected in
Which Private Parties Own Intellectual Property Rights
(Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 2-3, http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020418danielswanson.pdf [hereinafter
Swanson Submission] (discussing the possibility of
available substitutes).
14
See, e.g., CARL SHAPIRO & HAL R. VARIAN,
INFORMATION RULES: A STRATEGIC GUIDE TO THE
NETWORK ECONOMY 103-34 (1999).
15
Collaborative de jure standards sometimes face a
market test for acceptance, just as de facto standards
do. If a standard chosen by an SSO must compete
with rival standards, then the owner of any patented
technology necessary to implement the SSO’s
standard may have little market power. See, e.g., Apr.
18 Tr. at 76 (Lemley). The opportunity for users of
the SSO’s standard to move to a rival standard if the
royalty rates are too high may limit the owner to a
competitive royalty rate.
16
Nov. 6 Tr. at 15 (Shapiro) (“So, the notion of hold-
up would be that ex post there are very few choices,
and a company that controls an essential patent is in a
very strong bargaining position to extract royalties or
other concessions from people who want to comply
with the standard. Ex ante, the bargaining positions
are very different because, let’s suppose, there would
be maybe lots of choices . . . .”).
17
For consumer harm to occur, it is not necessary
that hold up result in higher marginal costs for
producers. For example, higher lump sum or fixed
royalties might discourage entry among firms that
would produce the standardized product. The
reduction in competition at the downstream level,
and possible reduction in product adoption, might
harm consumers.
18
See infra note 72-73 and accompanying text.
19
Complaint, In re Dell, 121 F.T.C. 616, 616-18 (1996)
(No. C-3658) (resolved by consent order, 121 F.T.C. at
618-26), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/
decisions/vol121.htm [hereinafter Dell Complaint];
Complaint, In re Rambus, Inc., No. 9302 (F.T.C. 2002),
available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/
020618admincmp.pdf; Complaint, In re Union Oil Co.
of Cal., No. 9305 (F.T.C. Mar. 4, 2003), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/ os/2003/03/unocalcp.htm
37
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
recently found a violation of section 5 in
one of these proceedings, following a full
adjudicative trial.
20
The second question involves joint
conduct and asks whether ex ante
negotiation of licensing terms by SSO
participants constitutes a per se violation
of section 1 of the Sherman Act because
competitors would be acting jointly to
negotiate licensing terms with each of the
firms whose technology may be
considered for inclusion in the SSO’s
standard.
21
In the Agencies’ view, a per se
approach fails to recognize that
negotiating licensing terms during the
standard-setting process may increase
competition between technologies that
are being considered for inclusion in a
standard. In light of these potential
procompetitive benefits, the Agencies
would generally expect to apply the rule
of reason to evaluate conduct such as
multilateral ex ante licensing negotiations
or SSO requirements to disclose model
licensing terms.
22
In announcing this policy
guidance, the Agencies seek to resolve
open questions about the Agencies’
enforcement intentions that may have
discouraged SSOs from attempting to
mitigate the threat of licensing hold up by
evaluating licensing terms and conditions
before hold up can occur. The Agencies
recognize that the evaluation of licensing
terms before the standard is set can
present substantial practical challenges
and costs for an SSO, so even with this
guidance there may be non-antitrust
reasons for an SSO not to engage in such
evaluations. When making this decision,
SSOs and their members should bear in
mind that the Agencies will still condemn
as per se illegal activities designed to
reduce or eliminate competition among
members of an SSO—such as bid rigging
by members who otherwise would
compete in licensing technologies for
adoption by the SSO or naked price fixing
on downstream products by members
who otherwise would compete in selling
downstream products compliant with the
standard—even if these activities are
cloaked by multilateral ex ante licensing
negotiations for the purported purpose of
setting a standard.
II. HOLD UP IN THE CONTEXT OF
JOINT STANDARD SETTING
Panelists reported that after a
standard has been adopted and switching
to an alternative standard would require
significant additional costs, the holder of
a patent that covers technology needed to
implement the standard can force users of
the technology to choose between two
unpleasant options: “You either don’t
make the standard or you accede to the –
[hereinafter Unocal Complaint], resolved by consent
order, No. 9305 (F.T.C. July 27, 2005), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9305/
050802do.pdf.
20
In re Rambus, Inc., No. 9302 (F.T.C. July 31, 2006),
available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/
060802commissionopinion.pdf., remedy ordered, In re
Rambus, Inc., No. 9302 (F.T.C. Feb. 2, 2007), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/070205opinio
n.pdf and http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/
070205finalorder.pdf.
21
The term “negotiation” is used in this Chapter to
encompass a range of activities relating to the
consideration of the price of a technology input for a
standard, including disclosure of most restrictive
licensing terms, discussion of the relative costs of
alternative technology inputs, or negotiation of
licensing terms leading to a licensing agreement.
22
Infra Parts V-VI.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION38
I don’t want to say blackmail, but that’s
[what it] tends to be in that
environment.”
23
Anointing a patented
technology as the standard improves the
bargaining position of the owner of the
needed technology in licensing
negotiations because “[i]f you are the
owner of one of the rights to one of those
many equally valuable [technologies],
then it is the standard-setting process that
will reduce the substitution, possibly
eliminate the substitutes, and elevate
your technology to [be] the most
valuable.”
24
A holder of IP incorporated into a
standard can exploit its position if it is
costly for users of the standard to switch
to a different technology after the
standard is set. Making such a change
would require abandoning that standard
and developing a new one, but
developing an alternative standard could
be costly and may delay the introduction
of a new product. The profits lost by such
a delay may represent a significant
portion of the cost of developing the
alternative standard. In addition, to
implement an alternative standard for an
existing product that requires
compatibility and interoperability, the
SSO members might incur switching costs
in redesigning components that had been
based on the old standard and might have
to subsidize consumers’ migration from a
standard based on one technology to a
standard based on another technology.
25
Generally, the greater the cost of
switching to an alternative standard, the
more an IP holder can charge for a
license.
23
Apr. 18 Tr. at 56-57 (Cargill).
24
Apr. 18 Tr. at 47-48 (Rapp); see also id. at 248-51
(Peterson) (discussing the “anointing” phenomenon);
id. at 76-77 (Lemley).
25
The most direct source of switching costs is the
difference between the costs of acquiring new
infrastructure to implement a new standard and the
salvage value of current infrastructure that is
supporting the existing standard but would not be
used to support a new standard. In the absence of
network effects, this switching cost can be viewed as
an upper bound on the extent to which the
underlying technology’s patent owner can hold up
firms using the standard. A second source of
switching costs can be network effects such as
compatibility. It may be impractical to change the
existing standard for one piece of infrastructure if
that piece must be compatible with other pieces of
infrastructure. Thus, for example, a person wanting
to upgrade his word processing software may be
locked in to his current software if there is a large
benefit to maintaining compatibility with the
software of other colleagues.
There is a vast literature on network effects
and the role of standards in network effects. Much of
it was developed in between the mid-1980s and early
1990s by Joseph Farrell, Richard Gilbert, Michael
Katz, Garth Saloner, and Carl Shapiro. Other major
contributors to this field have been Timothy
Bresnahan, Jeff Church, Neil Gandal, and Nicholas
Economides. For an overview of the literature, see
Bertrand V. Quélin, Tamym Abdessemed, Jean-
Philippe Bonardi & Rodolphe Durand, Standardisation
of Network Technologies: Market Processes or the Result
of Inter-firm Co-operation?, 15 J. ECON. SURVS. 543
(2001). See generally Dennis W. Carlton & J. Mark
Klamer, The Need for Coordination Among Firms, with
Special Reference to Network Industries, 50 U. CHI. L.
REV. 446 (1983); Katz & Shapiro, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. at
93; Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Technology
Adoption in the Presence of Network Externalities, 94 J.
POL. ECON. 822 (1986); Joseph Farrell & Garth Saloner,
Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product
Preannouncements, and Predation, 76 AM. ECON. REV.
940 (1986); Joseph Farrell & Garth Saloner, Converters,
Compatibility and the Control of Interfaces, 40 J. INDUS.
ECON. 9 (1992); Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro,
Product Introduction with Network Externalities, 40 J.
INDUS. ECON. 55 (1992); Jeffrey Church & Neil Gandal,
Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization,
40 J. INDUS. ECON. 85 (1992); Nicholas Economides,
The Economics of Networks, 14 INTL J. INDUS. ORG. 673
(1996).
39
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
It is useful to distinguish between
the licensing terms a patent holder could
obtain solely based on the merits of its
technology and the terms that it could
obtain because its technology was
included in the standard. This distinction
can be cast as differentiating two sources
of potential market power, defined as
“the ability to raise prices above those
that would be charged in a competitive
market.”
26
The mere existence of a patent
or other intellectual property right does
not necessarily create market power for
the IP holder, although it may in some
cases.
27
If the intellectual property right
does convey market power “it would be
worthwhile . . . to distinguish between the
market power that comes from the
technology on its own and the market
power that comes just from the standard,
the act of setting a standard that elevates
a technology above the competitors.”
28
Of
course, an analysis of potential harm
arising from failure to disclose relevant IP
would focus on the market power of the
IP holder that was acquired through the
standard-setting process. In contrast, any
claim that ex ante licensing discussions
violate section 1 of the Sherman Act
would focus on the exercise of market
power by the SSO members as a group,
not on the market power of the IP holder.
Panelists at the Hearings discussed
a range of related practical, legal, and
economic issues regarding hold up within
SSOs, including the extent to which hold
up occurs.
29
Some panelists said hold up
26
Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of the
Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 109 n.38 (1984).
27
Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281,
1284 (2006) (“[T]he mere fact that a tying product is
patented does not support [a market power]
presumption.”); U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL
TRADE COMMN, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE
LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY § 2.2 (1995),
reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132 (“The
Agencies will not presume that a patent, copyright, or
trade secret necessarily confers market power upon
its owner.”), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/
public/guidelines/0558.pdf [hereinafter ANTITRUST-
IP GUIDELINES].
28
Apr. 18 Tr. at 321-22 (Stiroh); see Nov. 6 Tr. at 39-40
(Farrell) (“[T]he core point is the extent to which an IP
holder acquires additional bargaining power through
the SDO having completed its – or gone a certain
distance in its standard[s] option process.”); Mark R.
Patterson, Inventions, Industry Standards, and
Intellectual Property, 17 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1043, 1044
(2002) (“When an industry standard incorporates a
patented invention, the legal challenge is to
distinguish several market effects. Some of the
demand for products that comply with the standard
may be for the inherent technical advantages of the
invention. A patentee is generally entitled to
revenues attributable to this demand. But some of the
demand may also be created by the adoption of the
standard. The patentee is not entitled to revenues
attributable to this demand.”) (footnotes omitted).
29
Panelists discussed these topics at several sessions
of the Hearings. The first session was held on April
18, 2002 and was divided into two parts. The
morning session was titled “Disclosure of Intellectual
Property in Standards Activities.” The panelists
included: Michael Antalics, Partner, O’Melveny &
Myers, L.L.P.; Carl Cargill, Director of Standards, Sun
Microsystems, Inc.; Donald R. Deutsch, Vice
President, Standards Strategy and Architecture,
Oracle Corp.; Ernest Gellhorn, Professor of Law,
George Mason University School of Law; Peter
Grindley, Senior Managing Economist, LECG, Ltd.,
London; Mark Lemley, Professor of Law, and
Director, Berkeley Center for Law & Technology,
Boalt Hall School of Law, University of California,
Berkeley, Of Counsel, Keker & Van Nest; Amy A.
Marasco, Vice President and General Counsel,
American National Standards Institute; Richard T.
Rapp, President, National Economic Research
Associates; David J. Teece, Mitsubishi Bank Professor
of International Business and Finance, Haas School of
Business, University of California, Berkeley; and
Dennis A. Yao, Associate Professor of Business and
Public Policy, The Wharton School, University of
Pennsylvania. The panel was moderated by Gail
Levine, then-Deputy Assistant General Counsel for
Policy Studies, Federal Trade Commission; Tor
Winston, Economist, U.S. Department of Justice; and
Robert W. Bahr, then-Deputy Solicitor, U.S. Patent
and Trademark Office. The afternoon session was
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION40
was the rare exception in a system that
otherwise works well.
30
Other panelists
questioned this assertion, suggesting that
hold up may be more widespread. They
posited that, although litigation
involving hold up may be rare, market
participants often may have little
incentive to complain about hold up
because they can pass on the hidden costs
of hold up to consumers or because there
is no venue for resolving complaints.
31
III. FACTORS OTHER THAN SSO
RULES THAT MAY MITIGATE
HOLD UP
Panelists suggested several factors,
independent of specific SSO rules or
practices, that may deter some IP holders
from holding up licensees. First, IP
holders that are frequent participants in
standard-setting activities may incur
“reputation and business costs . . . that
could be sufficiently large as to be the
primary deterrent [of fraudulent non-
disclosure] as opposed to whatever legal
remedies [the antitrust community]
comes up with.”
32
One panelist stated:
titled “Licensing Terms in Standards Activities” and
the panelists were: Stanley M. Besen, Vice President,
Charles River Associates; Daniel J. Gifford, Robins,
Kaplan, Miller & Ciresi Professor of Law, University
of Minnesota School of Law; Richard Holleman,
Industry Standards Consultant; Allen M. Lo, Director
of Intellectual Property, Juniper Networks, Inc.; Mark
R. Patterson, Associate Professor of Law, Fordham
University School of Law; Scott K. Peterson,
Corporate Counsel for Intellectual Property,
Hewlett-Packard Company, Chair, American
National Standards Institute Patent Committee;
Lauren J. Stiroh, Vice President, National Economics
Research Associates; Daniel Swanson, Partner,
Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP; Andrew Updegrove,
Partner, Lucash, Gesmer & Updegrove, LLP; and
Daniel J. Weitzner, Director of Technology and
Society Activities, World Wide Web Consortium. The
panel was moderated by Carolyn Galbreath, then-
Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice; Tor Winston,
Economist, U.S. Department of Justice; Gail Levine,
then-Deputy Assistant General Counsel for Policy
Studies, Federal Trade Commission; and Robert Bahr,
then-Deputy Solicitor, U.S. Patent and Trademark
Office. Apr. 18 Tr. at 2-5.
The second session was held on the morning
of November 6, 2002, titled “Standard-Setting
Organizations: Evaluating the Anticompetitive Risks
of Negotiating Intellectual Property Licensing Terms
and Conditions Before a Standard Is Set.” The
panelists included: Joseph Farrell, Professor of
Economics and Chair of the Competition Policy
Center, University of California, Berkeley; Joseph
Kattan, Partner, Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher; Scott K.
Peterson, Corporate Counsel for Intellectual Property,
Hewlett-Packard Company; Carl Shapiro,
Transamerica Professor of Business Strategy, Haas
School of Business, Director and Professor of
Economics, Institute of Business and Economic
Research, University of California, Berkeley; Earle
Thompson, Intellectual Asset Manager and Senior
Counsel, Texas Instruments, Inc.; and Paul Vishny,
Member, D’Ancona & Pflaum, LLC, General Counsel,
Telecommunications Industry Association. The panel
was moderated by Carolyn Galbreath, then-Attorney,
U.S. Department of Justice; Gail Levine, then-Deputy
Assistant General Counsel for Policy Studies, Federal
Trade Commission; and Tor Winston, Economist, U.S.
Department of Justice. Nov. 6 Tr. at 3-13.
30
Apr. 18 Tr. at 236-37 (Holleman) (stating that the
extent to which patent holders try to extract
unreasonable terms is de minimis); Nov. 6 Tr. at 80
(Kattan); id. (Thompson); id. at 21 (Kattan).
31
Nov. 6 Tr. at 26-27 (Farrell) (“I think it’s also
relevant to observe that to the extent that the people
paying royalties are competing against each other
and are all – or believe that they’re all paying roughly
the same royalty, there’s a lot of pass-through, so it’s
the final consumer rather than these competitors who
end up paying.”); accord id. at 18 (Thompson) (“[T]hat
may be a tax on the industry, and . . . it doesn’t hurt
me worse than anybody else.”). But see id. at 56
(Kattan) (companies without cross licenses have a
higher cost position and therefore an incentive to
complain about high royalty rates).
32
Apr. 18 Tr. at 122 (Yao); see also Stanley M. Besen,
Standard Setting and Intellectual Property: An Outline of
the Issues (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 2 n.5 (“[T]he
license fee that a winning [patentee] will demand
may be constrained by its desire to develop a
reputation for reasonableness, in order to increase the
likelihood that its technology will be chosen in future
standards competitions . . . .”), http://www.ftc.gov/
41
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
“You fool people two or three times and
the next time you go back to play with
them they don’t like you. And that hurts
more than the actual [legal] remedy. . . .
People start to mistrust you after that.”
33
Yet even that panelist acknowledged that
this market cure has its limits: “[T]he
next time you may be allied with [the firm
that failed to disclose its IP] and have to
support them no matter what. So it’s not
really deep penalties. I mean we play too
quickly, too fast.”
34
Second, one panelist suggested
that in some cases a licensor may try to
affect the SSO’s technology choice by
informally indicating the terms under
which it intends to license intellectual
property incorporated into a standard.
35
A licensor also might make bilateral ex
ante licensing commitments outside the
formal standard-setting process.
36
This
panelist stated that information filters
back to the standards committee fairly
quickly if it becomes apparent that an IP
holder is not being forthcoming about
terms during bilateral negotiations. Upon
receiving such confirmation, the
committee can consider alternative
technologies before the standard is set, he
noted.
37
Third, an IP holder might enjoy a
first-mover advantage if its technology is
adopted as the standard. IP holders that
produce and sell a product using the
standard sometimes may find it more
profitable to offer attractive licensing
terms in order to promote the adoption of
the product using the standard,
increasing demand for its product rather
than extracting high royalties.
38
As one
panelist put it, “if you in fact have your
technology accepted as a standard you
have a tremendous competitive
advantage . . . because you are the first
mover, you are the most competent.”
39
Fourth, IP holders that have broad
cross-licensing agreements with the
owner of the selected IP might be
protected from hold up.
40
Of course, this
protection is not available to firms that
have little IP to offer in cross-licensing
deals.
41
opp/intellect/020418stanleymbesen.pdf [hereinafter
Besen Submission].
33
Apr. 18 Tr. at 124 (Cargill).
34
Id. at 124-25 (Cargill).
35
See Richard J. Holleman, Comments on Standards
Setting and Intellectual Property (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.)
at 3, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020418richardjholleman.pdf [hereinafter Holleman
Submission I].
36
Apr. 18 Tr. at 194-95 (Holleman); Nov. 6 Tr. at 52-
53 (Vishny).
37
Apr. 18 Tr. at 194-95 (Holleman).
38
Apr. 18 Tr. at 225-26 (Updegrove) (“So the first
thing is that most people who are going to respond to
a call [for a standard] aren’t people who want to
make that product and collect royalties on it. They
are people who want a head start from already being
at that starting point. They don’t want to saddle
competitors with royalties because what they want is
a big market for that product. And they’re satisfied
with a head start.”).
39
Id. at 58 (Cargill).
40
Nov. 6 Tr. at 18 (Thompson); cf. id. at 27-28 (Farrell)
(asking whether institutions using “mutual assured
destruction or portfolio cross-licensing” can solve
licensing hold up, and inquiring about the limits of
these solutions).
41
Apr. 18 Tr. at 242-43 (Lo).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION42
IV. CURRENT SSO METHODS TO
AVOID OR MITIGATE HOLD
UP
Many SSOs have developed
policies to mitigate hold up. The
provisions of such SSO policies fall,
broadly speaking, into two nonexclusive
categories: disclosure rules and licensing
rules. Disclosure rules require SSO
participants to disclose patents (and,
sometimes, patent applications and other
intellectual property or confidential
information) related to a standard under
consideration. Licensing rules restrict the
terms that holders of such intellectual
property can demand. The most common
licensing rule requires that IP holders
license to users of the standard on RAND
terms. Some SSOs require the
incorporated IP to be licensed on royalty-
free terms.
A. Use of Disclosure Rules to Deter
Hold Up
Panelists noted that disclosure
rules can help avoid hold up by
informing SSO members about relevant
intellectual property held by those
participating in the standard-setting
process, thus allowing SSO members
jointly to decide whether to incorporate
the patented technology in a standard.
42
Some SSOs have no disclosure
requirements. The disclosure policies of
those that do are diverse.
43
Some policies
state express disclosure obligations, while
others impose implied obligations; the
policies may cover existing patents,
pending patents, or other IP rights; and
they also may require an SSO member to
search its own inventory for patents.
44
1. Benefits and Costs of SSO
Disclosure Policies
Panelists said that SSO policies to
mitigate hold up confer substantial
procompetitive benefits.
45
One panelist
stated that such policies serve to clear
patent thickets, and he found it
“significant that they exist primarily in
industries in which it looks like patent
hold-up is the biggest problem.”
46
Panelists opined that “the fundamental
reason that drives most disclosure rules is
that people want to make informed
decisions. . . . It’s really designed to avoid
the hold-up situation where they create a
standard without knowing that there is
intellectual property incorporated into
it.”
47
Panelists suggested that disclosure
rules also have costs and limitations,
however. For example, compliance with
disclosure rules may slow down
standards development, which could be
particularly costly in fast-paced markets
with short product life cycles.
48
42
Id. at 42-43 (Antalics).
43
Lemley, 90 CAL. L. REV. at 1904.
44
Id. at 1904-05.
45
Apr. 18 Tr. at 35-36 (Lemley); Id. at 86 (Cargill)
(“[D]isclosure is a method of achieving a risk
reduction goal.”). See generally Nov. 6 Tr. at 50
(Peterson) (stressing that costs should be known); Id.
at 85 (Shapiro) (same).
46
Apr. 18 Tr. at 36 (Lemley).
47
Id. at 42 (Antalics); see id. at 108-09 (Lemley)
(stating that the system can be gamed the most when
disclosure is required but licensing is not).
48
Richard J. Holleman, A Response: Government
Guidelines Should Not Be Used in Connection with
Standard Setting (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 2
43
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
Complying with differing disclosure
policies in different SSOs can be costly to
IP holders,
49
especially for those with
large patent portfolios who participate in
many SSOs.
50
The cost of compliance may
cause some IP holders to opt out of some
collaborative standard setting.
51
As a
result, “whatever they might have had to
contribute to the process is going to be
lost.”
52
Furthermore, IP holders that
choose not to participate in an SSO are
not bound by the SSO’s disclosure rules.
53
Finally, disclosure rules that are not well-
crafted may not help prevent hold up.
Panelists said that disclosure rules drafted
by engineers and business people may
reflect their authors’ laudable ethos—to
work collaboratively toward a
standard—but sometimes fail to consider
carefully the intellectual property and
antitrust issues.
54
2. FTC Challenges to Hold Ups
Based on the Failure to Disclose IP
Rights
In the past ten years, the FTC has
brought three cases challenging alleged
hold ups based on failures to disclose the
existence of IP rights as unfair
competition under section 5 of the FTC
(mandatory patent disclosure rule could slow down
the standardization process), http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020418richardjholleman2.pdf
[hereinafter Holleman Submission II]; see Apr. 18 Tr.
at 101-02 (Teece) (noting that if lawyers must insert
themselves into the market-building work of the
technical and marketing people who generally run
certain SSOs and other consortia, the standard-setting
process will become slower and “more deliberate”);
id. at 73 (Antalics) (“[Y]ou could have good products
that are delayed coming to market if this whole
process is taking longer.”).
49
Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers
(“IEEE”), Comments Regarding Competition and
Intellectual Property (Public Comments Hr’g R.) at 2-3
(noting costs of disclosure rules, including costs of
potential searches for relevant patents),
http://www.ftc.gov/os/comments/intelpropertyco
mments/ieee.pdf [hereinafter IEEE Submission].
Simply learning the disclosure and other obligations
of each SSO a firm has joined is no small job, one
panelist noted, and not all firms take on the task of
educating themselves about the intellectual property
policies of the SSOs they have joined and how those
policies interact. Apr. 18 Tr. at 30-31 (Lemley). This
leads to “a recipe for maximum confusion when
complex systems standards are invoked. And,
unfortunately, that is exactly where we are today.”
Carl Cargill, Intellectual Property Rights and Standards
Setting Organizations: An Overview of Failed Evolution
(Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 8, http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020418cargill.pdf.
50
See Apr. 18 Tr. at 84-85 (Cargill) (“There is not an
organization in the [Information Technology]
industry I believe that doesn’t belong to at least 30,
40, or 50 consortia, standards organizations, [or]
alliances. We play against ourselves sometimes.”).
51
Apr. 18 Tr. at 95-96 (Marasco) (describing costs of
conducting a patent portfolio search); id. at 63-64
(Deutsch) (stating that if an SSO’s disclosure policy is
too burdensome, IP holders won’t come to the table
because of the high cost); Mar. 20, 2002 Hr’g Tr.,
Business Perspectives on Patents: Hardware and
Semiconductors at 62-63 (McCurdy) (noting costs of
educating firm’s SSO delegates about firm’s patents
or patent applications),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020320trans.pdf;
see also id. at 64 (Zanfagna) (acknowledging such
challenges at “a company the size of Honeywell”); In
re Dell, 121 F.T.C. at 633 (Azcuenaga, Comm’r,
dissenting) (noting that imposing burdens on SSO
members, including antitrust liability, may dissuade
some firms from participating in the standards-
setting process).
52
Apr. 18 Tr. at 73 (Antalics).
53
See id. at 63 (Deutsch).
54
Apr. 18 Tr. at 202-03 (Updegrove) (explaining that
companies founding consortia ask their business
marketing or technical experts to start them, and
“their acquaintance with intellectual property policies
may be slim to nil”); id. at 29-30 (Lemley) (stating that
some SSOs establish their intellectual property rules
ad hoc in response to issues that happen to arise, and
not in a comprehensive, forward-looking way); id. at
90, 92-93 (Cargill) (stating that the engineers who
draft SSO disclosure rules do not know when they are
being misled about legal issues, and that SSO
intellectual property policies have always been an
afterthought).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION44
Act.
55
The first FTC matter, In re Dell,
56
highlighted to industry the possibility of
antitrust liability for deceiving SSOs and
their members.
57
In that case, the FTC
alleged that during an SSO’s deliberations
about a certain standard, Dell, a member
of the SSO, had twice certified that it had
no intellectual property relevant to the
standard, and that the SSO adopted the
standard based, in part, on Dell’s
certifications. After the SSO adopted the
standard, Dell allegedly demanded
royalties from those using its technology
in connection with that standard. The
Commission accepted a consent
agreement under which Dell agreed not
to enforce the patent in question against
firms using it as part of the standard.
58
In a recent case, In re Rambus, the
Commission determined that Rambus
had acquired monopoly power through
deceptive, exclusionary conduct in
connection with its participation in an
SSO. According to the Commission’s
opinion, Rambus engaged in a course of
conduct “calculated to mislead [SSO]
members by fostering the belief that
Rambus neither had, nor was seeking,
relevant patents that would be enforced”
against products compliant with the
SSO’s standards.
59
The Commission
found that “Rambus’s course of conduct
constituted deception under Section 5 of
the FTC Act.”
60
The Commission further
found that Rambus’s course of conduct
contributed significantly to the SSO’s
technology selections and that the SSO’s
choice of standard contributed
significantly to Rambus’s acquisition of
monopoly power.
61
According to the
Commission, the switching costs that
developed as manufacturers became
increasingly committed to the standard
locked the industry in and rendered
Rambus’s monopoly power durable.
62
The Commission concluded that Rambus
unlawfully monopolized the markets for
four technologies incorporated into the
SSO’s standards in violation of section 5
of the FTC Act.
63
55
A variety of other mechanisms may be available to
challenge hold up in the context of an SSO. Some
have used actions for fraud. See, e.g., Rambus, Inc. v.
Infineon Techs. AG, 164 F. Supp. 2d 743, 750-58 (E.D.
Va. 2001) (upholding jury verdict finding actual fraud
based on firm’s non-disclosure of patents related to a
standard), rev’d in part, 318 F.3d 1081 (Fed. Cir. 2003)
(reversing a denial of judgment for defendant as a
matter of law upon determining that the record
showed no breach of SSO disclosure duty). Others
recommend using contract actions to enforce
disclosure policies. See Mark A. Lemley, Intellectual
Property Rights and Standard Setting Organizations
(Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 38-42, http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020418lemley.pdf [hereinafter Lemley
Submission]. Some have used the doctrine of
equitable estoppel to enforce disclosure policies. See
Symbol Techs., Inc. v. Proxim Inc., No. Civ. 01-801-SLR,
2004 WL 1770290 (D. Del. July 28, 2004) (rejecting an
estoppel defense when the firm had no duty to
disclose its patent rights). Others have suggested the
doctrines of implied license or patent misuse to
enforce disclosure policies. See, e.g., Lemley
Submission at 51-56; David R. Steinman & Danielle S.
Fitzpatrick, Antitrust Counterclaims in Patent
Infringement Cases: A Guide to Walker Process and
Sham-Litigation Claims, 10 TEX. INTELL. PROP. L.J. 95, 96
& n.2, 106 (2001).
56
121 F.T.C. 616.
57
Apr. 18 Tr. at 32-33 (Lemley); see also Feb. 28 Hr’g
Tr., Business Perspectives on Patents: Hardware and
Semiconductors (Afternoon Session) at 742 (Telecky),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020228ftc.pdf
[hereinafter Feb. 28 Tr.].
58
See Decision and Order, In re Dell, 121 F.T.C. at 618-
23.
59
In re Rambus, Inc., No. 9302, slip op. at 67.
60
Id.
61
Id. at 74-79.
62
Id. at 98-114.
63
Id. at 3-5, 118-19. Private litigation has also
45
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
One other FTC case resulted in a
consent order. In 2003, the FTC filed an
administrative complaint against the
Union Oil Company of California
(“Unocal”) for allegedly misrepresenting
information involving proposed low-
emissions gasoline standards in state
regulatory proceedings. According to the
complaint, Unocal presented research
results in these proceedings that it had
represented as non-proprietary, and the
state regulating board used these results
in setting its standards. At the same time,
Unocal was pursuing patent rights to
cover these research results. The FTC’s
complaint asserted that Unocal
misrepresented its proprietary interest in
the standard until members of the
refining industry had spent billions of
dollars modifying their refineries to
become compliant with the new
standards. Unocal then alleged that the
new standards infringed its patents. This
conduct allegedly enabled Unocal to
charge substantial royalties, costing
consumers hundreds of millions of
dollars per year.
64
An initial ALJ decision
dismissed the complaint on Noerr-
Pennington
65
and jurisdictional grounds,
66
but the full Commission reversed,
holding that Unocal’s alleged misleading
statements to the state regulatory board
were not protected as a matter of law by
the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, and that
the FTC had ample jurisdiction to
consider whether Unocal’s actions caused
competitive harm.
67
The Unocal matter
settled as part of a larger dual consent
agreement that allowed Chevron
Corporation to acquire Unocal. Under
the terms of the settlement, Unocal will
not enforce its patents related to the
reformulated gasoline standard set by the
state board.
68
B. Use of Licensing Rules to Deter
Hold Up
Even if SSO members are informed
about the existence of patented
technologies through disclosure during a
standard-setting process, hold up over
licensing terms may still be a concern.
One panelist identified six “ways that
challenged Rambus’s actions before the SSO. E.g.,
Samsung Elecs. Co. v. Rambus, Inc., 439 F. Supp. 2d 524
(E.D. Va. 2006); Hynix Semiconductor Inc. v. Rambus
Inc., 441 F. Supp. 2d 1066 (N.D. Cal. 2006); Micron
Tech., Inc. v. Rambus Inc., 189 F. Supp. 2d 201 (D. Del.
2002); Infineon, 164 F. Supp. 2d 743, rev’d in part, 318
F.3d 1081 (Fed. Cir. 2003). A district judge on remand
dismissed Rambus’s infringement claims against
Infineon in light of Rambus’s failure to retain certain
documents related to the case; in lieu of pursuing an
appeal, Rambus settled the case and all other claims
against Infineon related to the memory chip
technology. Under the agreement, Infineon has
agreed to pay Rambus royalties for the use of its
technology and to grant Rambus a perpetual license
for Infineon’s memory interfaces. See Licensing
Settlement Ends Patent Suit by Rambus, N.Y. TIMES,
Mar. 22, 2005, at C15.
64
See Unocal Complaint paras. 1-10.
65
E. R.R. Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight,
Inc., 365 U.S. 127 (1961); United Mine Workers v.
Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965).
66
In re Union Oil Co. of Cal., No. 9305, slip op. at 67
(F.T.C. Nov. 25, 2003), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/11/031126unionoil.pd
f, rev’d, No. 9305 (F.T.C. July 7, 2004), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9305/040706comm
issionopinion.pdf [hereinafter Unocal Commission
Opinion].
67
Unocal Commission Opinion, slip op. at 25 (“[T]he
decided weight of precedent concludes that deliberate
misrepresentation that cuts to the core of an
administrative proceeding’s legitimacy can fall
outside Noerr-Pennington protections.”).
68
See Statement of the Federal Trade Commission: In
the Matter of Union Oil Company of California, Dkt.
No. 9305 and Chevron/Unocal, File No. 051-0125
(June 10, 2005), available at www.ftc.gov/os/
adjpro/d9305/050802statement.pdf.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION46
patent license terms revealed only after
the standard is adopted can generate
conflict and impair many parties
abilit[ies] to compete in the affected
market.”
69
Some SSOs use licensing rules,
such as requiring IP holders to commit to
licensing on RAND terms, to mitigate
hold up.
70
Others, particularly those
focused on Internet-based industries,
actively promote the development of
standards that are licensed on a royalty-
free basis.
71
1. Use of RAND Licensing
Some believe that commitments
by IP holders to license IP incorporated
into a standard on RAND terms is an
effective means for SSOs to avoid hold
up.
72
Others believe that “a commitment
to offer a license on terms that are merely
specified as ‘RAND’ is not an adequate
safeguard against abusive use of a patent
that has become essential to a standard.”
73
69
Peterson Submission I at 8 (the patentee: (1) “seeks
a royalty that is . . . greater than the average profit
margin of all of the parties who will need licenses”;
(2) “seeks a broad grantback that appears even-
handed but [which has] significantly disparate effects
on different parties, perhaps forcing particular
licensees to forfeit the value of their own major
innovation investments, but patentee refuses to
deviate from its ‘standard’ agreement for any
reason”; (3) “demands a minimum annual royalty
based on ‘administrative costs’ but [has] the effect of
locking out smaller rivals and new entrants”; (4)
“seeks royalties from downstream providers (e.g.,
manufacturers of finished goods) and refuses to
license suppliers of upstream inputs”; (5) “requires
admissions of infringement and validity, and/or
retains the right to immediately terminate a license if
the licensor challenges infringement or validity”; (6)
“requires acceptance of venue in a ‘home court’
which might be fine for large companies but a major
problem for small companies or foreign
competitors”); see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 34 (Vishny)
(stating that “looking at the licensing process as
relating to fees, is terribly simplistic”).
70
Lemley, 90 CAL. L. REV. at 1906; Standards-Setting
and United States Competitiveness: Hearing Before the H.
Subcomm. on Environment, Technology, and Standards of
the H. Comm. on Science, 107th Cong. 62, 88 n.22 (2001)
(statement of Carl Cargill) (asserting that RAND
terms must be offered for intellectual property to be
included in an International Organization for
Standardization standard) [hereinafter Cargill
Congressional Submission]. Recently courts and
commentators have been addressing the meaning and
application of RAND terms. E.g., Broadcom Corp. v.
Qualcomm Inc., No. CIV A 05-3350 MLC, 2006 WL
2528545 (D.N.J. Aug. 31, 2006) (dismissing allegation
that SSO participant had violated antitrust law by
reneging on a commitment to license on fair,
reasonable, and nondiscriminatory terms), appeal
docketed, No. 06-4292 (3d Cir. Oct. 4, 2006); United
States v. Microsoft Corp., 231 F. Supp. 2d 144, 193
(D.D.C. 2002) (requiring licenses to be offered on
RAND terms and recognizing that “‘reasonableness’
is generally an objective standard”); ESS Tech., Inc. v.
PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 RMW, 2001 WL 1891713,
at *3-*6 (N.D. Cal. 2001) (applying the fifteen criteria
announced in Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood
Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970), as
appropriate to determine RAND calculation in
context of a patent license). Some scholars have
proposed alternative methodologies for determining
appropriate licensing terms. See, e.g., Patterson, 17
BERKELEY TECH. L.J. at 1056-73 (proposing that
benefits to which the patentee is entitled be calculated
by determining portion of demand attributable to the
patentee’s invention); Daniel G. Swanson & William J.
Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND)
Royalties, Standards Selection, and Control of Market
Power, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 25-45 (2005) (advocating
the use of the “efficient component pricing rule” to
determine a competitively neutral licensing fee).
71
See Apr. 18 Tr. at 23-24 (Lemley); id. at 207-08
(Updegrove); id. at 266-67 (Weitzner).
72
Nov. 6 Tr. at 22-23 (Vishny) (stating that hold up is
resolved in a reasonable period of time within the
Telecommunications Industry Association and that
other standard development organizations, such as
the IEEE, the American National Standards Institute
(“ANSI”), and the Alliance for Telecommunications
Industry Solutions, have not had complaints arise
about RAND terms); see also Apr. 18 Tr. at 270-72
(Updegrove) (explaining that competition from other
consortia promotes willingness to license on RAND
terms).
73
E.g., Scott K. Peterson, Consideration of Patents
During the Setting of Standards (Nov. 6, 2002 Hr’g R.)
at 6, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
47
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
Some panelists attributed the potential
inadequacy of a RAND commitment to
the difficulty of defining the terms
“reasonable” and “nondiscriminatory.”
74
Few SSOs give “much explanation of
what those terms mean or how licensing
disputes [are to] be resolved,”
75
and
courts may be reluctant to determine
what is a “reasonable” price.
76
The
meaning of “nondiscriminatory” may be
similarly unclear.
77
Some panelists raised concerns
about the extent to which commitments to
license on RAND terms succeed in
mitigating hold up and whether SSOs are
able to assess the full extent of RAND
failures. Supporting those who believe
that hold up is more widespread than it
appears, one panelist said that “[licensees
are] not going to come back to the SDO
[standard development organization] and
complain [about RAND licensing terms].
The SDOs have made it very clear that
they don’t want to hear about this stuff.”
78
The absence of a good forum for potential
licensees to complain about RAND
licensing terms may enhance licensors’
ability to hold up licensees.
79
2. Royalty-Free Licensing Standards
A few SSOs require IP holders to
commit to royalty-free licensing before
incorporating the IP into a standard.
80
The evolution of the Internet may present
the best opportunity to study market
experiments in royalty-free licensing. For
example, the World Wide Web
Consortium requires all participants to
commit to royalty-free licensing terms.
81
021106peterson.pdf [hereinafter Peterson Submission
II].
74
Nov. 6 Tr. at 63 (Shapiro) (“[S]ince reasonable is so
vague, it doesn’t amount to anything.”); id. at 64
(Thompson) (“RAND [is] an empty term . . . .”); id. at
64 (Vishny) (“[T]he people who are negotiating for
the establishment . . . of a standard don’t know what
[RAND] mean[s].”).
75
Lemley, 90 CAL. L. REV. at 1906; see also id. at 1954
n.272 (“[T]here has not been much in the way of
judicial explication of [RAND licensing terms] so
far . . . .”).
76
One panelist explained: “[T]he insights of modern
economics tell us that prices are determined in
markets and are the result of supply and demand.
It’s not something that’s typically easy for a [c]ourt
sitting as a regulatory body to determine and to
effectively administer. Courts are very, very loath to
take the role of markets. . . . So from the standpoint
of imposing constraints on the possible subsequent
development of market power as the result of
anointment or selection as a part of a standard,
obviously one wants to give incentives to standard
setting organizations. One wants to bestow them
with the power to put limits, effective limits that will
restrain that exercise after the technology is chosen.
And the whole trick is doing that in a way that’s
consistent with antitrust law.” Apr. 18 Tr. at 286-87
(Swanson).
77
See id. at 302-03 (Holleman) (stating that licensing
is nondiscriminatory if licenses are made available to
everyone who requests a license although there is no
guarantee that the terms and conditions of each
license will be identical); see also id. at 272
(Updegrove).
78
Nov. 6 Tr. at 28 (Peterson).
79
See id. at 27-28 (Farrell).
80
See, e.g., Lemley, 90 CAL. L. REV. at 1905
(identifying only four standards groups of the forty-
three studied that require royalty-free licensing of
patents incorporated in a standard); Apr. 18 Tr. at
257-69 (Weitzner) (discussing the World Wide Web
Consortium and the Platform for Privacy
Preferences). In practice, however, a royalty-free
license may not eliminate the need for agreement
concerning the other terms and conditions under
which the license is offered. Apr. 18 Tr. at 191
(Holleman).
81
See, e.g., Press Release, World Wide Web
Consortium, World Wide Web Consortium Approves
Patent Policy (May 21, 2003) (announcing finalized
royalty-free patent policy), http://www.w3.org/
2003/05/patentpolicy-pressrelease.html.en.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION48
Some panelists endorsed royalty-
free licenses as the best means for limiting
licensing hold up and for growing
markets.
82
Some asserted that giving a
royalty-free license might be of little
competitive consequence to an
intellectual property holder that is a
market player. Such might be the case
because the intellectual property holder
could retain a first-mover advantage and
be in the best position to implement the
standard, or the IP holder could license its
other protected technologies that are
complements to those incorporated in the
standard.
83
Others raised concerns about
royalty-free licensing and argued that
royalty-free licenses, even those infused
with a first-mover advantage, might not
provide an efficient incentive for research
and development (“R&D”).
84
One
panelist stated, “economists generally
know[,] and antitrust lawyers generally
suspect[,] that zero is rarely a reasonable
price.”
85
Panelists debated whether
mandatory royalty-free licenses might
represent the ultimate monopsony by
collectively depriving the licensor of the
ability to extract economic benefit from its
intellectual property.
86
Neither Agency advocates that
SSOs adopt any specific disclosure or
licensing policy, and the Agencies do not
suggest that any specific disclosure or
licensing policy is required.
82
Apr. 18 Tr. at 294-96 (Lo); see also Andrew
Updegrove, Observations on the Current Dynamics of
Consortium Standard Setting (Apr. 18, 2002 Hr’g R.) at
3-4, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020418updegrove3.pdf [hereinafter Updegrove
Submission II] (permitting intellectual property
holders to charge royalties in the context of the
Internet could cripple it, while forbidding royalties in
a more limited commercial area might “unnecessarily
deprive a member of the full economic value” of its
intellectual property). Others discussed the value of
“open” standards. See, e.g., Cargill Congressional
Submission at 21-22; Apr. 18 Tr. at 137 (Cargill).
83
Apr. 18 Tr. at 225-26 (Updegrove); David J. Teece &
Edward F. Sherry, Standards Setting and Antitrust, 87
MINN. L. REV. 1913, 1954 (2003) (“[A] patent holder
may be willing to license its patents royalty-free to all
interested parties . . . . [T]his is most likely to occur . .
. when the patent holder will benefit from others’
adoption of its patented technology as a standard
because the patent holder has other complementary
capabilities that will enable it to profit from its
innovation in a manner other than collecting
royalties.”).
84
E.g., Apr. 18 Tr. at 221-22 (Besen).
85
Id. at 288 (Swanson); id. at 289 (“[I]n the intellectual
property realm obviously the reason why we have
intellectual property protection is to give those who
have engaged in costly efforts to create intellectual
property sufficient protection to give them the
expectation that they will get a return for that, some
return greater than zero.”).
86
Compare Nov. 6 Tr. at 66-67 (Farrell) (“[I] think that
[a royalty-free license] raises the technology
monopsony concern much more sharply than ex ante
negotiation . . . . I also think that the way these things
are often structured, they’re as duties on member
participants. And to the extent that . . . might create
an incentive not to join, it seems like that could be a
real concern.”), with id. at 67-68 (Kattan) (“[I] think
[Farrell is] beginning from a faulty factual premise.
The way that the organizations that provide for
royalty-free licensing work is not by requiring
members to commit up front to royalty-free licensing.
It is rather by agreeing that there will be a license,
which will be royalty-free. If you want to take
advantage of the license and get a royalty-free license
from all the other members who agree to sign the
license, then you have to agree to give them a
reciprocal license. So, it doesn’t create a monopsony
problem, it gives you a choice. What is more valuable
to me? Getting a royalty-free license from everybody
else or paying everybody else the royalties that they
may ask for and at the same time charging royalties
for my patents. So, it’s fundamentally different from
the kind of hold-up that [Farrell] is talking about.”).
For a discussion of group buying power, see infra Part
V.B.2.
49
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
V. USING EX ANTE LICENSING
NEGOTIATIONS TO
MITIGATE HOLD UP
In some cases, market factors, IP
disclosures, and commitments to license
on RAND terms may not sufficiently
mitigate the potential for licensing hold
up.
87
Some SSO members have suggested
that SSOs should be permitted to require
IP holders to make specific licensing
commitments that are better defined than
RAND terms. These well-defined
licensing commitments could be
introduced into the standard-setting
process through ex ante unilateral
announcements of licensing terms by IP
holders or through ex ante multilateral
licensing negotiations between IP holders
and the group of SSO members.
An economist at the hearings
noted that “[i]t is efficient [for standard
setters] to choose the technology that
involves the lowest cost of producing
[the] product,” so they would likely
prefer to be able to combine the selection
of technology for a standard with the
negotiation of licensing terms for that
technology.
88
Another panelist explained:
“A truly informed and intelligent decision
[that] . . . would best serve all parties’
interests – including the public’s interest
in competitive market conditions – cannot
be made without knowing what the
patent holder would extract from all users
as the price for admission into the
affected market.”
89
To illustrate this point, the
economist described a stylized setting in
which an SSO needed to select one of
multiple alternative protected
technologies.
90
He suggested that the SSO
could hold an auction and require the
holders of the IP to submitbids”
describing the licensing terms to which
they would agree if their technology were
incorporated into the standard. He
explained that, under his simplifying
assumptions, one would expect such an
auction to result in the SSO selecting the
efficient technology, and that the terms of
the licensing agreement would reflect the
relative benefit of the selected
technology.
91
Several panelists expressed
concern that such auctions or negotiations
could slow down the standard-setting
process, raise the costs of participation,
and potentially result in antitrust
liability.
92
For these reasons, many SSOs
and companies strictly prohibit
discussions of licensing terms within
SSOs.
93
87
Peterson Submission II at 6; Peterson Submission I
at 9-12; see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 59-60 (Farrell).
88
Apr. 18 Tr. at 214-15 (Besen); accord Nov. 6 Tr. at
50-51 (Peterson).
89
Peterson Submission I at 11; accord Lemley, 90 CAL.
L. REV. at 1947 (“[Monopsony problems do] not mean
that members of the SSO should be prohibited from
discussing price. Finding out what a ‘reasonable and
nondiscriminatory’ license will actually cost will help
determine the true value of a proposed standard and
how it compares to possible alternatives.”).
90
Dr. Besen made several other simplifying
assumptions: the alternative technologies are equally
capable of performing in the standard, but they have
different manufacturing costs and the holders of the
relevant intellectual property rights are not members
of the SSO. He also discussed how relaxing the
various assumptions would complicate this analysis.
Apr. 18 Tr. at 217-24 (Besen); Besen Submission at 1-3.
91
See Apr. 18 Tr. at 214 (Besen); Besen Submission.
92
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 33 (Thompson).
93
Peterson Submission I at 9-10 & n.2; Apr. 18 Tr. at
171 (Lemley); see also id. at 153 (Cargill).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION50
A. Practical Reasons for the Lack of
Ex Ante Licensing Negotiations
There was a general consensus
among panelists that a more transparent
process for setting licensing terms is
desirable. Nonetheless, the increased
administrative costs and delays
associated with such transparency led
many panelists to disfavor ex ante
discussions for practical reasons,
independent of antitrust considerations.
94
Several panelists stated that ex ante
licensing negotiations would require
firms to completely overhaul how they
participate in SSOs. Currently, firms are
typically represented at SSOs by technical
experts who focus on selecting the best
technology for a standard, not on
negotiating licensing terms.
95
Multilateral
ex ante negotiations would likely require
lawyers and business and marketing
personnel to also participate in the
process.
96
Such participation would likely
increase the costs and lengthen the
already significant amount of time that it
takes to adopt a standard, which may
dissuade some firms from participating.
97
B. Antitrust Concerns About Ex Ante
Licensing Negotiations
Panelists raised concerns about
two categories of antitrust liability that
could result from ex ante negotiation of
licensing terms: (1) naked agreements to
restrain trade by intellectual property
holders or SSO members, and (2) the
exercise of group buying power by those
that participate in the standard-setting
process.
1. Naked Restraints of Trade by
Intellectual Property Holders or
SSO Members
As discussed above, standard-
setting activities were the subject of
several U.S. Supreme Court decisions
between the 1960s and 1980s that dealt
principally with exclusionary practices
and the “capture” of an SSO by a group of
competitors.
98
These cases have
influenced the strict antitrust compliance
rules and procedures adopted by many
SSOs.
99
94
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 79-80 (Vishny) (asserting that
ex ante discussions are “highly unworkable and
impractical”); Apr. 18 Tr. at 193-94 (Holleman)
(stating that committees do not want to discuss terms
and conditions of licenses).
95
Apr. 18 Tr. at 173 (Marasco); id. at 195 (Holleman).
96
Nov. 6 Tr. at 33 (Thompson) (asserting that Texas
Instruments does not have enough “rare breed”
licensing attorney/engineers to engage in ex ante
negotiations with all of the standards bodies in which
Texas Instruments participates).
97
Id. at 87 (Thompson) (“At some point [ex ante
discussions are] either going to add to my cost,
which, by the way, gets passed on to the consumer at
some point, or it’s going to be we don’t participate in
certain groups. To me, it’s a major longer term
concern and I’m not sure if the thing that we’re trying
to fix, which doesn’t seem to be a real problem, is
worth presenting another problem down the road.”);
see id. at 25-26 (Farrell). However, one panelist
labeled the stated concerns about extra administrative
costs as a “red herring” because Agency guidance
permitting ex ante negotiations would not require
participants to undertake them; it would merely
allow participants to decide for themselves whether it
was worth the costs. Id. at 65-66 (Shapiro).
98
Radiant Burners, 364 U.S. 656; Nat’l Soc’y of Prof’l
Eng’rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978); Am. Soc’y
of Mech. Eng’rs, 456 U.S. 556; Allied Tube, 486 U.S. 492.
99
In 2004, Congress enacted legislation to limit the
potential antitrust liability of SSOs that meet certain
open-process standards. The Standards Development
Organization Advancement Act of 2004 provides that
the antitrust rule of reason applies to these SSOs
51
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
Some panelists extrapolated from
the usual antitrust “presumption that
when competitors get into the same room
together[,] as Adam Smith said, little
good can come out of it.”
100
In the
opinion of those panelists, standard
setting that involves intellectual property
rights raises the potential for section 1 per
se liability for individuals and firms
participating in ex ante multilateral
licensing negotiations.
101
Sham multilateral licensing
negotiations certainly may offer an
opportunity for SSO members to reach
naked price-fixing agreements that lack
plausible and cognizable justifications,
restraints that the Agencies and courts
summarily condemn.
102
For example, if
manufacturers use the cover of
multilateral licensing negotiations to
reach naked agreements on the prices of
the products they sell downstream,
summary condemnation is warranted.
103
Meeting to discuss royalty rates within an
SSO may give manufacturers an
opportunity to discuss downstream prices
with less risk of detection, making
collusion less expensive.
104
Likewise,
summary condemnation would be
justified if IP holders were to reach naked
agreements on the licensing terms they
will propose to an SSO that permits
multilateral licensing negotiations, thus,
while they are engaged in standards development
activities. It also provides special rules for attorney
fees in any antitrust case challenging the standards
development activity of an SSO. In addition,
qualifying SSOs may limit their antitrust liability for
standards development activities to actual, as
opposed to treble, damages if they file a proper
notification with the Agencies. 15 U.S.C. §§ 4301-4305
(Supp. 4 2006).
100
Apr. 18 Tr. at 127 (Gellhorn).
101
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 43-47 (Vishny); Sony Elecs.,
Inc. v. Soundview Techs., Inc., 157 F. Supp. 2d 180 (D.
Conn. 2001) (denying a motion to dismiss an antitrust
claim against a group of standard setters based on
allegations of price-fixing and group boycott).
Soundview alleged that the group sought to fix the
licensing fee for its patent that was likely infringed by
the standard and then refused to accept a license,
choosing instead to challenge the patent’s validity.
Although some cite Soundview for the proposition that
antitrust liability may attach in the ex ante licensing
context, the reliance is somewhat misplaced. The
conduct allegedly giving rise to antitrust liability in
Soundview occurred ex post, after the standard had
been adopted. See also Golden Bridge Tech., Inc. v.
Nokia, Inc., 416 F. Supp. 2d 525 (E.D. Tex. 2006)
(denying defendants’ motion to dismiss plaintiff’s
claim that members of the Third Generation
Partnership Project conspired to remove plaintiff’s
Common Packet Channel technology from a
Wideband Code Division Multiple Process wireless
communications standard set by the organization in
violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act and various
state laws).
102
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.4 ex.7 (describing
likely Agency challenge under the per se rule of “a
sham intended to cloak [the] true nature” of a
particular licensing agreement); Addamax Corp. v.
Open Software Found., Inc., 152 F.3d 48, 52 & n.5 (1st
Cir. 1998) (stating that joint ventures are generally
reviewed under rule of reason “unless they amount
to complete shams”).
103
See United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S.
150, 223-24 (1940).
104
ROGER D. BLAIR & JEFFREY L. HARRISON,
MONOPSONY: ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS 124
(1993) (“[S]ince the parties are permitted to gather for
the purpose of determining a uniform purchase price,
it would be more difficult to detect when they had
crossed over to at least a tacit agreement on selling
price. This decreased likelihood of detection lowers
the risk associated with the price fixing collusion.”);
see also Peterson Submission II at 7 (discussing risk of
collusion on product prices, development, or
marketing). For similar reasons, some fear that
information-sharing among buyer-members of
business-to-business electronic marketplaces could
facilitate downstream coordination. FEDERAL TRADE
COMMN, ENTERING THE 21
ST
CENTURY: COMPETITION
POLICY IN THE WORLD OF B2B ELECTRONIC
MARKETPLACES pt. 3, at 4 (2000), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/10/b2breport.pdf;
Blair & Harrison, Monopsony at 159 (“‘[P]ermission’
to collude as buyers creates a huge danger that
collusion as sellers will also occur.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION52
in effect, rigging their selling bids.
105
2. Group Buying Power
Standards set by SSOs, like all
types of standards, can promote
competition by lowering prices,
increasing consumer choice, or improving
quality. In the absence of nakedly
anticompetitive restraints by an SSO or by
its members, it is appropriate to
determine whether an SSO’s efforts to
reduce opportunities for IP holders to
hold up future users of a standard
violates the antitrust laws pursuant to the
rule of reason. Relying on the rule of
reason when analyzing the competitive
harm that might arise from
implementation of an SSO policy
promoting ex ante licensing negotiations is
appropriate because ex ante negotiations
may mitigate the market power of patent
holders created by SSO members when
they incorporate a particular technology
in a standard that creates or expands a
market for that technology. As one
panelist explained, “to talk about per se
liability is to disregard the integrative
effort that takes place in developing the
standard and in creating the demand for
the technology.”
106
In most cases, it is likely that the
Agencies would find that joint ex ante
activity undertaken by an SSO or its
members to establish licensing terms as
part of the standard-setting process is
likely to confer substantial
procompetitive benefits by avoiding hold
up that could occur after a standard is set,
and this would be an important element
of a rule of reason analysis. Ex
ante licensing discussions may lead to
price competition, in effect allowing for
broader competition among alternative
technologies vying for inclusion in the
standard.
107
Patent holders choosing to
participate in the standard-setting process
would compete against other patent
holders, as well as against public domain
technologies, on the basis of technical
merit and on price and other licensing
terms in order to have their technology
included in the standard. Ex ante
licensing discussions can thus preserve
the benefits of competition that exist by
increasing the ex ante knowledge of SSO
decision-makers about licensing terms
and may improve the quality of their
decisions, enabling them to make
tradeoffs between price and technical
105
See Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. at 223 (“Under
the Sherman Act a combination formed for the
purpose and with the effect of raising, depressing,
fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of a
commodity in interstate or foreign commerce is illegal
per se.”); 12 HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW
2005, at 65-71 (1999).
106
Nov. 6 Tr. at 45-46 (Kattan) (referencing Gail F.
Levine, B2Bs, E-Commerce & the All-Or-Nothing Deal,
28 RUTGERS COMPUTER & TECH. L.J. 383 (2002)); see also
Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S.
1, 20, 23-24 (1979) (holding that blanket license
agreements are not “naked restraints of trade” that
would constitute per se price fixing and should be
examined under the rule of reason); Robert A. Skitol,
Concerted Buying Power: Its Potential for Addressing the
Patent Holdup Problem in Standard Setting, 72
ANTITRUST L.J. 727, 739 (2005) (examining how the
effects of monopsony power fall within the rule of
reason); cf. Patterson, 17 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. at 1078
(“[The SSO itself] should be treated as a single entity
when involved in negotiations related to the
standard. . . . In such circumstances, the individual
members are not pooling their market shares to gain
greater power, but are using the power of the
standard.”).
107
Chi. Bd. of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238
(1918) (“The true test of legality is whether the
restraint imposed is such as merely regulates and
perhaps thereby promotes competition or whether it
is such as may suppress or even destroy
competition.”).
53
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
merit that are not possible unless the price
of patented technological inputs is known
before the standard is set. This ex ante
knowledge may place an upper bound on
a patent holder’s RAND commitment,
and it lowers the risk that users of a
standard will face demands for more
restrictive licensing terms after the
standard is set than SSO members
expected when they chose to include the
patented technology in the standard.
Reducing this risk may speed adoption of
the standard in the marketplace.
Nonetheless, joint ex ante licensing
negotiations may raise competition
concerns in some settings.
108
For example,
such negotiations might be unreasonable
if there were no viable alternatives to a
particular patented technology that is
incorporated into a standard, the IP
holder’s market power was not enhanced
by the standard, and all potential
licensees refuse to license that particular
patented technology except on agreed-
upon licensing terms. In such
circumstances, the ex ante negotiation
among potential licensees does not
preserve competition among technologies
that existed during the development of
the standard but may instead simply
eliminate competition among the
potential licensees for the patented
technology.
VI. AGENCY POLICY
CONCLUSIONS ABOUT
ANTITRUST CONCERNS
ASSOCIATED WITH EX ANTE
LICENSING NEGOTIATIONS
Some SSOs, and their participants,
have hesitated to allow the question of
price to be part of the formal standard-
setting process in any form. They have
allowed neither ex ante unilateral
announcements of licensing terms by
firms that own the protected technology
nor joint discussions about licensing
terms between these firms and the SSO
members.
109
To the extent such
prohibitions are based on concerns about
per se illegality of ex ante agreements on
licensing terms, they fail to account for
the procompetitive reasons SSO members
have to broaden ex ante competition
between technologies beyond the
traditional selection criteria, such as
technical merit.
110
Such ex ante knowledge
about licensing terms could help mitigate
hold up that is not resolved in the first
instance by the existence of SSO rules
requiring disclosure of IP or by
requirements that SSO members license
108
See, e.g., Deborah Platt Majoras, Chairman, Federal
Trade Comm’n, Recognizing the Procompetitive
Potential of Royalty Discussions in Standard Setting,
Remarks at Standardization and the Law:
Developing the Golden Mean for Global Trade 8-9
(Sept. 23, 2005), available at http://www.ftc.gov/
speeches/majoras/050923stanford.pdf (noting that
joint ex ante bargaining could, in theory, reduce
incentives for innovation but questioning whether
that risk would be a frequent practical concern).
109
Marasco Submission at 7, 11; Skitol, 72 ANTITRUST
L.J. at 728-29; Peterson Submission II at 6 (“Some
participants in standards development activities have
refused to permit license terms to be taken into
consideration in the selection of a standard because of
a concern about antitrust risks.”); Lemley, 90 CAL. L.
REV. at 1965 (“[S]ome SSOs expressly forbid
discussion of [the terms on which licenses must be
granted beyond the vague requirement that they be
reasonable] when a standard is under consideration,
presumably for fear of antitrust liability.”); see also
Besen Submission at 2 n.2.
110
Cf. Patterson, 17 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. at 1056
(“Antitrust law can and should distinguish . . .
between collective action that facilitates negotiation in
the patent-standard context and anticompetitive
collusion among potential licensees.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION54
on RAND terms. Because of the strong
potential for procompetitive benefits, the
Agencies will evaluate joint ex ante
activity to establish licensing terms under
the rule of reason. The Agencies’ general
approach to these issues is outlined
below.
First, an IP holder’s voluntary and
unilateral disclosure of its licensing terms,
including its royalty rate, is not a
collective act subject to review under
section 1 of the Sherman Act. Further, a
unilateral announcement of a price before
“selling” the technology to the standard-
setting body (without more) cannot be
exclusionary conduct and therefore
cannot violate section 2.
111
Second, bilateral ex ante
negotiations about licensing terms that
take place between an individual SSO
member and an individual intellectual
property holder (without more) outside
the auspices of the SSO also are unlikely
to require any special antitrust scrutiny
because IP rights holders are merely
negotiating terms with individual
buyers.
112
Third, per se condemnation is not
warranted for joint SSO activities that
mitigate hold up and that take place
before deciding which technology to
include in a standard.
113
Rather, the
Agencies will apply the rule of reason
when evaluating joint activities that
mitigate hold up by allowing the
“buyers” (members of the SSO who are
potential licensees of the standard) to
negotiate licensing terms with the
“sellers” (the rival IP holders) before
competition among the technologies ends
and potentially confers market power (or
additional market power) on the holder of
the chosen technology. Such joint
activities could take various forms,
including joint ex ante licensing
negotiations or an SSO rule that requires
intellectual property holders to announce
their intended (or maximum)
114
licensing
terms for technologies being considered
for adoption in a standard. The
Department recently analyzed an SSO’s
proposal to require member firms to
disclose their intended most restrictive
licensing terms for patents essential to a
standard. Pursuant to the rule of reason,
the Department concluded that it would
not take enforcement action if the policy
were adopted because the policy
111
Michael A. Carrier, Why Antitrust Should Defer to
the Intellectual Property Rules of Standard-Setting
Organizations: A Commentary on Teece & Sherry, 87
MINN. L. REV. 2019, 2036-37 (2003) (stating that
announcing licensing terms before a standard is
adopted is not an antitrust violation); cf. Marasco
Submission at 11 (“Certainly nothing in the ANSI
Policy prohibits a patent holder from voluntarily
disclosing its proposed licensing terms and
conditions.”).
112
Bilateral negotiations between individual SSO
members and individual patent holders already take
place on occasion. Apr. 18 Tr. at 194-95 (Holleman);
Holleman Submission II at 4 (“[O]utside of the
activities of the SDO, individual standards
participants are able to approach the patent holder to
inquire [about] available licensing terms.”).
113
See Majoras, Recognizing the Procompetitive
Potential of Royalty Discussions in Standard Setting
at 7; R. Hewitt Pate, Assistant Attorney Gen., U.S.
Dep’t of Justice, Competition and Intellectual
Property in the U.S.: Licensing Freedom and the
Limits of Antitrust, Remarks at the 2005 EU
Competition Workshop 9-10 (June 3, 2005), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/209359
.pdf.
114
A patent holder may wish to announce a
maximum royalty rate, rather than a single rate
applicable to all licensees if it anticipates that
licensing arrangements with some SSO members
might involve cross licensing, which could lower the
royalty rate appropriate for particular SSO members.
55
Collaborative Standard Setting and Patents
preserved competition between
technologies during the standard-setting
process.
115
If intellectual property holders
turn joint ex ante licensing discussions
into a sham to cover up naked
agreements on the licensing terms each IP
holder will offer the SSO, per se
condemnation of such agreements among
“sellers” of IP rights may be warranted.
Similarly, ex ante discussion of licensing
terms within the standard-setting process
may provide an opportunity for SSO
members to reach side price-fixing
agreements that are per se illegal. The
Agencies will almost certainly treat as per
se illegal any effort by manufacturing
rivals to fix the price of the standardized
products they “sell” instead of discussing
the price of the terms on which they will
“buy” a technology input that is needed
to comply with the standard. However,
such risks are not sufficient to condemn
all multilateral ex ante licensing
negotiations, particularly given the fact
that “[t]hose developing standards
already have extensive experience
managing this risk.”
116
The Agencies do not suggest that
SSOs are required to sponsor such
discussions during the standard-setting
process. Concerns about legitimate
licensing discussions spilling over into
dangerous antitrust territory may
dissuade some groups from conducting
them in the first place. Moreover, it is
fully within the legitimate purview of
each SSO and its members to conclude
that ex ante licensing discussions are
unproductive or too time consuming or
costly.
117
An SSO may also fear that
requiring ex ante commitments to
licensing terms would deter some IP
holders from participating in the
standard-setting process, depriving the
standard-setting process of the expertise
of those IP holders.
The Agencies take no position as to
whether SSOs should engage in joint ex
ante discussion of licensing terms but
recognize that joint ex ante activity to
establish licensing terms as part of the
standard-setting process will not warrant
per se condemnation. Such activity might
mitigate the potential for IP holders to
hold up those seeking to use a standard
by demanding licensing terms greater
than they would have received before
their proprietary technology was
included in the standard. Given the
strong potential for procompetitive
115
Letter from Thomas O. Barnett, Assistant Attorney
Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, to Robert A. Skitol, Esq.,
Drinker Biddle & Reath LLP (Oct. 30, 2006), available
at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/
219380.pdf.
116
Peterson Submission II at 7; see also Vogel v. Am.
Soc’y of Appraisers, 744 F.2d 598, 603 (7th Cir. 1984)
(“[T]he danger that abolishing an anticompetitive fee
system will lead to adoption of an equally or more
anticompetitive one in its place is . . . too speculative
to bring the per se rule into play.”). See generally U.S.
DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
STATEMENTS OF ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT POLICY IN
HEALTH CARE (1996), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep.
(CCH) ¶ 13,153, at 20,812-14, 20,813 n.20 (clarifying
that certain joint purchasing agreements do not raise
antitrust concerns, but that attendant anticompetitive
activities remain unlawful), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/1791.
pdf.
117
See, e.g., IEEE Submission at 5 (“The standard-
setting process is designed to develop the best
technical standard, as independent of marketing and
intellectual property rights issues as possible.”);
Holleman Submission II at 4-5 (“Discussions [within
SSOs about which technology to support] should be
focused on technical issues – not licensing terms and
conditions.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION56
benefits, the Agencies will evaluate joint
ex ante negotiation of licensing terms
pursuant to the rule of reason.
57
CHAPTER 3
ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF
PORTFOLIO CROSS-LICENSING AGREEMENTS
AND PATENT POOLS
I. INTRODUCTION
In many industries, the patent
rights necessary to commercialize a
product are frequently controlled by
multiple rights holders. This
fragmentation of rights can increase the
costs of bringing products to market due
to the transaction costs of negotiating
multiple licenses and greater cumulative
royalty payments. Portfolio cross licenses
and patent pools can help solve the
problems created by these overlapping
patent rights, or patent thicket, by
reducing transaction costs for licensees
while preserving the financial incentives
for inventors to commercialize their
existing innovations and undertake new,
potentially patentable research and
development (“R&D”).
1
A portfolio cross license, under
which two firms license large blocks of
their respective patents to one another,
can provide a partial solution to the
problem of patent thickets because it
removes the need for patent-by-patent
licensing. This bilateral licensing
solution, however, is not likely to be
much help when a firm requires licenses
to a small number of patents held by each
of many firms. In such cases, patent-
pooling agreements may create
substantial transaction efficiencies by
enabling multiple patent holders to pool
their patented technologies and, through
a joint entity, license them as a group to
each other and to third parties. As a
result, patent pools may reduce the
transaction costs of multiple licensing
negotiations and may mitigate royalty
stacking and hold up problems that can
occur when multiple patent holders
individually demand royalties from a
licensee.
2
1
Carl Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross
Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting, in 1
INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY 119, 120
(Adam B. Jaffe et al. eds., 2000) [hereinafter Shapiro,
Navigating the Patent Thicket]; see also discussion infra
Part II.A, II.B. See generally FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
TO PROMOTE INNOVATION: THE PROPER BALANCE OF
COMPETITION AND PATENT LAW AND POLICY ch. 3
(2003) (discussing circumstances under which patent
thickets arise in various industries), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/innovationrpt.pdf
[hereinafter FTC INNOVATION REPORT].
2
U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY § 5.5 (1995), reprinted in 4
Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132, available at
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION58
Although both cross-licensing and
patent-pooling agreements have the
potential to generate significant
efficiencies, they also may generate
anticompetitive effects if the
arrangements result in price fixing,
coordinated output restrictions among
competitors, or foreclosure of innovation.
3
Pooling agreements typically warrant
greater antitrust scrutiny than do cross-
licensing agreements due to the collective
pricing of pooled patents, greater
possibilities for collusion, and generally
larger number of market participants.
The Agencies dedicated several
sessions of the Hearings to the subject of
cross-licensing and patent-pooling
agreements. Participants discussed a
number of topics, including the
similarities and differences between
pooling and cross-licensing agreements,
the potential procompetitive benefits and
anticompetitive effects of pools and cross
licenses, and the safeguards that have
been proposed to help ensure that patent
pools do not harm competition.
4
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.
pdf [hereinafter ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES]; Robert P.
Merges, Institutions for Intellectual Property
Transactions: The Case of Patent Pools, in EXPANDING
THE BOUNDARIES OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY:
INNOVATION POLICY FOR THE KNOWLEDGE SOCIETY 123,
129-30, 132, 144 (Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss et al. eds.,
2000), available at http://www.law.berkeley.edu/
institutes/bclt/pubs/merges/pools.pdf at 10-11, 14,
26 [hereinafter Merges, The Case of Patent Pools]. A
manufacturer may be required to pay royalties for
each patent his product, production process, or
development process infringes. When these
individually priced licensing fees are stacked together
they can represent a significant cost of production.
See discussion of royalty stacking infra Part II.A; see
also discussion of hold up infra Part III.A.
3
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5.
4
Panelists addressing this topic at the April 17, 2002
Hearing included: Garrard R. Beeney, Partner,
Sullivan & Cromwell; Jeffery Fromm, Senior
Managing Counsel, Hewlett-Packard Company;
Baryn S. Futa, Manager and Chief Executive Officer,
MPEG LA, LLC; Peter Grindley, Senior Managing
Economist, LECG, Ltd., London; Christopher J. Kelly,
Special Counsel, Litigation Department, Kaye Scholer
LLP; James J. Kulbaski, Partner, Oblon, Spivak,
McClelland, Maier & Newstadt, PC; Josh Lerner,
Jacob H. Schiff Professor of Investment Banking,
Harvard Business School; David McGowan, Associate
Professor of Law, University of Minnesota Law
School; M. Howard Morse, Partner, Drinker, Biddle &
Reath, LLP; Joshua A. Newberg, Assistant Professor,
Robert H. Smith School of Business, University of
Maryland; Jonathan D. Putnam, Assistant Professor
of the Law and Economics of Intellectual Property,
University of Toronto School of Law; Lawrence M.
Sung, Assistant Professor, University of Maryland
School of Law, Baltimore. This panel was moderated
by Frances Marshall, Special Counsel for Intellectual
Property, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of
Justice; Mary Sullivan, then-Assistant Chief, Antitrust
Division, U.S. Department of Justice; William Cohen,
then-Assistant General Counsel, Policy Studies,
Federal Trade Commission; and Raymond T. Chen,
Assistant Solicitor, U.S. Patent and Trademark Office.
Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Patent Pools and Cross-
Licensing: When Do They Promote or Harm
Competition?, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020417trans.pdf [hereinafter Apr. 17 Tr.].
Portfolio cross-licensing agreements were
also discussed at the afternoon session of the
November 6, 2002 Hearing. The panelists included:
Michelle Burtis, Director, LECG, LLC; Joseph Farrell,
Professor of Economics and Chair of the Competition
Policy Center, University of California, Berkeley;
Jeffrey Fromm, Former Senior Managing Counsel,
Hewlett-Packard Company; Michael McFalls, Partner,
Jones Day, Reavis & Pogue; Barbara M. McGarey,
Chief Counsel, National Institutes of Health; Janusz
A. Ordover, Professor of Economics, New York
University; Charles F. (Rick) Rule, Partner, Fried,
Frank, Harris, Shriver & Jacobson; Carl Shapiro,
Transamerica Professor of Business Strategy, Haas
School of Business, Director and Professor of
Economics, Institute of Business and Economic
Research, University of California, Berkeley. This
panel was moderated by David Scheffman, then-
Director, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade
Commission; Gail Levine, then-Assistant General
Counsel, Policy Studies, Federal Trade Commission;
Sarah Mathias, then-Attorney, Policy Studies, Office
59
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
The Agencies continue to develop
scholarship and guidance on patent pools
and similar licensing agreements. As part
of this process, the Hearing participants
and the Agencies identified a number of
key concerns and best practices that may
be of benefit to patent licensors and
licensees contemplating entering into
cross-licensing and pooling agreements.
II. PORTFOLIO CROSS LICENSES
Portfolio cross licenses are
commonly bilateral agreements between
two parties seeking to avoid infringement
litigation.
5
They are licenses to broad
portfolios of technology, generally related
to a particular field of use.
6
Some
panelists noted that cross licenses usually
grant the licensee the right to use the
patented technology only in a limited
field and for a fixed period of time. Cross
licenses often cover both existing patents
as well as those issued during the period
of the agreement. Panelists further
suggested that most cross licenses require
royalty payments and are granted on a
non-exclusive basis so that the parties
retain the right to license their patents to
others.
7
A. Efficiencies
Portfolio cross licenses may be
especially useful in industries, such as the
semiconductor and computer industries,
that are characterized by large numbers of
overlapping patent rights.
8
The most
of the General Counsel, Federal Trade Commission;
and Frances Marshall, Special Counsel for Intellectual
Property, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of
Justice. Nov. 6, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Relationships Among
Competitors and Incentives to Compete: Cross-
Licensing of Patent Portfolios, Grantbacks, Reach-
Through Royalties, and Non-Assertion Clauses
(Afternoon Session), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/021106ftctrans.pdf [hereinafter Nov. 6 Tr.].
5
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5; see also Feb. 27, 2002
Hr’g Tr., Business Perspectives on Patents: Software
and the Internet (Morning Session) at 356 (Friedman)
(“[In the software industry t]he maintenance of a
patent portfolio serves mainly as a means of keeping
detente or for cross-licensing opportunities.”),
http://www.ftc.gov/ opp/intellect/020227trans.pdf
[hereinafter Feb. 27 Tr.]; Feb. 28, 2002 Hr’g Tr.,
Business Perspectives on Patents: Hardware and
Semiconductors (Afternoon Session) at 662 (Hall)
(stating that software industry participants “pile up a
lot of patents because the other guy has a lot of
patents” and can engage in cross-licensing
negotiations if threatened), http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020228ftc.pdf [hereinafter Feb. 28 Tr.].
6
Peter C. Grindley & David J. Teece, Managing
Intellectual Capital: Licensing and Cross-Licensing in
Semiconductors and Electronics, CAL. MGMT. REV.,
Winter 1997, at 8, 9 [hereinafter Grindley & Teece,
Cross-Licensing in Semiconductors].
7
Peter Grindley, IP, Cross-Licensing and Patent Pools:
Similarities and Contrasts (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.)
(slides) at 6, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020417petergrindley.pdf [hereinafter Grindley
Presentation]; see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 109 (Fromm);
Grindley & Teece, Cross-Licensing in Semiconductors at
17.
8
Nov. 6 Tr. at 97-98 (Shapiro); id. at 99-100 (Fromm).
Panelists did not specifically discuss portfolio cross
licensing as a practice in the pharmaceutical or
biotechnology industries. Feb. 26, 2002 Hr’g Tr.,
Business Perspectives on Patents: Biotech and
Pharmaceuticals (Afternoon Session) at 314-15
(Blackburn), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020226trans.pdf [hereinafter Feb. 26 Tr.]. But see
Lawrence M. Sung, Greater Predictability May Result in
Patent Pools (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.) (discussing
concerns with the proliferation and seemingly broad
scope of some biotechnology patents and the benefits
of patent pooling and other cooperative licensing
arrangements for biotechnology research and
development (“R&D”)), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020417lawrencemsung1.pdf [hereinafter
Sung Submission]. Others cautioned that a
“proliferation of gene patents, including multiple
patents on various research tools” may eventually
create a patent thicket in biotechnology as well.
ORGANISATION FOR ECON. CO-OPERATION & DEV.,
GENETIC INVENTIONS, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS
AND LICENSING PRACTICES : EVIDENCE AND POLICES 15
(2002). More recent papers and presentations also
suggest that patent licensing issues may become more
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION60
significant potential benefit of portfolio
cross licensing is that it allows firms
operating within a patent thicket
9
to use
each other’s patented technology without
the risk of litigation, including the risk of
facing an injunction that shuts down
production.
10
Panelists suggested that
this elimination of risk, or “patent peace,”
can give firms the design freedom they
need to improve current products or
design new products without fear of
infringement.
11
Some commentators
agreed that portfolio cross licensing may
encourage long-term investments in both
manufacturing capacity and R&D because
the parties to the portfolio cross license do
not fear “unforeseen, and unforeseeable,
infringement actions.”
12
Portfolio cross
complex and difficult in the biotechnology industry
in the future. See, e.g., COMM. ON INTELLECTUAL PROP.
RIGHTS IN GENOMIC & PROTEIN RESEARCH &
INNOVATION, NATL ACADS., REAPING THE BENEFITS OF
GENOMIC AND PROTEOMIC RESEARCH: INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY RIGHTS, INNOVATION, AND PUBLIC HEALTH
2-3 (Stephen A. Merrill & Anne-Marie Mazza eds.,
2006) (“[Although IP does not appear to be
hampering current research to any great degree,] the
patent landscape, which already is becoming
complicated in areas such as gene expression and
protein-protein interactions, could become
considerably more complex and burdensome over
time.”); James Simon, Dealing with Patent
Fragmentation: The SARS Patent Pool as a Model (May
27, 2005), http://www.law.kuleuven.be/cir/27-05-
05%20studiedag%20presentaties/SARS%20patent%2
0pool-JSimon.pdf [hereinafter Simon Presentation
Slides].
9
See Feb. 28 Tr. at 667-68 (Detkin) (“[In the
semiconductor industry,] people are tripping over
each other’s patents right and left.”); id. at 684
(Poppen) (“[T]hese [semiconductors] are very
complex products; hundreds, thousands of patents
cover a single product.”); id. at 676-77 (Barr) (“[T]he
proliferation, sheer number of issued patents in our
fields [i.e., the semiconductor and computer
industries] makes it virtually impossible to search all
potentially relevant patents . . . .”); Nov. 6 Tr. at 100
(Fromm) (“In any group of five or 10,000 patents, I’m
reasonably certain that I can find [a patent of mine
infringing] somebody else’s product and vice
versa.”).
10
Nov. 6 Tr. at 102 (Fromm) (“[T]he objective during
that four-year period was to prevent any continuing
litigation over the patent portfolios during that period
so people would be able to design products and ship
them without the threat of injunctions . . . .”); see also
id. at 98, 111 (Shapiro); COMM. ON INTELLECTUAL
PROP. RIGHTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECON., NATL
ACADS., A PATENT SYSTEM FOR THE 21ST CENTURY 37
(Stephen A. Merrill et al. eds., 2004) (“[T]he
avoidance of litigation is important, since litigation
can be especially damaging in an industry where a
new product can provoke multiple infringement suits
and the capital investment required to produce it is
very large.”). In May 2006, the U.S. Supreme Court
held that a categorical grant (or denial) of an
injunction in a patent case was not an appropriate
application of the traditional rules of equity, which
govern patent cases as well as other federal cases
involving injunctions. eBay Inc. v. MercExchange,
L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837 (2006).
11
Nov. 6 Tr. at 111 (Shapiro) (“[M]ultiple companies
who are engaging in these cross-licenses have the
design freedom and the freedom from paying
royalties and therefore, can make better, cheaper
products.”); see also id. at 104-05 (Ordover) (“[I]f you
want to stimulate current product competition then
cross-licensing is an obviously very effective way to
minimize some of the dangers for firms making sunk
investments.”). Consider, for example, AT&T’s
liberal licensing and portfolio cross-licensing policy,
which, according to some, “promote[d] new services
and reduce[d] costs,” making AT&T one of the first
companies to have “‘design freedom’ as a core
component of its patent strategy.” Grindley & Teece,
Cross-Licensing in Semiconductors at 12 (noting this
policy was in place at the time AT&T entered its 1956
consent decree). Grindley and Teece believe that
AT&T created the policy in part because it “figured
that its service customers would be better off if its
technologies were widely diffused amongst its actual
and potential suppliers, as this would lower prices
and increase the performance of procured
components.” Id.
12
DAVID J. TEECE, MANAGING INTELLECTUAL CAPITAL:
ORGANIZATIONAL, STRATEGIC, AND POLICY
DIMENSIONS 139 (2002); see also Apr. 17 Tr. at 228-29
(Grindley) (noting that broad cross licenses reduce
uncertainty over future infringement litigation). The
need for patents to cross license also may foster
future innovation by encouraging small companies to
engage in research and development to obtain their
own patents. Nov. 6 Tr. at 108-09 (Fromm). But cf.
Nov. 6 Tr. at 104-07 (Ordover) (noting that although
broad cross licenses encourage sunk investment from
61
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
licenses also can reduce transaction costs
to licensors by allowing firms to license
multiple patents at once.
13
A portfolio cross-licensing
arrangement among multiple patent
holders may also mitigate the problem of
stacking royalties.
14
Royalty stacking
occurs when access to multiple patents is
required to produce an end product,
forcing the manufacturer’s products “to
bear multiple patent burdens,” usually in
the form of multiple licensing fees.
15
Royalty stacking can make production
unprofitable and retard innovation. But
when a rights holder enters into a
portfolio cross-licensing arrangement, it
may acquire access to all the blocking
technologies required for production at a
lower royalty rate than if each input were
independently priced.
16
As one
economist has stated, a portfolio license
can alleviate the “drag on innovation and
commercialization of new technologies”
that royalty stacking creates.
17
One panelist questioned whether
patent thickets are much of a problem and
suggested that, if a patent holder will not
license a patent or tries to extract a
royalty that is too high, other firms may
respond by designing around the
technology covered by the patent.
18
He
argued that when firms design around
each other’s intellectual property rights,
they avoid royalties, and may be able to
offer newer, less expensive products to
consumers.
19
Others were skeptical that
design-around attempts would be
successful.
20
B. Competitive Concerns
Portfolio cross licenses with
provisions that may facilitate the
incumbents, they could discourage R&D by entrants
who lack portfolios of patents to license).
13
Grindley Presentation at 10; see also Feb. 26 Tr. at
208-09 (Teece) (“[W]hen you have a portfolio . . . you
don’t necessarily know which patents read on which
products, and that if in fact you force unbundling of a
portfolio . . . you require the owner of the intellectual
property to incur a tremendous amount of transaction
costs.”); Grindley & Teece, Cross-Licensing in
Semiconductors at 9 (“It is simply too cumbersome and
costly to license only the specific patents you need for
specific products. The portfolio approach reduces
transaction costs and allows licensees freedom to
design and manufacture without infringement.”). But
see Grindley Presentation at 9 (noting that negotiating
a portfolio cross license is intense, with negotiations
typically lasting eighteen to twenty-four months).
14
Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket at 123-24.
15
Id. at 124.
16
Id. at 123-24.
17
Id. at 124. Royalty-free portfolio cross licenses can
reduce production costs, which may allow licensees
to offer lower prices to consumers because they do
not have to account for per-unit royalties in the final
price of the product. See Nov. 6 Tr. at 98 (Shapiro).
Typically, however, these cross-licensing agreements
are not royalty-free. See Grindley Presentation at 6.
The returns on a portfolio cross license vary. Returns
can be based on fixed fees or running royalties. In the
former case, there may be “balancing payments at the
outset to reflect differences in the strength of the two
companies’ patent portfolios.” Shapiro, Navigating the
Patent Thicket at 130; see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 102
(Fromm); Grindley Presentation at 9.
18
Feb. 28 Tr. at 758-60 (Telecky).
19
Fredrick J. Telecky, Jr., Statement (Feb. 28, 2002
Hr’g R.) at 3 (stating that a product created by design-
around activity may cost the manufacturer less
because the payment of royalties is avoided),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020228telecky.
pdf [hereinafter Telecky Submission].
20
E.g., Feb. 28 Tr. at 676 (Barr) (“[D]esign-around is
very expensive . . . [and] is worse in industries where
a large number of patents have potentially read on a
given product because the likelihood of stepping on a
landmine is so great.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION62
coordination of other activity—such as
the setting of prices, dividing markets, or
licensing to third parties—can raise
antitrust concerns.
21
Some panelists
suggested that a portfolio cross-licensing
regime can pose a barrier to entry if
existing relationships make it harder for
“new firms to come in and overcome the
patent thicket.”
22
Other panelists doubted
that portfolio cross-licensing
arrangements create barriers to entry
because, they said, companies engaged in
portfolio cross licensing are generally
willing to license their portfolios to all
interested parties.
23
Panelists also found
that new firms entering the market
frequently develop their own patents
with their own R&D.
24
C. Analysis
The Agencies continue to
recognize that most of the nonexclusive
cross-licensing agreements of the type
discussed herein generally do not raise
competition concerns. When the licensing
of intellectual property allows firms to
combine complementary factors of
production, such licensing can be
procompetitive.
25
Accordingly, cross-
licensing (and pooling) arrangements
typically are analyzed pursuant to the
rule of reason.
26
Indeed, the case law
generally establishes that both cross-
licensing and patent-pooling agreements
should be so analyzed because, although
21
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 116-17 (Rule) (noting that
patent-pooling and cross-licensing arrangements
could serve as a mechanism for coordinating other
activity, such as prices); John H. Barton, Patents and
Antitrust: A Rethinking in Light of Patent Breadth and
Sequential Innovation, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 449, 464 (1997)
(“[Portfolio cross licenses can be anticompetitive if the
cross-licensing system amounts] to the creation of a
common front in which, in a form of oligopolistic
parallelism, members hesitate to license their own
patents to outsiders, thus protecting the group’s
position even at the expense of the individual firm’s
short-term interest.”); see also ANTITRUST-IP
GUIDELINES § 5.5 (“When cross-licensing or pooling
arrangements are mechanisms to accomplish naked
price fixing or market division, they are subject to
challenge under the per se rule.”).
22
Nov. 6 Tr. at 105 (Ordover). Claims of such an
arrangement arose in the late 1980s when Allied
Signal alleged that Japanese firms had copied certain
Allied technology (while Allied was waiting for
Japanese patents on that technology) and then formed
a licensing cartel to exclude Allied from exploiting its
own technology in Japan. See Janusz A. Ordover, A
Patent System for Both Diffusion and Exclusion, J. ECON.
PERSP., Winter 1991, at 43, 47 n.4; see also A PATENT
SYSTEM FOR THE 21ST CENTURY at 37-38 (“In
semiconductors, for example, the need to have
substantial patent assets to trade in order to
participate in the pervasive cross-licensing of
portfolios probably acts as a barrier to new entrants,
although the enormous capital required to establish
semiconductor manufacturing capacity is an even
more substantial barrier.”).
23
See Jeffery Fromm, Statement (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.)
at 8, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020417jefferyfromm.pdf (stating that such agreements
are pervasive in the high technology sector)
[hereinafter Fromm Submission]; Telecky Submission
at 3.
24
Nov. 6 Tr. at 108-09 (Fromm) (“[Smaller
companies] take one hit for $10 million and then they
very quickly start finding their own patents on their
own R&D.”); see also id. at 111-12 (Shapiro) (noting
that a patent thicket may give small firms with one
patent an advantage negotiating with larger
companies because the smaller firms are likely to
have less financial exposure from hold up in terms of
their revenues than the larger firms); Telecky
Submission at 3 (“After [new firms] themselves have
become technology contributors and have patents of
their own, those patents can be used as trading
material to obtain necessary patent licenses.”).
25
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.3; see also Richard
Gilbert & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Issues in the Licensing
of Intellectual Property: The Nine No-No’s Meet the
Nineties, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY,
MICROECONOMICS 283, 325-26 (stating that assembling
complementary patents enhances their usage, which
in turn causes efficiency gains).
26
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES §§ 3.4, 5.5.
63
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
they have the potential to diminish
competition in some circumstances,
27
they
also can be procompetitive mechanisms
for using technologies that require access
to a large number of patents.
28
The
Agencies’ general approach in analyzing
a licensing restraint pursuant to the rule
of reason is to inquire whether the
restraint “harms competition among
entities that would have been actual or
likely potential competitors” in the
absence of the license and whether the
restraint is reasonably necessary to
achieve procompetitive benefits that
outweigh those anticompetitive effects.
29
“The Agencies apply the same
general antitrust principles to conduct
involving intellectual property that they
apply to conduct involving any other
form of tangible or intangible property.”
30
In evaluating cross-licensing agreements,
patent pools, or any other IP-related
conduct, the Agencies do not presume
that market power is necessarily
associated with an intellectual property
right.
31
The Agencies also do not presume
market power derives from a cross-
licensing agreement (or patent pool)
because there may be viable alternatives
to participation in the licensing
agreement that would preclude the
assertion of market power. The Agencies
believe that antitrust concerns about
exclusion from portfolio cross licenses are
unlikely unless the parties to the portfolio
cross licenses collectively possess market
power.
32
Of course, agreements that are
determined to be mechanisms to
accomplish naked price fixing or market
division are subject to challenge under the
per se rule.
33
The Agencies would be
concerned, therefore, if a cross-licensing
relationship were a method for collusion
on price or output by downstream
producers.
34
27
See supra Part II.B; infra Part III.B, D (discussing
anticompetitive concerns that could arise with both
patent pools and cross-licensing arrangements);
Steven C. Carlson, Patent Pools and the Antitrust
Dilemma, 16 YALE J. ON REG. 359, 376-78, 383-84 (1999);
Apr. 17 Tr. at 107-15 (Newberg). See generally M.
Howard Morse, Cross-Licensing and Patent Pools (Apr.
17, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 4-6, http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020417mhowardmorse.pdf [hereinafter
Morse Submission]; Richard J. Gilbert, Antitrust for
Patent Pools: A Century of Policy Evolution, 2004 STAN.
TECH. L. REV. 3, ¶¶ 6-87 (2004),
http://stlr.stanford.edu/STLR/Articles/04_STLR_3/
index.htm (follow “Acrobat/PDF” hyperlink); Joshua
A. Newberg, Antitrust, Patent Pools and the
Management of Uncertainty, 3 ATLANTIC L.J. 1, 6-21
(2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020417joshuanewberg.pdf.
28
See supra notes 8-13 and accompanying text.
29
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.1; see also id. at §§ 3.3,
3.4, 5.5.
30
Id. § 2.1 (explaining that the flexibility of general
antitrust principles allows the Agencies to take into
account differences between intellectual property and
other forms of property).
31
Id. § 2.2 (“Although the intellectual property right
confers the power to exclude with respect to the
specific product, process, or work in question, there
will often be sufficient actual or potential close
substitutes for such product, process, or work to
prevent the exercise of market power.”). The U.S.
Supreme Court recently adopted this view in the
tying context as well. Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink,
Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281, 1293 (2006). See also supra
Chapter 1, The Strategic Use of Licensing: Unilateral
Refusals to License Patents Part II.B; infra Chapter 5,
Antitrust Issues in the Tying and Bundling of Intellectual
Property Rights Part III.B
32
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5 (“[E]xclusion
from cross-licensing and pooling arrangements
among parties that collectively possess market power
may, under some circumstances, harm competition.”).
33
Id. § 3.4.
34
Such a concern could arise, for example, if
competitors in a market entered into a sham cross-
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION64
The Antitrust-IP Guidelines
provide a safe harbor if the parties to a
cross license “collectively account for no
more than twenty percent of each
relevant market significantly affected by
the restraint,” and the restraint is not
“facially anticompetitive.”
35
The Agencies
recognize that, if a cross-licensing
agreement were to affect a technology
market, market share data may be
unavailable or may not accurately
represent the parties’ competitive
significance in the marketplace. In such
cases, the Agencies would consider
whether “there are four or more
independently controlled technologies in
addition to the technologies controlled by
the parties to the licensing arrangement
that may be substitutable for the licensed
technology at a comparable cost to the
user.”
36
III. PATENT POOLS
A. Efficiencies
Patent pools generally are created
when a group of patent holders each
decides to license its respective patents to
each other and to third parties
collectively. They often are formed when
multiple patented technologies are
needed to produce a standardized
product.
37
One panelist noted that patent-
pooling agreements usually last for the
life cycle of the technology or standard
rather than for a fixed period of time.
38
Patent pools also help to mitigate the
“hold up” and “hold out” problems that
can sometimes stymie industry efforts to
make a product that conforms to an
industry standard. According to some
commentators, hold up can arise when
firms make relationship-specific
investments, after which they may face
efforts by others to recontract for more of
the surplus. The problem derives from
the inability of parties to enter into
complete (and costlessly enforced)
contracts.
39
Others explained that hold
out can arise when buyers need multiple
complementary rights, and sellers arrive
in a sequenced fashion. In such a
situation, players may strategically delay
the start of a negotiation so as to garner
the greatest surplus by becoming the last
licensing arrangement in which each participant
agreed to pay every other participant a large per unit
licensing fee. Such an arrangement would impose a
high effective marginal cost on each competitor which
would help facilitate a tacit agreement to limit output
and raise prices. Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, On
the Licensing of Innovations, 16 RAND J. ECON. 504, 512-
13 (1985).
35
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 4.3.
36
Id.
37
Grindley Presentation at 10; see also James J.
Kulbaski, Comments on Patent Pools and Standards for
Federal Trade Commission Hearings Regarding
Competition & Intellectual Property (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g
R.) at 1 (“A patent pool is the most cost effective and
efficient way of collecting and distributing royalties
for patents that are essential to an industry
standard.”), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020417jamesjkulbaski.pdf [hereinafter Kulbaski
Submission]; Apr. 17 Tr. at 176-77 (Beeney) (“The
high cost of R&D and the increasing need in a global
competitive economy to reduce development costs
and reduce risks that develop initiatives that lead to
marketable products has led to at least two significant
developments: First, product standardization as
efforts are made to avoid format wars . . . ; second,
joint development of single products as multiple
industry participants attempt to share the risk and
costs of new product development.”); id. at 50
(Lerner) (“[F]acilitating the standard setting process
seems to be an important motivation . . . .”).
38
Grindley Presentation at 13.
39
See OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC
INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS,
RELATIONAL CONTRACTING 20-21, 388 (1985).
65
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
bidding seller.
40
As a result, the total
burden of all royalty payments may be
higher than if a single royalty is
demanded by a monopolist of all patents
essential to the production of a final
product.
41
Panelists and commentators noted
that patent pools can reduce transaction
costs for licensees in several ways. For
example, obtaining a pool license may be
less costly than negotiating separate
licenses with each patent owner.
42
By
licensing their pooled patents on a group
basis, patent pool members can offer
“one-stop shopping” to firms seeking to
manufacture products using those
patents. According to panelists, this
simplified approach to licensing can
enable more rapid development and
adoption of new technologies than could
be achieved with cross licensing alone.
43
Some panelists and commentators
argue that pools may reduce costs by
eliminating infringement litigation
44
and,
by using an independent expert to
determine which patents to include in the
pool, reassure licensees that the patents
being licensed are essential to
manufacturing products that comply with
the standard. Additionally, one
commentator suggested that pools can
institutionalize the exchange of non-
patented (or non-copyrighted) technical
information.
45
For these reasons, panelists
noted that patent pools “have become
40
Robert P. Merges, Contracting into Liability Rules:
Intellectual Property Rights and Collective Rights
Organizations, 84 CAL. L. REV. 1293, 1298 n.9 (1996)
(“A holdout is someone who refuses to agree to a
bargain for strategic reasons. For example, if a city
government needs to buy five parcels of land from
property owners A, B, C, D, and E, E might wait until
the other four (A-D) have sold their land. This puts E
in the driver’s seat in bargaining with the city: E can
now charge a very high price—in theory, up to the
total amount the city has to spend on the project,
minus what was paid to A-D—for his or her land.
Since this price will often be more than the average
price paid to A-D, and in any event more than the
price E could have obtained if he or she were not the
last to sell, such a holdout strategy will be rational in
many cases. See generally, Guido Calabresi & A.
Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and
Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L.
REV. 1089, 1106-07 (1972).”).
41
Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket at 121, 123-24;
see also AUGUSTIN COURNOT, RESEARCHES INTO THE
MATHEMATICAL PRINCIPLES OF THE THEORY OF
WEALTH 99-104 (1929) (noting that this problem is
generally known as the “double margin problem”);
Joseph J. Spengler, Vertical Integration and Antitrust
Policy, 58 J. POL. ECON. 347, 347-52 (1950).
42
Grindley Presentation at 10; see also Feb. 28 Tr. at
733 (Barr) (stating that pools limit problems posed by
stacking royalties by consolidating administration);
JEANNE CLARK, JOE PICCOLO, BRIAN STANTON & KARIN
TYSON, U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, PATENT
POOLS: A SOLUTION TO THE PROBLEM OF ACCESS IN
BIOTECHNOLOGY PATENTS? (2000) (asserting that
reducing transaction costs is particularly important
for biotechnology firms), available at
http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/pac/dapp/opla
/patentpool.pdf [hereinafter CLARK ET AL., BIOTECH
PATENT POOLS]; Kulbaski Submission at 7 (suggesting
that the transaction costs for companies seeking to
license seventy-five patents from fourteen licensors
could rival the cost of patent litigation); Merges, The
Case of Patent Pools at 134 (article), 17 (Internet).
43
Kulbaski Submission at 6-7; Merges, The Case of
Patent Pools at 144 (article), 25 (Internet) (stating that
one stop licensing for non-member licenses is an
important pool feature); see also Baryn S. Futa,
Statement (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 1 (“[A]s a
convenience to users who would like to acquire
patent rights from multiple parties in a single
transaction, MPEG LA offers a one-stop license.”),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020417barynfuta.
pdf [hereinafter Futa Submission].
44
Kulbaski Submission at 7; Carlson, 16 YALE J. ON
REG. at 379 (stating that patent pools arising from
litigation settlements can reduce litigation costs); see
also Merges, The Case of Patent Pools at 136-37 (article),
19 (Internet) (asserting that a chief function of the
aircraft pool was to “eliminate ruinous litigation”).
45
Merges, The Case of Patent Pools at 139 (article), 22
(Internet).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION66
critically important mechanisms for
enabling widespread use of new
technologies.”
46
B. Competitive Concerns
The panelists generally noted that
pools composed of pure substitute
patents, (i.e., patents covering
technologies that compete with each other
and that licensees can choose among), are
more likely to harm social welfare than
are pools of complementary patents, (i.e.,
patents covering separate aspects of a
given technology that do not compete
with each other). Pools composed only of
complementary patents tend to increase
efficiencies and lower prices to
consumers. The panelists addressed
other areas that might raise competitive
concern, including whether patents
included in the pool were essential and
valid, whether patent pool members
retained the ability to license their patents
outside of the pool, whether grantback
47
requirements reduce incentives to
innovate, whether access to competitively
sensitive, proprietary business
information should be limited, whether
the Agencies should review pool royalty
rates, and whether pools that refuse to
offer licenses to subsets of the pool’s
patents cause competitive harm. The
panelists also discussed several
mechanisms that could lower the risk of
competitive concerns.
48
The following
sections review the Agencies’ guidance
regarding patent pools and analyze
panelists’ comments on specific issues of
competitive concern.
C. Existing Agency Guidance on
Patent Pools
In recent years, the Agencies have
provided substantial guidance regarding
the antitrust analysis used to evaluate the
potential harms associated with patent
pools and, to a lesser extent, cross-
licensing agreements.
49
As explained in
46
Feb. 28 Tr. at 700 (Fox); see also Fromm Submission
at 1; Sung Submission at 4-6 (discussing the benefits
of patent pooling for biotechnology research and
development); Futa Submission at 2.
47
See definition of grantback infra Part III.D.3.a.
48
See infra Part III.C.3-6.
49
In addition, courts have reviewed antitrust claims
lodged against numerous pooling and cross-licensing
agreements over the past century. See, e.g., Broad.
Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1
(1979) (copyright pooling arrangement); United States
v. Singer Mfg. Co., 374 U.S. 174 (1963); United States v.
New Wrinkle, Inc., 342 U.S. 371 (1952); United States v.
Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287 (1948); United States v.
U.S. Gypsum Co., 333 U.S. 364 (1948); Hartford-Empire
Co. v. United States, 323 U.S. 386 (1945); Standard Oil
Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163 (1931); Standard
Sanitary Mfg. Co. v. United States, 226 U.S. 20 (1912);
Bement v. Nat’l Harrow Co., 186 U.S. 70 (1902); Carpet
Seaming Tape Licensing Corp. v. Best Seam Inc., 616 F.2d
1133 (9th Cir. 1980); Kobe, Inc. v. Dempsey Pump Co.,
198 F.2d 416 (10th Cir. 1952); Baker-Cammack Hosiery
Mills, Inc. v. Davis Co., 181 F.2d 550 (4th Cir. 1950);
Cutter Labs., Inc. v. Lyophile-Cryochem Corp., 179 F.2d
80 (9th Cir. 1949); King v. Anthony Pools, Inc., 202 F.
Supp. 426 (S.D. Cal. 1962). The economic and legal
analyses articulated in these older cases are often less
sophisticated than contemporary antitrust doctrine
developed and applied by the Agencies in other
fields. For example, few earlier opinions give
significant weight to the relationships among the
patents in the pool, whereas modern economic
analysis of patent pools examines whether the patent
rights in the pool are complements or substitutes for
one another. Also the courts’ terminology is
inconsistent. Courts often have applied the term
“patent pools” to arrangements that the Agencies
would now describe as portfolio cross licenses
because these “pools” did not license to third parties.
See, e.g., Hartford-Empire Co., 323 U.S. at 392, 413
(describing licensing agreements where defendants
created a multi-firm portfolio of patents and licensed
them only to each other, not to third parties, as a
“patent pool”); see also Line Material Co., 333 U.S. at
313 n.24 (“The words ‘patent pool’ are not words of
67
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
the Antitrust-IP Guidelines, the Agencies
have two primary concerns when
analyzing the likely effects on
competition of a potential or actual patent
pool. First, horizontal coordination
among the pool’s licensors could lead to
a reduction in price competition among
downstream products. In particular, a
pool that includes patents for substitute
technologies could lead to increased
prices in the final goods market due to the
absence of competition among those
substitute technologies.
50
In addition,
participants in the pool might be able to
use it to collude, for example, by
exchanging competitively sensitive
information, such as pricing, marketing,
or R&D information through the
mechanism of the pool.
Second, the Agencies are
concerned that combining patent rights in
a pool could discourage R&D, new
product development, and cost-reducing
process innovations. Licensors could be
discouraged from making investments in
innovation if “a pooling arrangement . .
. requires members to grant licenses to
each other at minimal cost . . . because
members of the pool have to share their
successful research and development and
each of the members can free ride on the
accomplishments of other pool
members.”
51
Licensees could be
discouraged from innovating if the
licensors do not retain the right to license
their patents independently or if licensees
are not adequately rewarded for
innovations that they grant back to the
pool.
52
The Agencies have supplemented
the pooling analysis found in the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines in several
business review letters issued by the
Department of Justice
53
and in the FTC’s
enforcement action against the patent
pool formed by Summit Technology, Inc.
and VISX, Inc. (“Summit-VISX”).
54
art. The expression is used in this opinion to convey
the idea of a linking of the right to use patents issued
to more than one patentee.”). In recent years, only a
few courts have reviewed antitrust claims involving
portfolio cross-licensing and patent-pooling
agreements. See, e.g., Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v.
Cinram Int’l, Inc., 299 F. Supp. 2d 370 (D. Del. 2004)
(granting summary judgment on antitrust
counterclaims involving a six-company digital video
disc pool and holding pool participants provided
realistic opportunity for individual licensing of
patents).
50
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5. The Guidelines
state that patent pools have the greatest potential to
unreasonably limit competition among entities that
would have been actual or likely potential
competitors in a relevant market in the absence of the
license. Id. §§ 3.1, 4.1, 5.1, 5.5. According to the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines, vertical license restrictions
may harm horizontal competition if they foreclose
access to, or significantly raise the price of, an
important input, or if they facilitate coordination to
increase price or reduce output among competitors.
Id. §§ 4.1, 5.3, 5.4.
51
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5.
52
Id. The guidelines also note, however, that such
pooling arrangements can have procompetitive
benefits, especially if they do not include a large
fraction of the potential research and development in
an innovation market. Id.
53
See infra Part III.C.1.
54
Decision and Order, In re Summit Tech., Inc., 127
F.T.C. 208, 217 (1999) (No. 9286), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/decisions/docs/Volume127.
pdf [hereinafter Summit Consent Decree]; Decision
and Order, In re VISX, Inc., 127 F.T.C. 236 (1999) (No.
9286), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/
decisions/docs/Volume127.pdf [hereinafter VISX
Consent Decree]; Complaint, Summit, 127 F.T.C. at
208 (No. 9286) [hereinafter FTC Summit-VISX
Complaint].
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION68
1. U.S. Department of Justice
Business Review Letters
The Department analyzed patent
pool proposals in three business review
letters issued in the late 1990s: the
MPEG-2 pool Business Review Letter,
55
the three-member DVD pool (“3C DVD”)
Business Review Letter,
56
and the six-
member DVD pool (“6C DVD”) Business
Review Letter.
57
In its 2002 3G Business
Review Letter, the Department analyzed
a patent platform arrangement that
involved five separate wireless
communication technologies and shared
some characteristics of a patent-pooling
agreement.
58
a. The MPEG-2 Pool
MPEG-2 is a digital video
compression technology used in many
different products and services, including
DVDs and telecommunications, as well as
cable, satellite, and broadcast television.
59
When making products that meet the
MPEG-2 standard, a company could
infringe on the patent rights of many
different rights holders. As a result, firms
interested in adopting the MPEG-2
standard hired an independent patent
expert to search for the patents that were
“essential” to its implementation.
60
Nine
companies
61
that held twenty-seven
essential patents among them,
62
along
with one other company,
63
formed MPEG
LA, which acts as the pool’s licensing
administrator.
64
MPEG LA retains an
independent technical expert to
determine whether other patents are
essential to the MPEG-2 standard.
65
MPEG LA assembles and offers a package
of hardware and software licenses to the
pool members’ patents that are
“essential” to comply with the MPEG-2
55
Letter from Joel I. Klein, Acting Assistant Attorney
Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, to G[a]rrard R. Beeney,
Esq. (June 26, 1997), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/21574
2.pdf [hereinafter MPEG-2 Business Review Letter].
56
Letter from Joel I. Klein, Assistant Attorney Gen.,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, to Garrard R. Beeney, Esq. (Dec.
16, 1998), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/
public/busreview/2121.pdf [hereinafter 3C DVD
Business Review Letter]. The original name for this
technology was “Digital Video Disc;” however, the
word “video” was exchanged for “versatile” due to
an expansion of applications for the technology. See
DVD Forum, DVD Primer,
http://www.dvdforum.org/faq-dvdprimer.htm (last
visited Apr. 11, 2007).
57
Letter from Joel I. Klein, Assistant Attorney Gen.,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, to Carey R. Ramos, Esq. (June 10,
1999), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/
busreview/2485.pdf [hereinafter 6C DVD Business
Review Letter].
58
Letter from Charles A. James, Assistant Attorney
Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, to Ky P. Ewing, Esq. (Nov.
12, 2002), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/
public/ busreview/200455.pdf [hereinafter 3G
Business Review Letter].
59
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 2.
60
Id. at 3-5.
61
Id. at 1, 3 (noting that original pool members were
Trustees of Columbia University, Fujitsu Ltd.,
General Instrument Corp., Lucent Technologies Inc.,
Matsushita Electric Industrial Co., Ltd., Mitsubishi
Electric Corp., Philips Electronics N.V., Scientific-
Atlanta, Inc., and Sony Corp.).
62
Id. at 3. As of April 2002, the MPEG-2 pool
included 425 patents (100 patent families) owned by
twenty-one entities. Futa Submission at 2. As of
January 10, 2006, the MPEG-2 pool had grown and
included over 800 patents. See MPEG LA, MPEG-2
Attachment 1, http://www.mpegla.com/m2/m2-
att1.pdf (last visited Apr. 11, 2007).
63
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 3 (Cable
Television Laboratories, Inc.).
64
Id. at 3-4.
65
Id. at 5; see also infra Part III.D.1 (discussing
essentiality as a method for excluding substitute
patents).
69
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
standard, and distributes royalty income
among the contributing patent holders on
a per-patent basis.
66
Pool members and
third parties can challenge the
“essentiality” of patents in the pool, i.e.,
whether access to the patents in the pool
is indeed necessary to manufacture
products in compliance with the
standard.
67
The pool license agreement
also requires every licensee to grant back
licenses to the pool’s members on all
MPEG-2-related patents the licensee may
have or develop.
68
b. The DVD Pools
The Department issued two
business review letters concerning patent-
pooling arrangements related to DVD-
Video and DVD-ROM standards. The
Department issued the first of these, the
3C DVD Business Review Letter, on
December 16, 1998. The 3C DVD pool
was created by three firms licensing a
total of 210 patents.
69
In lieu of an
independent administrator, one of the
licensors, Philips, acts as the joint licensor
on behalf of the other pool members
through bilateral agreements with the
rights holders.
70
Pool members grant
licenses to essential patents (defined as
“necessary (as a practical matter) for
compliance with the DVD[-Video or
DVD-ROM] Standard Specifications”) to
the pool on a nonexclusive basis.
71
The
essentiality of the patents is determined
by a patent expert retained by the
licensors.
72
Royalties are distributed on a
negotiated basis that is not contingent on
the number of patents contributed to the
pool.
73
The Department issued the second
of these letters, the 6C DVD Business
Review Letter, on June 10, 1999. The 6C
DVD pool was formed by six firms.
74
Toshiba acts as the joint licensor for the
pool through a multilateral agreement
with the other five firms.
75
The parties
grant to the pool, on a nonexclusive basis,
licenses to essential patents (defined as
patents that are “necessarily infringed” or
for whichthere is no realistic
alternative” for “implementing the DVD
Standard Specifications.”).
76
Members of
this pool are obliged to offer licenses
independently of the pool.
77
Whether a
patent is “essential” to the standard is
determined by an expert retained by the
66
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 3-4, 6.
67
Id. at 5.
68
Id. at 7.
69
3C DVD Business Review Letter at 1-4 (pool
formed by Koninklijke Philips Electronics, N.V., Sony
Corp. of Japan, and Pioneer Electronic Corp. of
Japan).
70
Id. at 4-5.
71
Id. at 3, 4-5 (internal quotation marks omitted); see
also infra Part III.D.1 (discussing essentiality as a
method for excluding substitute patents).
72
3C DVD Business Review Letter at 3-4, 9-10.
73
Id. at 5-6.
74
6C DVD Business Review Letter at 1 (original pool
members were Hitachi, Ltd., Matsushita Electric
Industrial Co., Mitsubishi Electric Corp., Time
Warner Inc., Toshiba Corp., and Victor Company of
Japan, Ltd.); see also Christopher J. Kelly, Patent Pools
and Antitrust Enforcement – 1997-2001 (Apr. 17, 2002
Hr’g R.) (slides) at 11, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020417christopherjkelly.pdf [hereinafter
Kelly Presentation].
75
6C DVD Business Review Letter at 2-3.
76
Id. at 3 (internal quotation marks omitted); see also
infra Part III.D.1 (discussing essentiality as a method
for excluding substitute patents).
77
6C DVD Business Review Letter at 3.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION70
pool.
78
The licensing program also
provides for a quadrennial review by the
patent expert as to whether the pool’s
patents remain essential to practicing the
standard. It further provides for interim
review of individual patents if their
essentiality is questioned.
79
Royalties are
allocated on a per-patent basis, with some
adjustments for the age of the patent.
80
Both DVD pools require licensees
to grant back to the licensors, as well as to
the other pool licensees, licenses on any
essential DVD patents that they may own
or control during the term of the license,
on reasonable and nondiscriminatory
terms.
81
c. The 3G “Patent Platform” Licensing
Program
The Third-Generation Mobile
Communication System (“3G”) is a digital
wireless communication technology. At
the time the Department issued the 3G
Business Review Letter, there were five
different 3G technologies
82
rather than a
single standard, which was the case in the
patent pools discussed above. As many
as forty-five companies claimed
ownership of patents essential to at least
one of the 3G technologies.
83
A nineteen-
company partnership formed a licensing
arrangement dubbed a “patent platform,”
which proposed creating five separate
and independent licensing “platform
companies,” one for each 3G technology,
with a separate licensing administrator
and board of directors for each.
84
The
platform companies make licensing and
royalty decisions independently, but
coordinate through a single management
company for functions such as promoting
the 3G platform concept and evaluating
patents in order to exclude those that are
not essential to any relevant 3G
technology.
85
Each 3G platform company shares
many features with patent pools. The
platform companies, however, do not
aggregate the essential patents relevant to
a particular 3G technology into a single
license. Instead, each patent is licensed
individually. A licensee may choose to
use “a default Standard License”
established by the relevant platform
company “separately with each essential
patent licensor.” Or a licensee may
choose to use “an Interim License, on
terms similar to the Standard License,
while negotiating terms bilaterally with
the essential patent licensor for a final
license that may vary from the Standard
License.
86
The platform arrangements
are “structured to take into account
substitutability between 3G technologies
by creating an independent PlatformCo to
handle all licensing matters, including
[the] setting of actual royalty rates, with
respect to each individual 3G
technology.”
87
Over time, each platform
78
Id. at 3-4.
79
Id. at 4-5.
80
Id. at 6-7 & n.33.
81
3C DVD Business Review Letter at 6; 6C DVD
Business Review Letter at 8.
82
3G Business Review Letter at 2.
83
Id. at 3.
84
Id. at 4.
85
Id. at 5.
86
Id. at 7.
87
Id. at 10; 3G Business Review Letter at 1 n.2
(“PlatformCo is the generic name for several entities
71
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
company may modify the license terms
for the technology it is administering and
each platform company “independently
determine[s] the key values used to
calculate royalties.”
88
d. The Department’s Review
The Department concluded that
each of these patent-pooling proposals
were likely to create substantial
integrative efficiencies by reducing the
time and expense of disseminating the
patents to interested licensees, clearing
blocking positions, and integrating
complementary technologies. The
Department expected the 3G platform
proposal to deliver somewhat fewer
licensing efficiencies because the patent
rights would not be integrated into a
single bundle.
89
To address the
Department’s concern that the pooling
arrangement could reduce horizontal
price competition between licensors,
which could result in an increase in prices
of products that used the licensed patents
or in a decrease in price competition
between downstream market
participants,
90
each entity engaged an
independent expert to review the patents
and exclude substitute technologies from
the licensing arrangement by admitting to
the pool only those complementary
patents essential to manufacture products
complying with the standard.
91
The
proponents sought to ensure that the
licensing agent did not have access to
competitively sensitive proprietary
information, such as cost data, and
included provisions that prevented such
information from being shared with any
of the licensors or licensees.
92
The Department relied on several
factors to assess whether the pools were
likely to harm innovation.
93
The first was
the statutory presumption that issued
patents are valid,
94
a presumption
reinforced by the mechanisms created by
the pool and platform proponents to
exclude invalid patents from the licensing
arrangements.
95
The Department also
relied upon the proponents
representations that the licensors would
that would be established with licensing-related
responsibilities for essential patents concerning
specific 3G technologies, while ManCo is an entity
that would be established to oversee certain defined
common functions related to 3G patents such as
evaluation of essentiality.”).
88
Id. at 10.
89
See id. at 11.
90
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 11; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 9; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 10; 3G Business Review Letter at 9.
91
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 10-11; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 10-13; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 12-13; 3G Business Review Letter at
10. The distinction between complementary and
substitutable goods arises from a perspective of
consumer demand. More generally, A and B are
economic complements if the demand for A rises as
the price of B falls. A and B are economic substitutes
if the demand for A rises as the price of B rises. HAL
R. VARIAN, INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS: A
MODERN APPROACH 110 (4th ed. 1992); see also Morse
Submission at 3; Roger B. Andewelt, Analysis of Patent
Pools Under the Antitrust Laws, 53 ANTITRUST L.J. 611,
612-14 (1985).
92
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 12; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 13; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 14; 3G Business Review Letter at 13.
93
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 9, 11; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 9; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 10; 3G Business Review Letter at 9.
94
35 U.S.C. § 282 (2000) (“A patent shall be presumed
valid.”).
95
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 9 & n.40; 3C
DVD Business Review Letter at 9; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 10-11; 3G Business Review Letter at
9.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION72
retain the right to license their patents
individually,
96
the scope of grantback
clauses would be limited,
97
the license
agreement would be available to all
interested licensees,
98
and the pool would
provide a clear understanding of the
contents of the license.
99
Following extensive review of the
potential efficiencies and competitive
harms, as well as the safeguards
implemented by the proponents to guard
against these harms, the Department
issued a business review letter in each
case stating that, based on the information
provided, “the Department is not
presently inclined to initiate antitrust
enforcement action against the conduct
you have described.”
100
The Department’s analyses of the
anticipated competitive effects of these
pools and the 3G Patent Platform
pursuant to its business review procedure
may differ from decisions made in the
context of enforcement investigations.
101
Business review letters inform parties of
the Department’s enforcement intentions
based largely on the parties’ description
of the relevant facts before the proposed
activity has commenced. Parties desiring
a favorable business review often
incorporate mechanisms designed to
eliminate or minimize the risk of
anticompetitive effects, in order to give
the Department sufficient confidence in
its assessment of the likely competitive
effects of the proposed activity to permit
the issuance of a favorable letter.
102
Investigations of conduct, by contrast,
typically address whether a party is
violating, or has violated, the antitrust
laws. In an enforcement investigation
examining a patent pool currently in
effect, failure to incorporate all the
safeguards set forth in the pooling
business review letters will not
automatically lead to the conclusion that
a pool is anticompetitive. Rather, the
Agencies will evaluate the particular facts
and circumstances to determine whether
96
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 12; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 13-14; 3G Business Review
Letter at 12; see also 6C DVD Business Review Letter
at 14 n.66.
97
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 13-14; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 14; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 14-16; 3G Business Review Letter at
12.
98
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 11; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 13-14; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 15-16.
99
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 12; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 15; 3G Business Review
Letter at 13.
100
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 17; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 15; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 16; 3G Business Review Letter at 13.
The Department’s response to a business review
request will almost always fall into one of three
categories: (1) the Department does not presently
intend to challenge the proposed conduct, (2) the
Department “declines to state its enforcement
intentions,” or (3) the Department finds that it
“cannot state that it would not challenge the
proposed conduct if it is implemented.” In the
second case, the Department might or might not
challenge the conduct if implemented. In the third
case, such a challenge is probable. U.S. DEPT OF
JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION MANUAL ch. 3, pt. H.1.g.
(3d ed. 1998, rev. 2002), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/foia/divisionmanual/thr
ee.htm.
101
See Antitrust Division Business Review Procedure,
28 C.F.R. § 50.6 (2002). The FTC’s advisory opinion
procedure is similarly differentiated from its
enforcement investigations. See 16 C.F.R. §§ 1.1-1.4
(2003) (FTC advisory opinion procedure).
102
Fromm Submission at 2 (“The MPEG LA and DVD
letters delineate basic rules that can minimize
antitrust risk and that are now widely employed.”);
Morse Submission at 7 (“[The Department’s pooling
business review letters] set forth a road map of
practices that should minimize antitrust risk.”).
73
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
the actual conduct has an anticompetitive
effect.
2. The Summit-VISX Pool
In 1998, the FTC challenged a pool
formed by Summit Technology, Inc. and
VISX, Inc. that contained patents relating
to the manufacture and use of lasers
employed in performing photo-refractive
keratectomy (“PRK”), which is a form of
vision-correcting eye surgery.
103
At the
time, Summit and VISX were the only
firms whose laser equipment had
received marketing approval from the
U.S. Food and Drug Administration for
performing PRK.
104
Through the pool,
Summit and VISX relinquished the right
to license their patents unilaterally, but
each received the right to prohibit the
pool from licensing any third party. The
pool issued no third-party licenses over
its six year existence.
105
In addition, the
pool agreement required each company
to pay a $250 fee for each PRK procedure
performed with its laser equipment. That
fee functioned as a price floor for the
“per-procedure fee” that each company
charged ophthalmologists using its
equipment. As a result, Summit and
VISX both charged doctors $250 for each
PRK procedure they performed.
106
The FTC alleged that the pool
eliminated competition between Summit
and VISX in the sale or leasing of PRK
equipment, and in the licensing of
technology related to PRK.
107
The parties
contended that the pool reduced the
uncertainty and expense of patent
litigation because it included potentially
blocking patents.
108
The FTC rejected the
argument that the parties’ patent
portfolios justified the pool’s complete
elimination of price competition. As the
Analysis to Aid Public Comment
explained, “Summit and VISX could have
achieved these efficiencies by any number
of significantly less restrictive means,
including simple licenses or cross-licenses
that did not dictate prices to users or
restrict entry.”
109
The Complaint further alleged that
patent infringement would not have
precluded either firm from coming to
market, in part because VISX had
procured a key patent through fraud on
the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office
(“PTO”), rendering it unenforceable.
110
103
FTC Summit-VISX Complaint paras. 8, 25-30.
104
Id. para. 6.
105
Id. paras. 9-10; Analysis of Proposed Consent
Order to Aid Public Comment para. 8, In re Summit
Tech., Inc., No. 9286 (F.T.C. Aug. 21, 1998), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/1998/08/d09286ana.htm
[hereinafter Summit-VISX Analysis].
106
FTC Summit-VISX Complaint paras. 11-12.
107
Id. paras. 8, 25-30.
108
Summit-VISX Analysis para. 10.
109
Id.; see also ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 4.2 (“The
existence of practical and significantly less restrictive
alternatives is relevant to a determination of whether
a restraint is reasonably necessary. If it is clear that
the parties could have achieved similar efficiencies by
means that are significantly less restrictive, then the
Agencies will not give weight to the parties’
efficiency claim. In making this assessment, however,
the Agencies will not engage in a search for a
theoretically least restrictive alternative that is not
realistic in the practical prospective business situation
faced by the parties.”).
110
See FTC Summit-VISX Complaint paras. 14-21, 29-
30. In economic terms, a patent blocks “another when
the second cannot be practiced without using the
first;” the patent can neither be substituted for nor, as
a practical matter, invented around. ANTITRUST-IP
GUIDELINES § 2.3; see also Ian Simmons, Patrick Lynch
& Theodore H. Frank, “I Know It When I See It”:
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION74
The FTC’s allegations concerning the pool
were settled through consent orders that
dissolved the agreement.
111
D. Specific Issues of Competitive
Concern
1. Substitutes Within a Patent Pool
a. Competitive Concerns
The panelists generally agreed
that pools composed of pure substitute
patents are more likely to harm social
welfare than are pools of complementary
patents, which tend to increase
efficiencies and lower prices to
consumers. As one panelist stated, “[b]y
combining substitute patents, a pool can
be used as a price-fixing mechanism,
ultimately raising the price of products
and services that utilize the pooled
patents”
112
and thus harming competition
and consumers.
Panelists noted, however, that
categorizing patents as complements or
substitutes is not a simple task. In many
cases, patents in a pool are not pure
complements or pure substitutes, but
display characteristics of both. As one
panelist explained, “as much as we long
to categorize intellectual property neatly
in the conceptually distinct categories of
competing, complementary, [and]
blocking, patents[,] like facts[,] are
stubborn things that frequently defy such
convenient classifications. They may
straddle one or more classifications.”
113
The panelists also discussed
various tests for determining whether a
patent is essential to a standard or
technology. They noted that each of the
pools that received a business review
letter from the Department used a slightly
Defining and Demonstrating “Blocking Patents,
ANTITRUST, Summer 2002, at 48, 49 (“A patent is
blocking if circumventing it (1) is not commercially
practicable, or (2) will not produce a commercially
viable product.”) [hereinafter Simmons et al., Blocking
Patents].
111
VISX Consent Decree at pt. II; Summit Consent
Decree at pt. II. The Consent Decrees also required
each company to license to each other, on a royalty-
free and nonexclusive basis, the patents each firm
contributed to the patent pool. According to the
Analysis to Aid Public Comment, although the
Complaint contended that VISX and Summit could
have competed absent the pool, subsequent sunk-cost
investments in reliance on the pool made a cross
license desirable in order to approximate the
competitive conditions that would have been
achieved had the pool not been formed. Summit-
VISX Analysis para.7. The FTC’s litigation continued
against VISX on allegations that it had procured a key
patent through fraud on the PTO. After the PTO
issued a Reexamination Certificate concerning the
disputed patent, the Commission dismissed the
complaint on this issue. See Order Reopening the
Record and Dismissing the Complaint, In re VISX,
Inc., No. 9286 (F.T.C. Feb. 7, 2001), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2001/02/summitvisxorder.h
tm.
112
Morse Submission at 7; see also CLARK ET AL.,
BIOTECH PATENT POOLS at 10-11 (stating that concerns
about a patent pool expanding monopoly pricing can
be addressed by carefully evaluating whether the
patents are truly “blocking” as outlined in the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines); Josh Lerner, Patent Pools:
Some Policy Considerations (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.)
(slides) at 9 (asserting that pools containing direct or
perfect substitutes harm social welfare),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020417joshlerner.
pdf [hereinafter Lerner Presentation]; Garrard R.
Beeney, Pro-competitive Aspects of Intellectual Property
Pools: A Proposal for Safe Harbor Provisions (Apr. 17,
2002 Hr’g R.) at 5, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020417garrardrbeeney.pdf [hereinafter
Beeney Submission]; Shapiro, Navigating the Patent
Thicket at 134 (“[I]nclusion of truly complementary
patents in a patent pool is desirable and
procompetitive, but assembly of substitute or rival
patents in a pool can eliminate competition and lead
to elevated license fees.”).
113
Apr. 17 Tr. at 107-08 (Newberg); see also id. at 38-39
(Lerner).
75
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
different test for essentiality. In one
panelist’s view, the DVD pools
“economic test” is more efficient than the
MPEG-2 pool’s “technically essential test
for licensees and, therefore, should be
preferred by antitrust enforcers.
114
Another panelist stated that either
definition is acceptable and that few
competitive issues would arise so long as
each definition was faithfully applied.
115
A third panelist noted that the practical
implementation of the different
definitions of essentiality is “pretty much
the same.”
116
Using the criteria that a
patent must contain a claim essential to
implementing the standard was described
by some panelists as an effective means of
assuring that the patents included are not
substitutes.
117
In one panelist’s view,
where no standard has been set, it should
be sufficient to define a clear and limited
field of use for a pool’s license in order to
determine whether the included patents
are complements or substitutes and to
“assess the competitive impact of a pool .
. . on . . . innovation and downstream
product markets.”
118
A number of panelists discussed
whether, and under what circumstances,
substitute patents should be allowed in a
patent pool. One panelist urged the
inclusion of multiple substitute
technologies into pools when licensees
using the pool’s patents must also
infringe one of the substitute technologies
in order to produce or create a
downstream product that complies with
the standard. Including this limited class
of substitutes, he argued, would decrease
transaction costs and increase the pool’s
efficiency.
119
That might be the case, he
suggested, when the manufacturing steps,
calculations, or processes that produce a
defined product could be accomplished in
more than one way.
120
The same panelist asserted that
barring the substitute patents that cover
these functions required licensees to both
acquire a license from the patent pool and
negotiate a license from one of the patent
holders of the competing technologies,
which increases transaction costs.
121
Instead, this panelist suggested that all
competing options be allowed into the
pool and licensees could select which
method to use under the pool license.
122
To retain choice among the competing
technologies, the pool’s members could
require that the portion of the license
royalty attributable to the competing
process be distributed proportionate to
actual use by the licensees, he said.
123
This panelist suggested as an
alternative, albeit a less desirable one, that
114
David McGowan, Enforcement Issues Regarding
Pooling and Cross-Licensing (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 4,
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020417davidmcg
owan.pdf [hereinafter McGowan Submission].
115
Beeney Submission at 8.
116
Apr. 17 Tr. at 210-11 (Kulbaski).
117
Id. at 160-61 (Kelly).
118
Beeney Submission at 5; see also Apr. 17 Tr. at 232-
33 (Beeney).
119
Apr. 17 Tr. at 181-85 (Beeney); Beeney Submission
at 5-7.
120
Apr. 17 Tr. at 181 (Beeney); Beeney Submission at
6.
121
Apr. 17 Tr. at 183 (Beeney); Beeney Submission at
6.
122
Apr. 17 Tr. at 184 (Beeney); Beeney Submission at
7.
123
Apr. 17 Tr. at 185 (Beeney); Beeney Submission at
7.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION76
the pool’s members select one of the
competing technologies for inclusion in
the pool, provided the process of selection
does not disproportionately reward one
patent holder, exclude the others from the
market, or limit licensees’ choice of which
method to employ.
124
Panelists’ reactions to these
proposals were mixed. One panelist
stated that including only one of several
substitute patents in a pool “risks
foreclosing markets to competing patents
outside the pool” because a licensee
would not purchase both a pool license
and a license for a substitute patent, even
if that substitute were a superior
technology.
125
One economist on the
panel asserted that pools containing
patents that inhabit the middle ground of
impure complements and substitutes can
be welfare-enhancing,
126
while another
panelist stated that, although including
partial substitutes in the pool “may
increase transactions efficiency, [it could]
increase [both] administration costs and
antitrust concerns.”
127
b. Analysis
The Antitrust-IP Guidelines state
that “combin[ing] complementary factors
of production . . . is generally
procompetitive.”
128
Analyzing the
competitive effects of a patent pool
depends in substantial part on the
characterization of the patents within the
pool. Accordingly, the Department’s
favorable business reviews of pools have
relied heavily on assurances from the
parties that the pools contain only
complementary patents, stating that “a
combination of complementary
intellectual property rights, especially
ones that block the application for which
they are jointly licensed, can be an
efficient and procompetitive method of
disseminating those rights to would-be
users.”
129
Similarly, the FTC’s Summit-
VISX Complaint challenged the
combining of patents in a pool that were
alleged to cover substitute technologies.
130
124
Apr. 17 Tr. at 184 (Beeney); Beeney Submission at
6-7.
125
Morse Submission at 8; see also Michael R.
Franzinger, Latent Dangers in a Patent Pool: The
European Commission’s Approval of the 3G Wireless
Technology Licensing Agreements, 91 CAL. L. REV. 1693,
1723 (2003) (recommending that 3G licensing
agreements include a clause requiring removal of an
essential patent if a patented improvement is devised
so the improvement and the formerly essential patent
can compete for the license fees); cf. Regis C. Worley,
The MPEG LA Patent Pool: A Rule of Reason Analysis
and Suggestion to Improve Procompetitiveness, 24 T.
JEFFERSON L. REV. 299, 316 (2002) (arguing that the
most procompetitive outcome is to substitute a new
improvement patent for the original essential patent).
126
Apr. 17 Tr. at 38-39 (Lerner); Lerner Presentation
at 9; see also Merges, The Case of Patent Pools at 164
(article), 49 (Internet) (“[S]trict complementarity,
based on industry standards, should not be deemed
essential to future pools.”).
127
Grindley Presentation at 12.
128
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.0.
129
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 9; see also 3C
DVD Business Review Letter at 8-9; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 11. One panelist critiqued the
Department’s terminology, arguing that review
should focus on patent claims, not whole patents.
Apr. 17 Tr. at 215 (Fromm). Although review of the
patents does indeed examine the independent claims
within the patent, once such a claim is deemed
complementary it is not separated from the rest of the
patent so the entire patent is placed within the pool.
Id. at 218-19 (Kulbaski) (“[T]he evaluator looks at one
independent claim and usually picks the broadest
claim . . . . And if that claim is found to be essential,
then I believe the letter issued by the evaluator says
that this patent is then essential to the
standard . . . .”).
130
FTC Summit-VISX Complaint paras. 14-21, 29-30.
77
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
In short, a pool containing
complementary patents, i.e., patents
covering technologies that perform
different functions but are used
collectively to produce the licensed
product, may have the pro-competitive
effect of lowering the total royalty rate to
licensees, thereby lowering the final
product cost to consumers.
131
As noted in
the DOJ business review letters and in the
FTC’s VISX case, a pool containing
substitutable patents, i.e., patents
covering technologies that compete with
each other and that licensee producers
would choose between, may have the
anticompetitive effect of increasing the
total royalty rate to licensees.
132
Thus, an
important part of the analysis of a patent
pool is whether, and to what extent,
licensees use the patents in the pool as
complements or as substitutes.
133
(i) Determining Which Patents May
“Swim” in the Pool
The enforcement conclusions of
both Agencies depend heavily on the
particular facts of each pooling proposal
or existing pool. The Agencies continue
to believe that pools consisting only of
complementary patents are least likely to
prove anticompetitive. One way to
approach the issue of excluding substitute
patents from a pool is to determine
whether a patent is essential for purposes
of complying with a particular
standard.
134
The pooling proposals
approved by the Department have each
defined the term “essential” to the
standard in a slightly different manner.
The MPEG-2 pool limits essential patents
to those that are “technically essential” to
produce a product pursuant to the
standard’s specifications, whereas the
DVD pools also include patents that are
practically (or economically) essential.
135
Although there is a slightly greater
degree of subjectivity in the criterion used
by the DVD pools than in the criterion
used by the MPEG-2 pool, both were
found reasonable based on the facts
presented at the time.
136
If properly
determined, essentiality should guarantee
that the patents in the pool are
complements.
137
The Department has stated that if
several patented technologies could be
used to comply with part of a standard,
then including any of these technological
substitutes in the pool could raise
competitive concerns.
138
The Agencies
131
See supra notes 14-17 and accompanying text
(concerning royalty-stacking in connection with
portfolio cross licenses).
132
See Josh Lerner & Jean Tirole, Efficient Patent Pools,
94 AM. ECON. REV. 691, 695-98, 706 (2004).
133
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 15-16; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 15; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 16; 3G Business Review Letter at 13;
see also FTC Summit-VISX Complaint para. 8.
134
See 6C DVD Business Review Letter at 10; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 8-9.
135
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 9-10; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 3; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 3.
136
See Apr. 17 Tr. at 168 (Kelly).
137
Whether a patent is essential to a standard or
technology also depends on when the determination
is made. For example, a patent may be essential
when the pool is first formed, but as a result of
innovations or changes in the standard, over time that
same patent may no longer be essential. The
Department’s review of the MPEG-2 and 6C DVD
pools noted that both pools had mechanisms for
reviewing essentiality at the formation of the pool
and at later points in time. MPEG-2 Business Review
Letter at 5; 6C DVD Business Review Letter at 3-5.
138
6C DVD Business Review Letter at 11-12.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION78
acknowledge, however, that it might be
reasonable to include substitute patents in
a pool in certain situations. Evaluating
the competitive costs and benefits of a
pool containing substitute technology
would depend, of course, on the facts
available to the Agencies. In the context
of a DVD patent pool, the Department
found that “[i]nclusion in the pool of two
or more [substitute] patents would risk
turning the pool into a price-fixing
mechanism.”
139
At that time, however,
the Department also noted that it would
not challenge the inclusion of substitute
patents in a pool without taking into
account whether such inclusion creates
significant efficiencies.
140
The Agencies’
previous guidance should not be
interpreted to exclude the possibility of
including some substitute patents in the
pool. The Agencies will consider the
inclusion of some substitutes as one of the
many factors in their rule of reason
analysis of any pooling agreement.
(ii) Patent Validity
An invalid or unenforceable patent
is not in a complementary relationship
with other patents in the pool. The
Department’s positive view of patent-
licensing agreements in its business
review letters assumes that the licensed
patents are valid. Some of the pooling
proposals approved by the Department
include a process to eliminate patents
held to be invalid or unenforceable by a
court in order to ensure that only valid
patents are included in the license.
141
Such
mechanisms are important because the
presence of invalid patents in a pool
could raise competitive concerns. For
example, the Summit-VISX pooling
agreement raised competitive concerns
for the FTC in part because a key VISX
pool patent was allegedly obtained by
fraud on the PTO.
142
According to the
complaint, the pooling arrangement
prevented competition that otherwise
would have occurred, and inter alia,
served as a price-fixing mechanism for
PRK technology.
143
2. Exclusive and Nonexclusive
Licensing
a. Competitive Concerns
According to some panelists,
exclusively licensing patents to a pool can
reduce innovation. As one panelist noted,
“licensors and licensees [need to] be free
to combine technology either to improve
or compete with the pooled technology,”
so that products are made at lower cost
over time.
144
Panelists identified both
139
Id. at 12; 3C DVD Business Review Letter at 10.
140
6C DVD Business Review Letter at 12 n.64.
141
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 5; 6C DVD
Business Review Letter at 11. Noting the possible
trade-off in increased administrative costs, one
panelist proposed using independent experts to
evaluate the validity or enforceability of the patents
in the pool as part of the admission process or to
resolve disputes. David McGowan, Enforcement Issues
Regarding Pooling and Cross-Licensing (Apr. 17, 2002
Hr’g R.) (slides) at 10, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020417mcgowan.pdf [hereinafter McGowan
Presentation]; see also Apr. 17 Tr. at 75-77 (McGowan).
The proposed pools reviewed by the Department all
engage an expert to determine essentiality but not
patent validity or enforceability. MPEG-2 Business
Review Letter at 5; 3C DVD Business Review Letter at
4; 6C DVD Business Review Letter at 3-4.
142
See supra notes 103-11 and accompanying text.
143
See FTC Summit-VISX Complaint paras. 14-21, 29-
30.
144
Apr. 17 Tr. at 79, 97-100 (McGowan); McGowan
79
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
licensors and licensees as sources of
resistance to licensing outside the pool.
145
Panelists observed that, if the size of the
pool is small, licensees will have greater
opportunity and incentive to license
outside the pool. According to one
panelist, potential licensees will have less
opportunity and incentive to seek licenses
outside the pool as the number of
licensors in the pool grows, because the
transaction costs associated with
separately acquiring the pool’s patents
will tend to increase.
146
Another panelist
clarified that, although the amount of
independent licensing may decrease as
the size of the pool increases, the size of
the pool would not necessarily affect the
willingness of pool members to support
rival standards or to join other pools.
147
A third panelist explained that
nonexclusivity “leave[s] open the
possibility of some rights that are in that
pool becoming part of different
standards, competing standards, products
that might become substitutes even if
they’re not now, for the pool product.”
148
This panelist noted that whether a pool
member has the incentive to license
independently depends on whether the
license will maximize profits. He
explained that the decision will be based,
in part, on “the expected value of the
innovation on an alternative standard.”
149
b. Analysis
In the pooling proposals reviewed
by the Department, each licensor
proposed granting a nonexclusive license
to the pool and retaining the right to
license its patent outside the pool.
150
By
contrast, VISX and Summit granted
exclusive licenses to the pool and each
company retained veto power to prevent
the other company from licensing the
pooled intellectual property outside the
pool.
151
Exclusive licenses may be
desirable, and thus potentially
procompetitive if they are necessary to
provide a significant incentive for the
licensees to invest in complementary
assets (e.g., when complementary assets
Presentation at 12; see also Apr. 17 Tr. at 157 (Kelly);
Beeney Submission at 14.
145
Apr. 17 Tr. at 69, 85 (McGowan); id. at 86 (Lerner).
One panelist asserted that some licensors are not
motivated to license independently. Id. at 92-93
(Fromm). One court has held that patent pooling
does not violate sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act
when independent licensing is a realistic option,
finding $.06 per DVD disk royalty differential
between cost of the pool license and cost of multiple
individual licenses meant that independent licensing
was a realistic alternative because the differential was
not higher than the value of relevant rights conveyed.
Matsushita, 299 F. Supp. 2d at 377, 379.
146
Apr. 17 Tr. at 86-87 (Lerner) (“To the extent that . .
. the number of . . . licensors in the pool is small, then
the propensity to license outside the pool is high. To
the extent that the number of licensors in the pool is
very large, large being a number, say, greater than
four . . . essentially licensing from, say, five or six or
ten different licensors, the probability of someone
being able to invest the effort and the time . . . goes
down. The opportunity in a large pool to actually do
this licensing outside the pool is in fact . . . for many
firms not a real opportunity. Even firms that have
significant economic incentive to do so, they simply
don’t have the number of hours in the day before a
product has to be introduced.”); id. at 93 (Fromm)
(“[T]he practical realities tend to push [licensees]
towards the pool . . . because of time and cost.”).
147
Id. at 87-88 (Kelly).
148
Id. at 84 (McGowan).
149
Id. at 85 (McGowan).
150
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 4; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 5-6; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 3, 6.
151
FTC Summit-VISX Complaint para. 9.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION80
would be subject to free-riding absent the
exclusive license). Allowing independent
licensing outside the pool, however,
permits innovators that invent around
one or more pool patents to compete with
the pool.
152
Determining the competitive
significance of the exclusive nature of
licenses granted to the pool thus depends
on the specific facts of the case.
Creating the opportunity for
independent licensing does not guarantee
that such a license will be granted. A
pool’s licensors generally are free to
choose both whether to grant separate
licenses and to set the royalty rates for
any such licenses. A competitive concern
would arise, however, if decisions on
licensing outside a pool were part of a
concerted attempt by the pool’s licensors
to hinder the ability of others (outside the
pool) to offer a competitive product or
process.
3. Grantbacks
a. Competitive Concerns
The Antitrust-IP Guidelines define
a grantback as an agreement by which a
licensee extends to the licensor the “right
to use the licensee’s improvements to the
licensed technology.”
153
According to
panelists and commentators, however,
licensors may define a grantback’s scope
more broadly to cover “inventions which
relate in any way to the subject of the
licensed patent,”
154
or even to cover
inventions entirely unrelated to the
licensed technology.
155
Some panelists
noted that broadly written grantbacks can
deter innovation by reducing the returns
available to the follow-on innovator.
156
Of
particular concern to some panelists is the
scope of the rights to be granted back to
the licensor and whether the innovator
retains the right to license to others.
157
b. Analysis
Grantbacks can promote
competition within patent pools by
enabling licensors to practice
improvements that licensees make to the
152
See Lerner & Tirole, 94 AM. ECON. REV. at 698-700.
153
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6.
154
Richard E. Donovan, Antitrust Issues in Licensing,
in ADVANCED LICENSING AGREEMENTS FOR THE NEW
ECONOMY 2001, at 643, 660 (2001).
155
Morse Submission at 14; Nov. 6 Tr. at 117-18
(McFalls) (“[A] grantback is . . . a licensing provision
in which a licensee agrees to license back . . . some IP
which may or may not be related to the initial IP
licensed, for some period of time, in some or all parts
of the world.”).
156
Beeney Submission at 11-12 (suggesting the
breadth of grantbacks should be negotiable
depending on the intellectual property investments of
licensees); Kulbaski Submission at 4-5; Fromm
Submission at 6-7. One panelist suggested that a
grantback licensor should be guaranteed, in most
circumstances, that it will receive a reasonable royalty
for its patents. Beeney Submission at 11-12 & n.16
(noting that a “reasonable” royalty could be that
collected by the licensors and that in at least one
context a grantback need not be royalty-bearing); see
also McGowan Presentation at 12 (asserting that
grantbacks should bear royalties); ANTITRUST-IP
GUIDELINES § 5.6.
157
McGowan Presentation at 12 (asserting that
grantbacks should be nonexclusive). Another
panelist urged the Agencies to more strictly enforce
the limitations on grantbacks articulated in the
business review letters, in particular those that cover
unrelated technologies, future patents, and
nonessential patents. Apr. 17 Tr. at 205-06 (Morse);
see also ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6 (“Compared
with an exclusive grantback, a non-exclusive
grantback, which leaves the licensee free to license
improvements [in] technology to others, is less likely
to have anticompetitive effects.”).
81
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
licensed technology.
158
Grantbacks can
limit the ability of licensees to refuse to
license patented improvements.
159
As a
result, a pool’s licensors (and other
licensees) can continue to produce goods
conforming to the pool’s patents.
Grantbacks can promote innovation
incentives by rewarding first innovators
for enabling follow-on innovation by
others.
160
They also can promote the
subsequent licensing of the results of the
innovation.
161
The Agencies, however, recognize
the concerns raised by the panelists.
Indeed, the pooling proposals reviewed
by the Department contained mechanisms
designed to narrow grantbacks, making
them more likely to be procompetitive.
These grantbacks are limited to
innovations within the scope of the
existing patents in the pool and are
further limited to include only essential
patents, so as to add only complementary
patents to the pool.
162
In addition, the
grantbacks are nonexclusive, so licensees
may freely use their own inventions and
license them to others.
163
Such narrowly
tailored grantbacks are unlikely to raise
competitive concerns.
4. Access to Information
a. Competitive Concerns
Administering a patent pool may
require the pool’s licensing agent to have
access to competitively sensitive
proprietary information of licensors and
licensees, many of which may compete
against each other in downstream
markets. Such was the case in the DVD
pools, for example, where many of the
pools’ licensors and licensees were
competitors in the DVD disc and player
manufacturing markets. Many of them
were also competitors in the market for
content, such as recorded music, films,
and entertainment software, that are
incorporated in the DVDs.
164
A patent
pool could serve as a mechanism that
facilitates downstream price coordination
among the licensors if it were used to
disseminate information between them
about one another’s use of the pool’s
technologies.
165
Innovation incentives
158
See infra Chapter 4, Variations on Intellectual
Property Licensing Practices Part III.A (discussing the
efficiencies associated with grantbacks).
159
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6; Grindley
Presentation at 13; Beeney Submission at 12; see also
Apr. 17 Tr. at 79-80 (McGowan) (asserting that
grantbacks help standards evolve); 1 HERBERT
HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS & MARK A. LEMLEY, IP
AND ANTITRUST: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST
PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW §
25.2, at 25-2 (2002).
160
Suzanne Scotchmer, Standing on the Shoulders of
Giants: Cumulative Research and the Patent Law, J.
ECON. PERSP., Winter 1991, at 29, 31 (stating that first
innovators will have the correct incentive to invest
only if they receive some of the social surplus
provided by second-generation products).
161
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6.
162
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 13; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 8, 14; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 8-9, 14-16; see also ANTITRUST-IP
GUIDELINES § 5.6.
163
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 12-13; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 14; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 14-15.
164
3C DVD Business Review Letter at 2 n.2; 6C DVD
Business Review Letter at 2 n.2.
165
The Agencies have found U.S. markets conducive
to coordinated interaction when certain market
factors are present, including the ready availability of
reliable competitive information, homogeneous
products, and high concentration levels. U.S. DEPT OF
JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, COMMENTARY ON
THE HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES 18-23 (2006),
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION82
might also be reduced if concerns about
others in the pool misappropriating
proprietary information leads rivals
within the pool to invest less in areas such
as product development.
166
b. Analysis
Pooling agreements that limit
licensors’ access to each others
competitively sensitive proprietary
information, such as cost data, output
levels, and prices of final products, lowers
the risk that licensors will be able to
coordinate their activities in final product
markets.
167
Limiting access to such
information also makes it less likely that
rivals within the pool will have concerns
about others misappropriating their data.
Existing pools have used several
mechanisms to keep these types of
information confidential. In the MPEG-2
pooling proposal, the pool hired an
independent licensing administrator so
that the licensors would not be privy to
information gathered from other pool
participants.
168
In both DVD pooling
proposals, where one of the pool’s
licensors also acts as the program
administrator, the parties designed so-
called “walls” to sufficiently limit access
to each others’ sensitive information.
169
5. Royalties for the Pool’s Patents
a. Competitive Concerns
Panelists raised several concerns
about the amount of royalties charged by
patent pools. Some panelists suggested
that licensing terms should be reviewed
over time, set as a reasonable percentage
of the downstream price, or capped in
order to ensure that the royalties remain
reasonable.
170
One panelist suggested that
a pool that charges smaller royalties to
licensors that are also licensees (insiders)
than it charges to pure licensees
(outsiders) might produce
anticompetitive effects in downstream
markets. He argued that doing so would
allow inefficient [licensor] competitors to
dominate downstream markets by
combining the power of the patents in the
pool to the exclusion of efficient
independent competitors.”
171
b. Analysis
The Agencies generally do not
assess the reasonableness of royalties set
by patent pools.
172
Rather, the Agencies
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/
guidelines/215247.pdf.
166
See U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION
POLICY GUIDE TO MERGER REMEDIES 23 (2004), reprinted
in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,171, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/20510
8.pdf.
167
3C DVD Business Review Letter at 11-12; 6C DVD
Business Review Letter at 14.
168
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 4, 11.
169
See Beeney Submission at 13; 3C DVD Business
Review Letter at 7-8, 13; 6C DVD Business Review
Letter at 9-10, 14.
170
Morse Submission at 12; see also Fromm
Submission at 3-4.
171
Morse Submission at 12-13; see also Fromm
Submission at 3; Apr. 17 Tr. at 249-50 (Fromm).
172
See R. Hewitt Pate, Assistant Attorney Gen., U.S.
Dep’t of Justice, Competition and Intellectual
Property in the U.S.: Licensing Freedom and the
Limits of Antitrust, Address Before the 2005 EU
Competition Workshop 9 (June 3, 2005), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/209359
.pdf (“Bringing a complaint to the Antitrust Division
about ‘excessive’ royalties, without more, is a losing
strategy.”). Several panelists were adamant that the
Agencies should not involve themselves in the setting
83
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
focus on the pool’s formation and
whether its structure, including the terms
of the contract among pool participants,
would likely enable pool participants to
raise prices or restrict output in a relevant
market. In the MPEG-2 and DVD
Business Review Letters, the Department
noted that when royalties are a small
portion of the downstream price, it is
unlikely that they are being used to
coordinate downstream prices.
173
Royalties that are a significant portion of
the downstream price, however, do not
necessarily raise concerns, and other
indications of coordination of
downstream prices would be required
before the Agencies would be likely to
investigate further. Indeed, theoretical
economic models show that if only
complementary patents are pooled, the
royalties the pool charges should be
lower than those that would be charged if
no pool were formed.
174
The Agencies will not presume
that different royalty payments faced by
different licensees (e.g., insiders and
outsiders) are anticompetitive. Whether
such an arrangement could be
anticompetitive would depend upon the
specific facts of the case. The Agencies
may examine the structure and amount of
royalties as one of the many factors when
investigating alleged price coordination.
6. Requests for Partial-Pool Licenses
a. Competitive Concerns
Panelists also discussed whether it
harms competition if patent pools do not
offer licensees the option of licensing only
some of a pool’s patents, a partial-pool
license at a lower royalty rate, instead of
offering only a single comprehensive
blanket license.
175
One panelist asserted
that partial licenses are needed because,
even if a pool were originally devised to
include only those patents deemed
essential to a standard, over time some of
those patents would no longer be
essential to all the pool’s licensees.
176
In
addition, some licensees may desire
partial licenses if they already have access
to some of the necessary technology
through pre-existing licenses. In such
instances, one panelist asserted that
requiring a blanket license forces licensees
to pay for access to intellectual property
they do not need.
177
Other panelists responded that
offering only a blanket license is not
harmful to those seeking a partial license,
provided that the pool members retain
the right to license their contributed
patents independently, thereby creating
the opportunity to enter into bilateral
of pools’ royalties. According to one panelist:
“Marketplace acceptance is the best gauge of fair and
reasonable [licensing terms] . . . . Every license must
be priced to sell. In the end, we are dealing with very
sophisticated users who have many market choices.”
Futa Submission at 3; Apr. 17 Tr. at 245 (Futa).
Another panelist stated that lawyers are not well-
equipped to set royalties and that pools would
disappear if the freedom to set royalties disappeared.
See Apr. 17 Tr. at 283 (Beeney).
173
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter at 11; 3C DVD
Business Review Letter at 13; 6C DVD Business
Review Letter at 14.
174
Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket at 123-24,
149-50; Lerner & Tirole, 94 AM. ECON. REV. at 695-97.
175
Apr. 17 Tr. at 246-77 (Futa, Fromm, Kelly, Beeney,
Grindley, Morse).
176
Id. at 251 (Fromm).
177
Fromm Submission at 4-5.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION84
agreements for particular patents.
178
Furthermore, one panelist argued, if pools
were required to let firms pick and choose
which patents they wanted and then had
to vary the royalties accordingly, the pool
administrator could be required to offer
many different permutations of licenses,
perhaps at differing royalties.
179
In such
situations, some panelists suggested that
a pool offering partial licenses in addition
to the broader pool license may not create
the efficiencies that flow from reducing
transaction costs.
180
b. Analysis
In general, a refusal to license less
than all of a pool’s intellectual property
will not raise competitive concerns,
provided that the licensors retain the
ability to license their patents
individually and the pool’s design is
otherwise procompetitive. In this way,
licensees are not required to purchase
access to more technology than they need.
However, the combined price of the
individual licenses may be more than the
price of the pooled patents which benefits
from lower transaction costs. In addition,
although partial pool licensing could be
used to cull nonessential patents from the
pool over time, requiring such partial
licenses would tend to undermine the
chief efficiency benefit of pooling
arrangements, namely, the ability to offer
as close to “one-stop shopping” as
possible for a given technology.
181
Other
more efficient means to accomplish this
goal are available, such as continuous
review of the licensed patent portfolio
that is designed to exclude patents from
the pool that have become nonessential
over time.
IV. CONCLUSION
Both cross licenses and patent
pools are based on reciprocal agreements
to share patent rights,
182
and they can
achieve similar efficiencies,
183
including
integrating complementary technologies,
reducing transaction costs, clearing
blocking patents, decreasing infringement
litigation and the uncertainties related to
178
Apr. 17 Tr. at 262-63 (Futa). But see id. at 252
(Fromm) (asserting that the possibility of negotiating
individual licenses is “more illusory than real”);
Fromm Submission at 5 (“[Individual licensing is
problematic due to] major transaction costs and time
required for multiple negotiations; holders’
disincentives to entertain negotiations; likelihood that
the sum of individually negotiated royalties would
significantly exceed the prescribed package license
royalty; and the likely necessity of exchanging
competitively sensitive information with one’s
competitors in the administration of individual
licenses.”).
179
Apr. 17 Tr. at 275-76 (Beeney); see also Futa
Submission at 5 (stating licensees could attempt to
customize, in myriad ways, number of patents, length
of term, and parts of the standard).
180
Apr. 17 Tr. at 267-68 (Grindley); id. at 274-77
(Beeney). Moreover, according to one pool
administrator, the market develops subset licenses
when multiple firms request such a license. Id. at 262-
63 (Futa). In response, one panelist noted that the
ability to license fewer than all the patents in a pool is
important for the first mover, who will have lost the
innovation advantage once multiple firms start
requesting a specific subset license. Id. at 264-66
(Fromm); see also Fromm Submission at 5.
181
See supra Parts III.A, III.C.1.d.
182
See Joel I. Klein, Acting Assistant Attorney Gen.,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Cross-Licensing and Antitrust
Law, Address Before the American Intellectual
Property Law Association 3 n.3 (May 2, 1997),
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/
speeches/1118.pdf; Andewelt, 53 ANTITRUST L.J. at
611.
183
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5; Apr. 17 Tr. at 178
(Beeney); McGowan Submission at 2; Kelly
Presentation at 5.
85
Cross Licensing and Patent Pools
it, and promoting the dissemination of
technology. Although pools and cross
licenses seek to achieve these benefits via
methods that differ in fundamental ways,
the competitive analysis set forth in the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines is robust enough
to take these differences into account.
Indeed, the panelists generally agreed
that the Agencies’ guidance regarding the
antitrust analysis of patent pools and
cross-licensing agreements is sound.
184
That analysis acknowledges that
cross licensing and patent pooling can
offer substantial efficiencies, but also that
they sometimes present certain
competitive risks. Provisions in portfolio
cross licenses that may facilitate price
fixing, for example, can raise antitrust
concerns. The Agencies generally review
portfolio cross licenses under the rule of
reason.
The Agencies likewise generally
review patent pools under the rule of
reason. As noted above, patent pools can
help firms cut through overlapping
patent rights and bring products to
market. However, in certain
circumstances, they can also facilitate
horizontal coordination among the pool’s
licensors or discourage innovation. For
example, there may be an anticompetitive
risk in a pool containing substitute
patents. One solution is to exclude
substitute patents from the pool by
ensuring that each patent is essential to
the standard, or principle, around which
the pool is organized. Likewise,
exclusivity in patent pools can provide
incentives for procompetitive investment,
but may also pose competitive concerns
regarding reduced innovation. Similarly,
broadly written grantbacks in a patent-
pooling agreement can promote
competition by giving licensors access to
downstream improvements, or they can
erode incentives for future innovation.
Moreover, limiting licensors’ access to the
competitively sensitive information of
others in the pool can minimize the
anticompetitive risk of improper
information sharing in the pool.
Despite concerns voiced about the
anticompetitive potential of “high
royalty rates in a pool, the Agencies
generally will not police the
“reasonableness” of pool royalty rates.
Likewise, pool licensing provisions that
require the licensing of all (not just some)
of the pool’s intellectual property do not
generally raise competitive concerns if the
licensors retain the ability to license their
patents individually and the pool’s design
is otherwise procompetitive.
184
Apr. 17 Tr. at 193 (Morse); Feb. 27 Tr. at 512
(Shapiro) (“[B]y and large the [A]gencies have done
well to recognize the benefits of cross-licenses and
patent pools, and they should affirm those benefits
going forward. . . . [T]he DOJ’s . . . business review
letters in the MPEG and DVD patent pools . . . were
exemplary in that respect.”); Apr. 17 Tr. at 175
(Beeney); id. at 57 (McGowan); id. at 40 (Lerner); Feb.
28 Tr. at 700 (Fox).
87
CHAPTER 4
VARIATIONS ON INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LICENSING
PRACTICES
I. INTRODUCTION
For over a decade, the Agencies
have relied on the Antitrust Guidelines
for the Licensing of Intellectual Property
(“Antitrust-IP Guidelines”) to aid in their
analysis of complex licensing practices.
1
Recognizing that intellectual property
(“IP”) rights are critical to a well-
functioning market economy, the
Agencies crystalized some fundamental
principles regarding the intersection of IP
and antitrust law and policy in the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines. These principles
include recognizing that: (1) an IP right
does not necessarily create market
power;
2
(2) agreements involving IP can
be analyzed using the same antitrust rules
applied to agreements involving any
other property;
3
and (3) IP licensing is
generally procompetitive.
4
The vast
majority of licensing restraints “can be
expected to contribute to an efficiency-
enhancing integration of economic
activity,” by, for example, “facilitat[ing]
the combination of the licensor’s
intellectual property with [other]
complementary factors of production.”
5
The Agencies therefore will evaluate such
1
U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (1995), reprinted in 4 Trade
Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.
pdf [hereinafter ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES].
2
Id. § 2.2.
3
Id. § 2.1.
4
Id. § 2.0.
5
Id. § 3.4. Recognizing that intellectual property
licensing is generally procompetitive, many foreign
jurisdictions have followed the United States’ lead in
creating transparency in this area by adopting their
own intellectual property guidelines. E.g.,
COMPETITION BUREAU, GOVT OF CAN., INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY ENFORCEMENT GUIDELINES (2000), available at
http://www.strategis.ic.gc.ca/pics/ct/ipege.pdf;
Guidelines on the Application of Article 81 of the EC
Treaty to Technology Transfer Agreements (EC), 2004
O.J. (C 101) 2, available at http://www.europa.eu.int/
eur-lex/pri/en/oj/dat/2004/c_101/
c_10120040427en00020042.pdf; JAPAN FAIR TRADE
COMMN, GUIDELINES FOR PATENT AND KNOW-HOW
LICENSING AGREEMENTS UNDER THE ANTIMONOPOLY
ACT (1999), available at http://www.jftc.go.jp/
e-page/legislation/ama/patentandknow-how.pdf;
KOREA FAIR TRADE COMMN, GUIDELINES OF
REVIEWING UNDUE EXERCISE OF INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY RIGHTS (2000), available at http://ftc.go.kr/
data/hwp/ irp_guidelines.doc; COMPETITION
COMMN OF SING., GUIDELINES ON THE TREATMENT OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS (2005), available at
http://www.ccs.gov.sg/NR/rdonlyres/A67B68FC-D
B6F-415B-9DF1-5A97FC6855A9/6714/CCSGuideline
onIPR20051228websitefinal2.pdf; TAIWAN FAIR TRADE
COMMN, RULES FOR REVIEW OF TECHNOLOGY
LICENSING ARRANGEMENT CASES, available at http://
www.globalcompetitionforum.org/regions/asia/Tai
pei/Technology%20Licensing.pdf.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION88
agreements pursuant to the rule of
reason.
6
During the Agencies’ Hearings on
Competition and Intellectual Property
Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Economy, panelists discussed several
licensing practices that have the potential
to promote licensing efficiencies,
including non-assertion clauses,
7
grantbacks,
8
and reach-through licensing
agreements.
9
They considered when
these practices might be procompetitive,
under what circumstances they might be
anticompetitive, and whether the
Antitrust-IP Guidelines provide adequate
guidance for evaluating the antitrust
implications of these arrangements.
10
The
panelists generally agreed that the basic
principles set forth in the Antitrust-IP
Guidelines are preferable to bright line,
per se rules that affirmatively approve or
condemn a specific licensing practice
without regard to the circumstances in
which it is being employed.
11
Moreover,
panelists agreed that, although theories of
anticompetitive licensing practices may
exist, identifying such scenarios in
practice requires a highly fact-specific,
case-by-case analysis. Consequently,
applying simple rules to broad classes of
behavior can risk great inefficiency.
12
To
avoid this risk, the Agencies will continue
to use the flexible rule of reason to assess
the competitive significance of the
licensing arrangements discussed in this
Chapter, evaluating a particular
agreement’s ability to harm or enhance
competition in the factual circumstances
in which it arises.
13
II. NON-ASSERTION CLAUSES
According to panelists, non-
assertion clauses typically provide that a
contracting party will not assert patents
or other IP rights against the other
contracting party, even if that party were
to engage in an infringing use.
14
Panelists
said that such clauses are entered into for
a variety of reasons, but that, as a
practical matter, non-assertion clauses
serve one of the same functions as a
license or cross license, i.e., they permit
6
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.4.
7
See infra Part II.
8
See infra Part III.
9
See infra Part IV.
10
The panelists discussing these topics included:
Michelle Burtis, Director, LECG, Inc.; Joseph Farrell,
Professor of Economics and Chair of the Competition
Policy Center, University of California, Berkeley;
Jeffery Fromm, Former Senior Managing Counsel,
Hewlett-Packard Company; Michael McFalls, Partner,
Jones Day Reavis & Pogue; Barbara M. McGarey,
Deputy Associate General Counsel, National
Institutes of Health; Janusz A. Ordover, Department
of Economics, New York University; Charles F. (Rick)
Rule, Partner, Fried, Frank, Harris, Shriver &
Jacobson; Carl Shapiro, Transamerica Professor of
Business Strategy, Haas School of Business,
University of California, Berkeley. The panel was
moderated by Gail Levine, then-Deputy Assistant
General Counsel for Policy Studies, Federal Trade
Commission; Frances Marshall, Special Counsel for
Intellectual Property, U.S. Department of Justice;
Sarah Mathias, then-Attorney, Policy Studies, Federal
Trade Commission; and David L. Scheffman, then-
Director, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade
Commission. Nov. 6, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Relationships
Among Competitors and Incentives to Compete:
Cross-Licensing of Patent Portfolios, Grantbacks,
Reach-Through Royalties, and Non-Assertion Clauses
(Afternoon Session), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/021106ftctrans.pdf [hereinafter Nov. 6 Tr.].
11
E.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 146-47 (Rule); see also id. at 185-86
(Shapiro).
12
See, e.g., id. at 145 (Ordover).
13
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.4.
14
Nov. 6 Tr. at 121-22 (McFalls).
89
Other IP Licensing Practices
the contracting parties to avoid costly
litigation over the use of an IP right.
15
A
non-assertion clause is “a convenient way
for people to be able to effectively give
comfort to somebody they would
otherwise license,” one panelist
explained.
16
In this respect, panelists
stated, non-assertion clauses are similar to
nonexclusive, royalty-free licenses that
allow the parties to allocate risk and to
avoid litigation by contract.
17
Panelists
observed that non-assertion clauses can
appear in multilateral or bilateral
agreements, and they can cover existing
or potential future patents, or both.
18
Pure non-assertion clauses that do not
transfer a right to use the patent, do not,
by themselves, provide for the transfer of
know-how, something that frequently
accompanies the affirmative licensing of
patent rights.
19
A. Efficiencies of Non-Assertion
Clauses
Panelists stated that non-assertion
clauses may create efficiencies akin to
those created by patent licenses.
20
For
example, one panelist said that non-
assertion clauses tend to reduce
transaction costs because they “guarantee
to the licensor . . . that any intellectual
property issue that exists at [the time of
the license negotiation] will be surfaced
by the licensee.”
21
Indeed, according to
this panelist, the licensee typically will
benefit by, in effect, “charging” the
licensor for the value of the right it is
giving up—a right to assert a hidden
blocking patent, for example.
22
This
panelist reported that non-assertion
agreements also can facilitate the sharing
of information, because a licensor who is
unafraid of the eventual developments of
blocking patents is more likely to
“provide information and details that
otherwise might be used by the licensee
to develop a blocking patent position.”
23
The panelist asserted that such exchanges
of information are procompetitive
because both parties to the non-assertion
agreement avoid hidden blocking
patents.
24
Finally, the panelist saw an
15
Id. at 121 (McFalls) (“[I]nstead of giving somebody
an affirmative grant . . . [you] say, within this field,
just as with a license, I’m not going to [sue] you on
patents that I have today.”); see also id. at 127-28
(Rule).
16
Id. at 121 (McFalls).
17
Id.; id. at 125 (Farrell) (stating that a non-assertion
clause is essentially “royalty-free permission to use
one another’s IP”).
18
Nov. 6 Tr. at 122-23 (Fromm); id. at 127-28 (Rule).
Non-assertion agreements may also encompass
different categories of IP rights. For example, a non-
assertion agreement may permit use of one type of IP
(e.g., patents) in return for use of a different type of
intellectual property (e.g., copyright). Id. at 123
(Fromm).
19
Cf. David J. Teece, Peter Grindley & Edward
Sherry, Understanding the Licensing Option, in
MANAGING INTELLECTUAL CAPITAL 135, 135-38 (2000)
(discussing when know-how is typically transferred
between firms).
20
One panelist stated that a licensor may negotiate a
non-assertion clause in lieu of a grantback to prevent
its licensee from asserting a hidden blocking position
after the product has become successful. Nov. 6 Tr. at
127-28 (Rule). This panelist explained that non-
assertion clauses can cover both existing and future
portfolios, whereas a grantback generally is limited to
future technology. Id. at 127 (Rule).
21
Id. at 128 (Rule).
22
Id.
23
Id. at 129 (Rule).
24
Id.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION90
additional potential benefit if a non-
assertion clause can eliminate patent hold
up for the licensor’s other licensees
because the clause applies to the licensor
and to “those who license from the
licensor.”
25
B. Competitive Concerns Regarding
Non-Assertion Clauses
Panelists expressed concern over
the use of broad non-assertion clauses,
such as those that are unlimited in scope
or duration, or are more extensive than a
license. Some panelists noted that such
clauses raise competitive concerns
because, by limiting the ability of
licensees to collect rents on their own IP,
they may discourage independent
innovation.
26
Another concern is that a
broad non-assertion agreement between
the only two participants in a market may
help to maintain an illegitimate duopoly
or monopoly if the participants agree not
to challenge each other’s questionable
patents.
27
Invalid patents impair
competition,
28
and as a matter of patent
policy, challenges to their validity are
encouraged.
29
As the Solicitor General
recently urged, “[w]hile patent licensing
in general should be encouraged because
it allows the efficient exploitation of
technology and promotes competition
and innovation, public policy strongly
25
Nov. 6 Tr. at 129 (Rule). One panelist also noted
that non-assertion clauses may be used in lieu of a
license to avoid breaching an exclusive licensing
obligation in another contract or to provide a means
of avoiding the application of a “Most Favored
Nation” (“MFN”) clause in another licensing
agreement. Id. at 121 (McFalls). Another panelist
reported that courts have not accepted attempts to
label grantbacks as non-assertion clauses so as to
avoid having to comply with a MFN clause. Id. at 123
(Fromm).
26
Id. at 136 (Fromm) (“[A broad non-assertion clause]
can’t help but be a disincentive to the licensee, the
grantor of the non-assert, to further innovate because
essentially what [it has] done is [it has] eliminated the
patent thicket, that’s for sure.”); see also id. at 137-38
(Rule) (“[Y]ou can certainly abuse a non-assert if it’s
way too broad and it’s unconnected to the underlying
licensed technology.”); id. at 143 (Fromm) (stating
that the proper focus is on whether the non-assertion
clause is “significantly more extensive” than the
scope of a license). According to panelists, although a
patent thicket has the potential to impede innovation
when access to certain inputs necessary for
production is difficult, the elimination of a patent
thicket altogether can slow innovation when no firm
has the incentive to innovate by designing around an
infringing patent. See, e.g., Frederick J. Telecky, Jr.,
Statement (Feb. 28, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 3 (“Without the
need to design around, simple inertia and
practicalities such as the necessity of qualifying a new
product with customers can be a barrier to
innovation.”), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020228telecky.pdf.
27
See R. Hewitt Pate, Acting Assistant Attorney Gen.,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust and Intellectual
Property, Address Before the American Intellectual
Property Law Association 2003 Mid-Winter Institute
9 (Jan. 24, 2003) (“[P]otential concerns may arise with
agreements among IPR holders not to challenge one
another’s IPR claims through either innovation or
litigation . . . .”), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/
atr/public/speeches/200701.pdf.
28
FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, TO PROMOTE
INNOVATION: THE PROPER BALANCE OF COMPETITION
AND PATENT LAW AND POLICY, Executive Summary, at
5 (2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/
10/innovationrpt.pdf [hereinafter FTC Innovation
Report].
29
See Lear v. Adkins, 395 U.S. 653, 674 (1969)
(“[E]nforcing [a] contractual provision [that would
require a licensee to continue to pay royalties during
the time it is challenging the patent’s validity in
courts] would undermine the strong federal policy
favoring the full and free use of ideas in the public
domain.”); see also MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc.,
127 S. Ct. 764, 777 (2007) (“We hold that [a licensee is]
not required, insofar as Article III is concerned, to
break or terminate its 1997 license agreement before
seeking a declaratory judgment in federal court that
the underlying patent is invalid, unenforceable, or not
infringed.”).
91
Other IP Licensing Practices
favors ridding the economy of invalid
patents, which impede efficient licensing,
hinder competition, and undermine
incentives for innovation.”
30
Public policy
also concomitantly favors the swift
resolution of patent litigation on terms
not harmful to competition.
31
III. GRANTBACKS
A grantback is “an arrangement
under which a licensee agrees to extend to
the licensor of intellectual property the
right to use the licensee’s improvements
to the licensed technology.”
32
Panelists
said that a grantback is similar to a non-
assertion clause in that it provides the
freedom to use a particular intellectual
property right, but it encompasses only
future improvements.
33
Panelists noted
that the two arrangements are often
negotiated in the same way,
34
and that
their economic effects are virtually
identical.
35
According to panelists, the scope,
terms, and duration of grantbacks vary.
36
One panelist stated that a grantback may
give exclusive rights to use future
improvements solely to the licensor,
leaving none to the licensee,
37
or it may
allow both parties to share those rights to
the exclusion of others.
38
Conversely,
panelists noted, a grantback may be
nonexclusive, thus allowing one or both
contracting parties to license to others the
right on the improvement.
39
Grantbacks
may be limited by geographic scope or
territory or by field of use, a panelist
explained.
40
According to one panelist,
grantbacks “may not be related to the
initial IP licensed.”
41
For example, a
research tool patent license may grant
back to the licensor the rights to make a
drug created with the use of the research
tool patent, even though the patent
30
Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae
Supporting Petitioner at 23-24, MedImmune, 127 S. Ct.
764 (No. 05-608) (internal citations omitted), available
at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2005/3mer/
1ami/2005-0608.mer.ami.pdf.
31
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5 (“Settlements
involving the cross-licensing of intellectual property
rights can be an efficient means to avoid litigation,
and in general, courts favor such settlements.”); Brief
for the United States as Amicus Curiae at 17, Andrx
Pharms. Inc. v. Kroger Co., 543 U.S. 939 (2004) (No. 03-
779) (recognizing that settlements that end litigation
may “facilitate innovation and investment in the
patented technology by eliminating litigation risks
and providing certainty over patent rights”) (internal
quotations omitted), denying cert. to In re Cardizem CD
Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896 (2003), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2004/2pet/6invit
/2003-0779.pet.ami.inv.pdf; cf. id. at 8 (“Although
‘public policy wisely encourages settlements’ of legal
disputes, McDermott, Inc. v. AmClyde, 511 U.S. 202,
215 (1994), it does not follow that all settlements are
in the public interest.”).
32
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6; see also supra
Chapter 3, Antitrust Analysis of Portfolio Cross-
Licensing Agreements and Patent Pools Part III.D.3
(noting that patent pools may include grantbacks to
access newly developed, essential IP).
33
See Nov. 6 Tr. at 119, 121-22 (McFalls); id. at 120,
124 (Fromm).
34
Id. at 123-24 (Fromm).
35
Id. at 124 (Fromm) (referring to nonexclusive
agreements); id. at 124-25 (Shapiro); see also discussion
of non-assertion clauses supra Part II.
36
See Nov. 6 Tr. at 118-19 (McFalls); id. at 120
(Fromm).
37
Id. at 118 (McFalls).
38
Id. at 118-19 (McFalls).
39
Id. at 119 (McFalls); see also id. at 120 (Fromm)
(stating that grantbacks, at least as to improvements,
are “reasonably pervasive” in the computer industry).
40
Nov. 6 Tr. at 118 (McFalls).
41
Id. at 117-18 (McFalls).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION92
claiming the drug would not infringe the
research tool patent.
42
One panelist
explained that like many other licensing
arrangements, grantbacks may or may
not be royalty-free.
43
A. Efficiencies of Grantbacks
The Agencies already have noted
that grantbacks, particularly those that
are nonexclusive, can offer efficiencies to
licensees and licensors.
44
A grantback can
facilitate downstream licensing because it
provides a good way to value the licensed
intellectual property, one panelist
asserted, stating that a grantback is “a
useful way for the original licensor to get
some value later on [when an] initial
contract may be hard to write.”
45
Moreover, a nonexclusive grantback can
“serve as [an] alternative[] to higher
royalty rates where the nature and value
of future improvements is uncertain.”
46
The Agencies recognize that a grantback
can foster the sharing of risk and “reward
the licensor for making possible further
innovation based on or informed by the
licensed technology.”
47
Panelists stated
that, like a non-assertion clause, a
grantback can also facilitate bargaining
48
and encourage information exchange by
eliminating a licensor’s concern that a
licensee will assert a blocking patent
position in the future.
49
B. Competitive Concerns Associated
with Grantbacks
Panelists stated that the primary
anticompetitive concern presented by
grantbacks is their potential for adverse
effects on innovation.
50
Some have
expressed concern that an exclusive
grantback that allows only the original
licensor to reap the rewards of any
follow-on invention can deter innovation
42
See Michael A. Heller & Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Can
Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in
Biomedical Research, 280 SCIENCE 698, 699 (1998); Jane
Nielsen, Reach-Through Rights in Biomedical Patent
Licensing: A Comparative Analysis of Their
Anticompetitive Reach, 32 FED. L. REV. 169, 170-71, 176
(2004); see also infra Part IV (discussing reach-through
licensing agreements).
43
Nov. 6 Tr. at 118 (McFalls).
44
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6; see also 1 HERBERT
HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS & MARK A. LEMLEY, IP
AND ANTITRUST: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST
PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW
§§ 25.2 to -.4, at 25-2 to -10 (2002) [hereinafter 1
HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST].
45
Nov. 6 Tr. at 133 (Ordover).
46
1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 25.2, at
25-2 (“Nonexclusive grantback clauses are virtually
always competitive.”).
47
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6.
48
According to one panelist, grantbacks in the
biomedical field aid in valuing a research tool, for
example, by granting back an option to a license on
the end product. Nov. 6 Tr. at 151-52 (McGarey).
49
See, e.g., id. at 128-29 (Rule) (stating that the same
efficiencies are associated with non-assertion clauses).
50
Id. at 135 (Farrell); see also id. at 133-34 (Ordover).
The anticompetitive concerns associated with the use
of grantbacks within a patent pool are discussed in
Chapter 3, Antitrust Analysis of Portfolio Cross-
Licensing Agreements and Patent Pools, and are
essentially the same as those noted here. Broad
grantback clauses that, for example, “cover entirely
unrelated technology, [cover] future as well as
present patents, [or] cover non-essential as well as
essential patents,” may deter innovation and should,
according to panelists, engender antitrust scrutiny.
M. Howard Morse, Cross-Licensing and Patent Pools
(Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 14, http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020417mhowardmorse.pdf; see Apr. 17
Tr., Patent Pools and Cross-Licensing: When Do
They Promote or Harm Competition? at 204-05
(Morse) (recognizing that Department of Justice
business review letters had approved grantback
provisions that were structured so as not to impede
innovation), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020417trans.pdf.
93
Other IP Licensing Practices
because the licensee will receive none of
the benefits from any future
improvements it might make.
51
One
panelist stated that, as in the case of a
non-assertion clause, the disincentive to
innovate increases if the grantback
provision “is larger in scope than the
forward-going license or longer in
duration than the . . . license [for which
the grantback is conveyed].”
52
Some have
argued that grantbacks also have the
potential to extend improperly a
patentee’s market power because
“numerous improvements made by
different licensees all come back to the
original patentee. The patentee can then
use all the improvements, not merely to
obtain control of the affected technology
during the life of the original patent, but
often for a subsequent time as well.”
53
These potential concerns, however,
must be measured against the “but for”
world; that is, the Agencies must consider
the amount of innovation that might have
occurred in the absence of the licensing
restraint.
54
As noted earlier, grantback
provisions can make follow-on
innovation possible. Without the security
of a grantback provision, a licensor may
be hesitant to share its intellectual
property with others, fearing that it might
be prevented from accessing and
benefitting from follow-on improvements
to its own technology.
55
IV. REACH-THROUGH LICENSING
AGREEMENTS
Reach-through licensing
agreements grant the owner of a patent
on an upstream research tool
56
the right to
receive consideration based on sales or
usage of a subsequent downstream
product created with that tool.
57
For
example, a reach-through licensing
agreement might allow a pharmaceutical
company to use a patented research tool
to identify components of what becomes
a marketable drug without paying
royalties to the tool owner before
commercialization of the product.
58
51
1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 25.3, at
25-6 to -7.
52
Nov. 6 Tr. at 120 (Fromm); see also id. at 137
(Fromm) (“[T]here ought to be heightened scrutiny
whenever there is . . . a significant difference in the
grantback or the non-assertion provisions in the
forward-going licenses.”).
53
1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 25.3, at
25-7; see also John H. Barton, Patents and Antitrust: A
Rethinking in Light of Patent Breadth and Sequential
Innovation, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 449, 461-62 (1997).
54
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES §§ 3.1, 3.3.
55
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.6; supra Part III.A;
see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 128-29 (Rule) (discussing how
grantbacks and non-assertion clauses can promote
cooperation and information exchange between
licensor and licensee).
56
Patented research tools, which have primarily
arisen in the pharmaceutical and biotechnology
fields, are technologies “used to find, refine, or
otherwise design and identify a potential product.”
FTC INNOVATION REPORT ch. 3, at III(D)(1)(c); see also
Nov. 6 Tr. at 159 (McGarey) (“[I]n the context of
reach-through [licensing agreements] . . . we’re
talking about broad enabling tools that are not
destined to be products themselves . . . .”).
57
FTC INNOVATION REPORT ch. 3, at III(E)(1).
Although a research tool is used to develop a new
product, the sale or use of the new product generally
will not infringe the claims of the research tool patent.
See Feb. 26, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Business Perspectives on
Patents: Biotech and Pharmaceuticals (Afternoon
Session) at 260 (Blackburn) (“[A research tool] is not a
patent that covers the final product that is the subject
of ongoing manufacture and sale.”),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020226trans.pdf
[hereinafter Feb. 26 Tr.].
58
Heller & Eisenberg, 280 SCIENCE at 699; see also
Janice M. Mueller, No “Dilettante Affair”: Rethinking
the Experimental Use Exception to Patent Infringement for
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION94
Rather, the research tool owner would
opt to “reach through” and receive a
royalty based on a percentage of the
drug’s future sales.
59
This arrangement
can be particularly valuable to the
contracting parties in cases in which the
creator of the downstream product has
only limited ability to pay or borrow
funds to cover up-front licensing costs.
60
Reach-through licensing agreements may
also include the ability to use future
patented inventions, including the option
to license the final product created using
an upstream research tool.
61
A. Efficiencies of Reach-Through
Licensing Agreements
According to panelists, reach-
through licensing agreements can create
efficiencies when they promote the
dissemination of an upstream research
tool, by, for example, creating a way to
value the research tool or establish a
reasonable royalty.
62
Some have reported
that the initial fee for use of a patented
research tool may be difficult to
determine when there is no “commercial
product in existence” and “the research
tool owner and the tool user may have
very different views about the proper
economic valuation of the tool.”
63
Panelists said that by allowing the
research tool patent owner to accrue
royalties on sales of downstream
discoveries in lieu of up-front royalties,
the parties are better able to assess the
value of the research tool by taking into
account the value of the product
developed using the research tool.
64
Reach-through licensing agreements also
permit the research tool owner and
follow-on researchers to share innovation
risks, with the research tool owner
gambling that his tool will lead to the
development of a commercially viable
Biomedical Research Tools, 76 WASH. L. REV. 1, 16
(2001); Nielsen, 32 FED. L. REV. at 171.
59
Heller & Eisenberg, 280 SCIENCE at 699.
60
See Mueller, 76 WASH. L. REV. at 16.
61
Heller & Eisenberg, 280 SCIENCE at 699; Nielsen, 32
FED. L. REV. at 171; see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 151-52
(McGarey) (stating a reach-through licensing
agreement may take the form of a grantback of an
option to exclusively license the downstream
innovation).
62
Nov. 6 Tr. at 155 (Burtis) (“[If] whatever is
commercialized never has a market, then the person
who has bought the tool ends up paying a very little
amount for the tool.”); id. at 171 (Rule) (suggesting
the Agencies should not be concerned with reach-
through license agreements because the agreements
“essentially captur[e] the value created by intellectual
property” and allow for a broader dissemination of
the technology); see also Nielsen, 32 FED. L. REV. at 171
(“Reach-through rights allow patent holders to
license and reali[z]e value on their inventions even
when that value is speculative. In this respect, they
encourage the dissemination of patented inventions
and are likely to have a positive effect on
innovation.”); Mueller, 76 WASH. L. REV. at 59
(“[Reach-through license agreements are] an
expedient method of measuring the value of the use
of the research tool rather than an unlawful leverage
of the patent right.”); Nov. 6 Tr. at 151-52 (McGarey)
(acknowledging that a reach-through arrangement is
a way to value the technology).
63
Mueller, 76 WASH. L. REV. at 16.
64
See Nov. 6 Tr. at 154-56 (Burtis) (“[P]eople [like]
reach-through agreements because . . . [they are] a
way to efficiently price . . . .”); Feb. 26 Tr. at 279
(Blackburn) (“I think that really reduces to a price
negotiation, how much does the tool owner profit
from the successful development of a product. So
that allocation of risk I think is taken care of in the
pricing.”); see also Nielsen, 32 FED. L. REV. at 176 (“If
an upstream invention is subsequently determined to
be a foundational research tool, setting a value on it
too early would deprive the patent holder of valuable
income, and allow the licensee to reali[z]e a windfall
gain. Reach-through rights allow the patent holder to
defer decisions about the value of research tools and
technologies.”).
95
Other IP Licensing Practices
product.
65
In this way, reach-through
licenses may facilitate an efficient
allocation of risk when there is
uncertainty regarding the value of the
licensed technology.
B. Competitive Concerns About
Reach-Through Licensing
Agreements
Panelists were primarily concerned
that reach-through licensing agreements
could impair innovation in downstream
markets
66
because of “royalty stacking”
by multiple research tool owners.
67
Royalty stacking occurs when royalties
are owed to multiple licensors. As one
panelist noted, when “one company
comes in and asks for five percent,
another company comes in and asks for
five percent, . . . all of a sudden you’re . .
. giving away a hundred and twenty
percent, three hundred percent of your
revenues to various patents.”
68
Although
no rational firm would knowingly agree
to give up all its profits, some have
expressed concern that the cumulative
royalties of all upstream holders have the
potential to stifle follow-on innovation if
they reach a level at which
commercialization of the improvement is
no longer profitable from a business
perspective.
69
Thus, some fear royalty
stacking may result in a “tragedy of the
anticommons” whereby “people under
use scarce resources because too many
owners can block each other.”
70
At the
Hearing, the Deputy Associate General
Counsel of the National Institutes of
Health (“NIH”) explained that NIH
adopted a policy discouraging the use of
reach-through royalty agreements
65
See, e.g., Feb. 26 Tr. at 275 (Blackburn) (“Reach-
through royalties are a way to lower the up-front
costs for the smaller firms and to have a risk-sharing
arrangement basically with the tool owner . . . .”). But
see id. at 278 (Oehler) (questioning whether “risk is
truly shared” when a tool may prove valuable in
early stages of research and development but the end
product fails in clinical trials).
66
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 153 (McGarey) (arguing that
reach-through agreements can result in a “pile-up” of
royalties that impair innovation); July 10, 2002 Hr’g
Tr., Trends in Federal Circuit Jurisprudence (Morning
Session) at 56-57 (Scherer) (stating that numerous
upstream patents can impede downstream
innovation by, among other things, attempting to
collect royalties individually), http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020710trans.pdf; Oct. 30, 2002 Hr’g Tr.,
Competition, Economic, and Business Perspectives on
Substantive Patent Law Issues: Non-Obviousness
and Other Patentability Criteria at 175 (Stoner)
(asserting that when an upstream patent manages the
downstream flow of innovations it could lead to less
downstream commercialization),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/021030trans.pdf
[hereinafter Oct. 30 Tr.].
67
See Mueller, 76 WASH. L. REV. at 7 (“Innovation is
impeded by the ‘royalty stacking’ problem imposed
by the numerous upstream patents that must be
practiced in order to make the new downstream
product.”); ORGANISATION FOR ECON. CO-OPERATION
& DEV., GENETIC INVENTIONS, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY
RIGHTS AND LICENSING PRACTICES: EVIDENCE AND
POLICIES 63 (2002) [hereinafter GENETIC INVENTIONS]
(“The concerns evoked about reach-through royalties
are that they increase royalty stacking, as multiple
tests and assays are needed when developing a
medicinal product[;] that they make project
management more complex and the relationship to
all collaborators more delicate[;] and that they are
costly to negotiate.”).
68
Feb. 27, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Business Perspectives on
Patents: Software and the Internet (Morning Session)
at 415 (Kohn) (noting the high transaction costs
stemming from proliferating patents),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020227trans.pdf.
69
See, e.g., GENETIC INVENTIONS at 61-62 (describing
the large number of license agreements
pharmaceutical companies must enter).
70
Heller & Eisenberg, 280 SCIENCE at 698; see also Feb.
26 Tr. at 310-11 (Kirschner) (explaining the potential
for an anticommons problem in the biotechnology
industry due to the proliferation of reach-through
royalty agreements); FTC INNOVATION REPORT ch. 3,
at III(D)(4)(a).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION96
because they may impose restrictions on
the IP developed using the tool, as well as
create multiple royalty obligations
associated with downstream discoveries.
71
Some have argued that reach-
through licensing does not allow a
patentee to capture excessive royalties
and does not pose a concrete harm to
innovation. As one panelist explained:
“If the licensor . . . is about to propose a
royalty that’s going to kill the product
they’re not going to make any money.
And most of the players in this field are
sophisticated enough to understand
that.”
72
In any event, the inefficiencies
associated with royalty stacking can occur
even without the use of reach-through
licensing agreements.
73
Thus, some
panelists opined that reach-through
licensing agreements raise no real
competitive concerns unless licensors
adversely affect innovation by prohibiting
entry or exploitation of the upstream
research tool or downstream products.
74
In addition, another panelist reported that
extensive interviews of people in the
biomedical industry demonstrated that
the “anticommons” had not developed.
75
Panelists also suggested that reach-
through agreements could reduce
incentives to challenge a potentially
invalid patent or the scope of protection
claimed by the patent “by specifying that
payments continue even if the patent
were to be found invalid or the product
[is] non-infringing.”
76
Other panelists
asserted that the collection of royalties on
a patent that is beyond its statutory term
or scope could amount to an antitrust
violation or patent misuse.
77
These
71
Nov. 6 Tr. at 152-53, 158 (McGarey) (discussing the
problems reach-through agreements pose for the
NIH); see also Principles and Guidelines for Recipients
of NIH Research Grants and Contracts on Obtaining
and Disseminating Biomedical Research Resources,
64 Fed. Reg. 72,090, 72,091 (Dec. 23, 1999), available at
http://ott.od.nih.gov/pdfs/64FR72090.pdf; Mueller,
76 WASH. L. REV. at 7-8, 16 (discussing NIH’s
position). To foster access to protected research tools,
for which a license on reasonable terms cannot be
freely negotiated, the National Research Council of
the National Academies recommends that federal
research-sponsoring agencies assume liability for
patent infringement arising from the use of a
protected research tool by including an
“authorization and consent” clause in research
funding instruments. COMM. ON INTELLECTUAL PROP.
RIGHTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECON., NATL
ACADS., A PATENT SYSTEM FOR THE 21ST CENTURY 115-
17 (Stephen A. Merrill et al. eds., 2004).
72
Feb. 26 Tr. at 315 (Blackburn) (“[Most research tool
owners are] fairly sophisticated and know that [they
will] kill the goose if the stack is too high.”).
73
If numerous complementary patents are necessary
to create a new innovation and these patents are
valued independently by multiple licensors, then the
total royalties paid generally will be greater than they
would be if all patents were controlled by a single
licensor. See, e.g., Carl Shapiro, Navigating the Patent
Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard
Setting, in 1 INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY
121, 122-23 (Adam B. Jaffe et al. eds., 2000). In
economics, this problem is known as “double
marginalization” and can be mitigated with the use of
a patent pool. See supra Chapter 3, Antitrust Analysis
of Portfolio Cross-Licensing Agreements and Patent Pools
Part III.D.1.b.
74
See Nov. 6 Tr. at 169 (Ordover); id. at 171-72 (Rule);
id. at 169-70 (McGarey) (“[NIH] certainly [does not]
like reach through [licensing agreements] . . . but I
don’t think I can say that it’s anticompetitive or it’s
something that the Federal Trade Commission or the
Department of Justice needs to look at because . . . it’s
something that the marketplace takes care of,
perhaps, very painfully.”).
75
See Oct. 30 Tr. at 149 (Cohen).
76
Nov. 6 Tr. at 172-73 (Farrell).
77
Feb. 26 Tr. at 269-70 (Earp) (stating that collecting
royalties on noninfringing downstream products
raises antitrust and misuse issues); Nov. 6 Tr. at 153
(McGarey) (“[A] patent owner is trying to get, by
contract, what they could not get through their patent
rights, because typically . . . the tool is not going to
show up in the final product. And so, it’s a way for a
97
Other IP Licensing Practices
panelists suggested that the patent misuse
doctrine or antitrust law would not allow
a “licensing company [to demand]
royalties on the sale of a product that is
not covered by [its] patent”
78
or to extend
royalty payments beyond the enforceable
life of the patent on the underlying
research tool.
79
Other panelists disagreed.
From an economics perspective,
“spreading out royalties over a larger
[base] and a lower rate could be better,”
one panelist opined, because that would
suggest the licensee negotiated a lower
rate.
80
From a legal perspective, another
panelist remarked, reach-through
royalties can be a mechanism for
metering, which antitrust law has
generally treated favorably because it
“tends to disseminate technology [often
more broadly] than a single price.”
81
Indeed, in 2002 one federal trial court
found no patent misuse when a reach-
through licensing agreement provided for
royalties based on products not covered
by the patent and allowed for the
collection of royalties beyond the term of
the patent, because the agreement was
structured for the convenience of the
parties and was valued based on the
patent’s actual term.
82
V. PERSPECTIVES ON
ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF
LICENSING PRACTICES
Panelists debated several analytical
approaches for evaluating competitive
concerns raised by the licensing practices
discussed in this Chapter, particularly
with respect to non-assertion clauses and
grantbacks. One panelist, for example,
advocated an assessment of likely
competitive effects in both the relevant
product and innovation markets.
83
patent owner to really extend rights that the patent
system has not really given them.”). See generally infra
Chapter 6, Competitive Issues Regarding Practices That
Extend the Market Power Conferred by a Patent Beyond
Its Statutory Term.
78
Feb. 26 Tr. at 270 (Earp) (citing Zenith Radio Corp. v.
Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 135 (1969)
(“[C]onditioning the grant of a patent license upon
payment of royalties on products which do not use
the teaching of the patent does amount to patent
misuse.”)); see also Nov. 6 Tr. at 157 (Fromm)
(advocating for heightened scrutiny of a reach-
through agreement when a patentee receives royalties
on an unpatented item).
79
Nov. 6 Tr. at 163 (Fromm); see also Brulotte v. Thys
Co., 379 U.S. 29, 32 (1964) (“[A] patentee’s use of a
royalty agreement that projects beyond the expiration
date of the patent is unlawful per se.”).
80
Nov. 6 Tr. at 162-63 (Shapiro); cf. Scheiber v. Dolby
Labs., Inc., 293 F.3d 1014, 1017 (7th Cir. 2002) (“The
duration of the patent fixes the limit of the patentee’s
power to extract royalties; it is a detail whether he
extracts them at a higher rate over a shorter period of
time or a lower rate over a longer period of time.”),
cert. denied, 537 U.S. 1109 (2003); see also Richard
Gilbert & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Issues in the Licensing
of Intellectual Property: The Nine No-No’s Meet the
Nineties, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY,
MICROECONOMICS 283, 322 (permitting royalties to be
paid over a longer period can reduce the deadweight
loss from the patent monopoly); infra Chapter 6,
Competitive Issues Regarding Practices That Extend the
Market Power Conferred by a Patent Beyond Its Statutory
Term Part I.
81
Nov. 6 Tr. at 171 (Rule); see also Mueller, 76 WASH.
L. REV. at 62 (“A reach-through license agreement
merely time-shifts the royalty payments to the period
when they are most accurately indicating the research
tool’s true value to the user.”).
82
Bayer AG v. Housey Pharms., Inc., 228 F. Supp. 2d
467, 471-72 (D. Del. 2002). But see Robin C. Feldman,
The Insufficiency of Antitrust Analysis for Patent Misuse,
55 HASTINGS L.J. 399, 448 (2003) (“Patent misuse rules
based on whether the agreement is voluntary fail to
recognize that an agreement may be in the interests of
both parties and yet be adverse to the interests of the
patent system as a whole.”) (footnote omitted).
83
Nov. 6 Tr. at 139 (McFalls) (“[T]he focus . . . has to
return to what’s the actual effect going to be on the
grantor of a non-assert’s incentive to innovate, and
are they an important innovator in the product
market in which that entry could occur, and are you
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION98
Although other participants agreed that
such an analysis would be desirable, they
questioned whether it would always be
practical.
84
Another panelist proposed the
use of a market power screen, asking “do
the firms entering into this agreement
jointly have market power?”
85
Consideration of market structure,
market power, and complementarities
can, according to the panelist, lead to a
correct assessment of parties’ incentives
for efficient rather than anticompetitive
conduct or vice-versa.
86
Panelists suggested that market
power is not always easy to determine,
however.
87
One participant therefore
advocated applying the ancillary
restraints doctrine to assess a potentially
anticompetitive provision as “a heuristic
kind of approach” that “establishes
certain rules that are administrable and
somewhat easy to understand and apply
at the time you’re doing an agreement.”
88
Another panelist found the doctrine to be
unhelpful in some cases, when there are
no restrictions on the use of the
technology, as is the case for a mutual or
one-way non-assertion agreement.
89
Other panelists desired more definite
guidance, such as specific factors to
consider when structuring a licensing
agreement or practices that raise “red
flags” or provide “green lights.”
90
Using
a grantback as an example, one panelist
proposed several shortcuts, inquiring
whether the grantback is “beyond the
duration of the license” or “relating to
products that are only marginally related
to the initial licensed technology” or if it
is exclusive.
91
This panelist conceded,
however, that defining such shortcuts
would be difficult because “at this stage
[we are] still looking for answers.”
92
Another panelist asserted that fixed rules
are not the best answer, pointing to the
abandonment of the “Nine No-Nos” by
the Department of Justice.
93
going to lose product differentiation or value to
consumers at the end of this long road.”).
84
Id. at 140 (Farrell); id. at 141-42 (Rule); id. at 142-43
(Fromm).
85
Id. at 131 (Farrell).
86
Id. at 132 (Farrell).
87
Nov. 6 Tr. at 136 (Fromm) (stating market power is
difficult to measure); see also id. at 134-35 (Ordover)
(focusing on the question of appropriate markets in
which to measure market power).
88
Id. at 141 (Rule).
89
Id. at 138 (McFalls).
90
Id. at 145 (Ordover); see also id. at 143 (Fromm)
(“[I]s the grantback or . . . non-assert provision
significantly more extensive than the forward-going
[license].”); Jeffrey Fromm, Patent Pools and Cross-
Licensing (Apr. 17, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 8-9 (proposing a
rule of presumptive legality for portfolio cross
licenses which could be overcome in certain
circumstances), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020417jefferyfromm.pdf.
91
Nov. 6 Tr. at 145 (Ordover).
92
Id.
93
Id. at 147 (Rule); see also Bruce B. Wilson, Deputy
Assistant Attorney Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Patent
and Know-How License Agreements: Field of Use,
Territorial, Price and Quantity Restrictions, Remarks
Before the Fourth New England Antitrust Conference
(Nov. 6, 1970), reprinted in ANTITRUST PRIMER:
PATENTS, FRANCHISING, TREBLE DAMAGE SUITS 11
(describing the patent licensing practices covered by
the Nine No-Nos); Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr., Deputy
Assistant Attorney Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Current
Antitrust Division Views on Patent Licensing
Practices, Remarks Before the American Bar
Association Antitrust Section (Nov. 5, 1981), reprinted
in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,129 (abandoning
application of the Nine No-Nos).
99
Other IP Licensing Practices
VI. THE AGENCIES’ COMPETITIVE
CONCERNS AND ANALYSES
The Agencies generally agree with
the panelists’ conclusions that fixed
antitrust rules in intellectual property
licensing are often difficult to articulate
94
and are not necessarily desirable.
95
To
evaluate whether a particular restraint is
likely to have anticompetitive effects
pursuant to the rule of reason, the
Agencies ask whether the restraint is
likely to diminish competition in a
properly defined market “among entities
that would have been actual or likely
potential competitors” in the absence of
that restraint.
96
Pursuant to a rule of
reason analysis, the Agencies consider the
anticompetitive concerns and the
efficiencies of the particular
arrangement.
97
In general, the Agencies
expect that non-assertion agreements,
grantbacks, and reach-through licenses
either will not raise any competitive
concerns or that the efficiencies of these
types of agreements will be sufficient to
alleviate competitive concerns. Several
factors will be particularly relevant to the
Agencies’ examination of these licensing
practices, including (1) whether the patent
holder possesses market power in the
relevant market, (2) whether the practice
encourages unlawful coordination among
competitors, (3) whether the practice
inhibits entry of other firms through the
licensing regime’s exclusivity or
exclusion, and (4) whether the practice
reduces the incentive to innovate in the
future.
98
As a threshold matter, the
Agencies do “not presume that a patent,
copyright, or trade secret necessarily
confers market power upon its owner
because intellectual property rights are
not necessarily associated with market
power.
99
A patent, for example,
may create a monopoly—just as an
auto manufacturer may own all of
the auto production facilities—but
property and monopoly usually
differ. That a patent covers an
“entire” idea or product no more
implies monopoly than the fact
that USX Corporation owns the
“entire” South Works in Chicago.
Frequently, indeed almost always,
different patented goods and
processes compete with each other
94
See Nov. 6 Tr. at 145 (Ordover).
95
Id. at 147, 187 (Rule); see also id. at 185 (Shapiro).
96
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.1 & n.14 (“A firm
will be treated as a likely potential competitor if there
is evidence that entry by that firm is reasonably
probable in the absence of the licensing agreement.”);
U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR COLLABORATIONS AMONG
COMPETITORS § 3.1 (2000), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg.
Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,161 (“Under the rule of reason, the
central question is whether the relevant agreement
likely harms competition by increasing the ability or
incentive profitably to raise price above or reduce
output, quality, service, or innovation below what
likely would prevail in the absence of the relevant
agreement.”), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/
2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf.
97
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.4.
98
See id. § 3.2.3 (considering future innovation); id. §
4.1.2 (discussing licensing arrangements involving
exclusivity); id. § 5.5 (considering portfolio cross
licenses and patent-pooling arrangements); id. § 5.6
(discussing grantbacks). See generally id. § 3.1.
99
Id. § 2.2; see also Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc.,
126 S. Ct. 1281, 1293 (2006) (“Congress, the antitrust
enforcement agencies, and most economists have all
reached the same conclusion that a patent does not
necessarily confer market power upon the
patentee.”).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION100
and with unpatented goods and
processes.
100
For this reason, “the antitrust agencies
determine whether a patent owner
possesses market power by applying the
same analysis that they apply to any other
valuable asset, which requires the
consideration of possible substitutes that
might allow consumers to turn to other
suppliers of a similar product or
process.”
101
Consistent with this
approach, in Illinois Tool, the U.S.
Supreme Court recently held that market
power cannot be presumed based on the
existence of a patent.
102
Equally
important is the notion that, “[i]f a patent
or other form of intellectual property
does confer market power, that market
power does not by itself offend the
antitrust laws.”
103
Market power that is
“solely ‘a consequence of . . . superior
product, business acumen, or historic
accident’” does not create competition
concerns.
104
Efficiently exploiting the
market power that might be associated
with an intellectual property right is
likely reasonable conduct under the
Agencies’ framework, provided that
market power is legitimately obtained
and maintained.
105
Although efficient exploitation of
the market power associated with an
intellectual property right is likely
reasonable and procompetitive activity,
the licensing of intellectual property
rights can involve coordination, especially
if a license includes restrictions on the use
of the intellectual property rights.
Coordination between or among
intellectual property holders on one
aspect of competition may provide a
means or opportunity for coordination on
other aspects of competition, such as
downstream price or output.
106
Sometimes competitive concerns arise not
from the underlying arrangement itself,
but rather from attendant restrictions that
may facilitate coordination on price or
other competitive variables.
107
In addition, exclusivity could raise
competitive concerns if, for example,
firms agreed to limit their granting of
non-assertion clauses to each other,
100
Frank H. Easterbrook, Intellectual Property is Still
Property, 13 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POLY 108, 109 (1990).
101
Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae
Supporting Petitioners at 13-14, Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct.
1281 (No. 04-1329), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2005/3mer/1ami
/2004-1329.mer.ami.pdf; ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES §§
2.1, 2.2. The existence of substitute inputs for the
patented input that could be used as a work-around
when producing the final product may also be
relevant to the Agencies’ analysis.
102
Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1293.
103
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.2.
104
Id. (citing United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S.
563, 571 (1966)).
105
See id. §§ 2.2, 3.4.
106
See id. § 5.5 (“Collective price or output restraints
in pooling arrangements, such as the joint marketing
of pooled intellectual property rights with collective
price setting or coordinated output restrictions, may
be deemed unlawful if they do not contribute to an
efficiency-enhancing integration of economic activity
among the participants.”); supra Chapter 3, Antitrust
Analysis of Portfolio Cross-Licensing Agreements and
Patent Pools Part III.D.5.
107
See ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.5; Nov. 6 Tr. at
116-17 (Rule) (“[P]otentially the big issue is—and this
really goes to consumers in many ways—are the
restrictions that come along with the cross- licensing
and the pooling [agreements] . . . . [I]t is something
that . . . lawyers, when they look at these problems,
are particularly concerned about as opposed to the
question of whether to enter into that agreement, per
se.”).
101
Other IP Licensing Practices
precluding other competitors from
receiving such protection from
infringement suits by the parties to the
agreement. An exclusive reach-through
licensing agreement might also raise
competitive concerns if it has a substantial
impact on the ability of other competitors
to innovate.
108
Of course, the Agencies
recognize that exclusivity can have
desirable effects on competition and
innovation, by, for example, encouraging
investment in the research, development,
and marketing of a product created with
the licensed technology.
109
Thus, when
analyzing a particular license requiring
exclusivity, the Agencies weigh such
efficiencies against any anticompetitive
effects.
110
Finally, certain licensing practices
could impede innovation. If a license
includes restrictions on patents that have
yet to be issued or filed, competitive
concerns could arise about the
arrangement’s likely effect on future
innovation. Scholars have expressed
concern about grantbacks that require the
licensee to assign all rights to
improvements to the grantor, thereby
potentially reducing the licensees
incentives to improve the patented
technology.
111
Non-assertion clauses that
are the functional equivalent of broadly
worded grantbacks could raise similar
concerns.
In contrast, the Agencies may find
that a situation such as the “royalty
stacking” generated by multiple reach-
through licensing agreements does not
raise antitrust concerns even when it
might impede innovation. In some cases,
licenses on multiple patents, each
requiring payment of a royalty, are
legitimately required to innovate,
develop, or commercialize a new product.
However, assuming no anticompetitive
conduct and that the patents at issue are
legitimate, the mere fact that the
cumulative cost of the licenses might
impede innovation is not an antitrust
issue. In this context, the antitrust laws
permit a single IP holder with a desirable
intellectual property asset to extract as
much return as the market will bear for
the use of that property.
112
Moreover, according to panelists,
it is often not clear that the cost of
royalties arising from reach-through
licensing agreements will be excessive,
such that it impedes innovation or
otherwise causes competitive harm. The
royalty that an upstream firm may charge
for use of a patented research tool will be
108
Sections 4.1.2 and 5.4 of the ANTITRUST-IP
GUIDELINES outline the analysis relevant to both
exclusivity and exclusion in the context of the types of
arrangements discussed in this Chapter.
109
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.3.
110
Id. §§ 3.4, 4.1.2.
111
See supra notes 50-53 and accompanying text.
112
See, e.g., R. Hewitt Pate, Assistant Attorney Gen.,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Competition and Intellectual
Property in the U.S.: Licensing Freedom and the
Limits of Antitrust, Address Before the 2005 EU
Competition Workshop 8-9 (June 3, 2005), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/209359
.pdf; Gerald F. Masoudi, Deputy Assistant Attorney
Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Intellectual Property and
Competition: Four Principles for Encouraging
Innovation, Address Before the Digital Americas 2006
Meeting 7-8 (April 11, 2006), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/215645
.pdf; Schor v. Abbott Labs., 457 F.3d 608, 610 (7th Cir.
2006) (Easterbrook, J.) (“[Absent some exclusionary
practice,] [t]he price of [a patented product] cannot
violate the Sherman Act: a patent holder is entitled to
charge whatever the traffic will bear.”); see also
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.2.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION102
limited by the downstream firm’s
willingness to pay. That willingness will
reflect the value of the patent to the
downstream firm, and includes
considerations such as the probability that
the patent would be found invalid or
unenforceable, as well as the difficulty of
detecting infringement. The Agencies’
rule of reason analysis, applied to
particular facts, may well indicate that
anticompetitive harm would not arise
from a reach-through licensing
agreement,
113
in which case the Agencies
would not challenge the agreement.
114
VII. CONCLUSION
Panelists generally agreed that the
various licensing practices discussed in
this Chapter can provide great efficiencies
to the contracting parties that would
ultimately benefit consumers, but also
that each licensing practice has the
potential to stymie innovation and
weaken competition among firms. These
countervailing effects complicate an
antitrust analysis, especially because
procompetitive benefits and
anticompetitive effects can be difficult to
unravel, and may or may not be present
in any individual case. Indeed, the
competitive effects of certain licensing
practices are not obvious—an example is
the reach-through license, where the
harm may not be apparent simply by
examining the four corners of the
agreement. Most panelists recognized
that the Agencies are not in a position
immediately to decipher possible
procompetitive benefits and
anticompetitive effects or to provide fixed
rules that work efficiently in every case.
Although “red flags” and “green lights”
may be easy to apply, many panelists
found them considerably less desirable
than the Agencies’ current approach
based on principled economics.
115
The Agencies will continue to
apply the flexible framework set forth in
the Antitrust-IP Guidelines and to
evaluate each licensing practice
individually with particular focus on
whether it “harms competition among
entities that would have been actual or
likely potential competitors in a relevant
market in the absence of the license.”
116
The Agencies will analyze the agreements
discussed in this Chapter pursuant to the
rule of reason.
117
113
See supra Part IV.
114
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 4.2.
115
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 147, 187 (Rule); id. at 185
(Shapiro).
116
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.1; see also id. §§ 3.3,
3.4.
117
Id. § 3.4. However, the Agencies may challenge a
license restraint under the per se rule if “there is no
efficiency-enhancing integration of economic activity
and if the type of restraint is one that has been
accorded per se treatment . . . .” Id.; see also id. § 3.4
ex.7 (explaining that the Agencies may challenge a
licensing agreement under the per se rule when it is “a
sham intended to cloak [the] true nature” of the
arrangement).
103
CHAPTER 5
ANTITRUST ISSUES IN THE TYING AND BUNDLING
OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS
I. INTRODUCTION
“Tying and bundling [are] so
ubiquitous that we forget they are there
. . . . Tying and bundling [are], roughly
speaking, what the modern firm does. It’s
the rationale. It puts things together and
offers them in packages to consumers.
1
A tying arrangement occurs when,
through a contractual or technological
requirement, a seller conditions the sale
or lease of one product or service on the
customer’s agreement to take a second
product or service.
2
The term “tying” is
most often used by economists when the
proportion in which the customer
purchases the two products is not fixed or
specified at the time of purchase, as in a
requirements tie-in” sale.
3
A bundled
sale typically refers to a sale in which the
products are sold only in fixed
proportions (e.g., one pair of shoes and
one pair of shoe laces or a newspaper,
which can be viewed as a bundle of
sections, some of which may not be read
at all by the customers). Bundling may
also be referred to as a “package tie-in.”
4
Case law in the United States sometimes
uses the terms “tying” and “bundling”
interchangeably.
5
In view of their potential
efficiencies, many economists believe that,
in general, tying and bundling are more
likely to be procompetitive than
anticompetitive.
6
Analysis of the
1
Center for the New Europe, Edited Transcript of a
CNE Market Insights Event: Tying and Bundling:
From Economics to Competition Policy (Sept. 19,
2002) (Prof. Paul Seabright discussing tying and
bundling), http://www.cne.org/pub_pdf/
2002_09_19_tying_bundling.htm.
2
DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN
INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 319 (4th ed. 2005).
3
A “requirements tie-in” sale occurs when a seller
requires customers who purchase one product from
the seller (e.g., a printer) also to make all their
purchases of another product from the seller (e.g., ink
cartridges). Such tying allows the seller to charge
customers different amounts depending on their
product usage. Id. at 321-22.
4
Id. “Pure bundling” occurs when consumers can
purchase only the entire bundle (e.g., when
customers are allowed to purchase only a fixed price
meal that includes all courses). “Mixed bundling”
occurs if the components also are sold separately,
with a discount for purchasing the bundle (e.g.,
restaurant menus that include both à la carte items
and complete meals). See id. at 324.
5
See, e.g., United States v. Loew’s, Inc., 371 U.S. 38
(1962) (analyzing the licensing of feature films only in
blocks (or bundles) as tying).
6
See, e.g., David Evans & Michael Salinger, Why Do
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION104
anticompetitive effects of tying and
bundling by U.S. courts, by contrast, has
evolved over time. Although courts long
have expressed concern that tying or
bundling might enable firms to use
monopoly power in one market as
leverage to curb competition, and thereby
acquire monopoly power, in a second
market,
7
judicial concern has eased as
tying and bundling have become better
understood. Once thought to be worthy
of per se condemnation
8
without
examination of any actual competitive
effects, tying currently is deemed per se
illegal under U.S. Supreme Court rulings
only if specific conditions are met,
including proof that the defendant has
market power over the tying product.
9
Further, the Supreme Court has recently
recognized that competitive markets and
tying arrangements are not
incompatible.
10
Indeed, some lower
courts have required proof of likely or
actual anticompetitive effects and
efficiencies in tying cases.
11
At the Hearings, one panel
discussed how the Agencies and the
courts could best analyze tying and
bundling when two or more products are
tied or bundled together and at least one
of the products is protected by intellectual
property rights. Panelists discussed how
to reach the right answers in particular
cases and how to give private parties a
reasonable ability to predict how their
intellectual property licensing practices
will be treated under the antitrust laws.
12
As discussed below, panelists generally
doubted that tying and bundling
involving intellectual property are likely
enough to harm consumer welfare to
justify per se treatment, and therefore
advocated a rule of reason approach that
would require proof of likely or actual
Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive
Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 YALE J. ON
REG. 37 (2005).
7
See, e.g., N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5-
6 (1958); Int’l Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392, 396
(1947).
8
Business practices merit treatment as per se illegal if
“their pernicious effect on competition and lack of
any redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to
be unreasonable.” N. Pac. Ry., 356 U.S. at 5.
9
Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2,
9, 16-18 (1984) (retaining per se treatment for “certain
tying arrangements” but requiring consideration of
market power); Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc.,
126 S. Ct. 1281, 1292 (2006); id. at 1291 (stating that an
allegation of illegal tying must be supported by proof
of market power, rather than a presumption of
market power based on a patent).
10
Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1292; see also infra note 21 and
accompanying text.
11
See infra notes 40-43 and accompanying text
(discussing United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34
(D.C. Cir. 2001) (applying the rule of reason to the
bundling of operating systems and applications
software)).
12
Panelists addressing this topic at the May 14, 2002
Hearing were: Joseph Farrell, Professor of Economics
and Chair of the Competition Policy Center,
University of California, Berkeley; Jonathan M.
Jacobson, Partner, Akin, Gump, Strauss, Hauer &
Feld, LLP; Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr., Partner, Latham &
Watkins; David S. Sibley, John Michael Stuart
Professor of Economics, University of Texas at
Austin; J. Gregory Sidak, F. K. Weyerhaeuser Fellow
in Law and Economics Emeritus, American
Enterprise Institute; and Gregory Vistnes, Vice
President, Charles River Associates. The session was
moderated by Michael Katz, then-Deputy Assistant
Attorney General, and David L. Scheffman, then-
Director, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade
Commission. They were joined by C. Edward Polk,
Jr., then-Associate Solicitor, U.S. Patent and
Trademark Office. May 14, 2002 Hr’g Tr., Antitrust
Analysis of Specific Intellectual Property Licensing
Practices: Bundling, Grantbacks and Temporal
Extensions (Morning Session), http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020514trans.pdf [hereinafter May 14
Tr.].
105
Tying and Bundling of IP Rights
anticompetitive effects and allow
consideration of the efficiencies that such
arrangements may generate.
13
II. LEGAL ANALYSES OF TYING
AND BUNDLING
14
Ever since the late 1940s, when the
Supreme Court stated in International Salt
Co. v. United States that “it is
unreasonable, per se, to foreclose
competitors from any substantial
market,”
15
and in Standard Oil Co. v.
United States that “[t]ying agreements
serve hardly any purpose beyond the
suppression of competition,”
16
U.S. courts
have found tying to be per se unlawful.
17
Although the Court’s 1984 Jefferson Parish
opinion confirmed the continued role of a
per se analysis,
18
it emphasized that
market power in the tying product was a
requirement for per se illegality.
19
Later
that same year, the Court explained that
the application of the per se rule to tying
had evolved to incorporate a market
analysis:
[T]here is often no bright line
separating per se from Rule of
Reason analysis. Per se rules may
require considerable inquiry into
market conditions before the
evidence justifies a presumption of
anticompetitive conduct. For
example, while the Court has
spoken of a “per se” rule against
tying arrangements, it has also
recognized that tying may have
procompetitive justifications that
make it inappropriate to condemn
without considerable market
analysis.
20
Consistent with this approach, the
Supreme Court recently acknowledged
that “[m]any tying arrangements . . . are
fully consistent with a free, competitive
market.”
21
Indeed, leading treatises have
commented that the test lower courts use
to determine whether to apply the per se
rule to a particular alleged tie
“increasingly resembles a rule of reason
inquiry.”
22
Although the elements of a per
se tying violation have been articulated
differently, courts generally require that:
(1) two separate products or
services are involved, (2) the sale
13
Panelists stated that such tying and bundling do
not meet the standard for per se analysis of always or
almost always being harmful to competition. Id. at
35-44 (Jacobson, Farrell, Sidak, Sibley, and Lipsky).
14
More complete summaries of basic tying law are
found in ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST
LAW DEVELOPMEN TS 175-214 (5th ed. 2002)
[hereinafter ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS] and 1
HERBERT HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS & MARK A.
LEMLEY, IP AND ANTITRUST: AN ANALYSIS OF
ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY LAW §§ 21.1, at 21-3 to -8, 21.5(d), at 21-113
to -16 (2002) [hereinafter 1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND
ANTITRUST].
15
332 U.S. at 396.
16
337 U.S. 293, 305-06 (1949).
17
ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS at 177-79.
18
“It is far too late in the history of our antitrust
jurisprudence to question the proposition that certain
tying arrangements pose an unacceptable risk of
stifling competition and therefore are unreasonable
per se.’” 466 U.S. at 9.
19
Id. at 9-18.
20
Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of the
Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 104 n.26 (1984) (citation
omitted).
21
Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1292.
22
ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS at 178; 1
HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 21.5, at 21-
113 to -15.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION106
or agreement to sell one is
conditioned on the purchase of the
other, (3) the seller has sufficient
economic power in the market for
the tying product to enable it to
restrain trade in the market for the
tied product, and (4) a not
insubstantial amount of interstate
commerce in the tied product is
affected.
23
For other per se violations, such as naked
agreements to fix price, plaintiffs are not
required to define the relevant product
markets or show that the defendant has
market power in a relevant market. In
addition, some courts have shown a
willingness to consider business
justifications for the alleged tie,
24
and
some courts have required proof that the
tie has anticompetitive effects.
25
Courts have sometimes analyzed
bundling under the rubric of tying. In
United States v. Loew’s, Inc.,
26
for example,
the Supreme Court found that the
practice of licensing feature films to
television stations only in blocks (or
“bundles”) containing films the stations
did not want to license constituted
unlawful tying in violation of section 1 of
the Sherman Act.
27
Nonetheless, in
explaining its tying analysis in Jefferson
Parish, the Supreme Court noted the fact
that “a purchaser is ‘forced’ to buy a
product he would not have otherwise
bought even from another seller” does
not imply an “adverse impact on
competition.”
28
Thus, to prevail on an
unlawful tying claim, a plaintiff would
have to show an exclusionary effect on
other sellers as a result of plaintiff’s
thwarted desire to purchase substitutes
for one or more items in the bundle from
other sources that harms competition.
III. TYING AND BUNDLING
INVOLVING INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY
Linking intellectual property with
products or other intellectual property
can take many forms, such as offering
licenses that cover multiple patents or
copyrighted materials or tying the sale of
two patented goods or one unpatented
and one patented good. Such linkages
carry various labels, depending on
whether the linked product embodies
intellectual property, whether one price
23
ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS at 179 & n.998
(citing cases).
24
United States v. Jerrold Elecs. Corp., 187 F. Supp. 545,
557-58 (E.D. Pa. 1960), aff’d per curiam, 365 U.S. 567
(1961) (concluding that a tie was justified for a limited
time in a new industry to assure effective functioning
of complex equipment); Mozart Co. v. Mercedes-Benz of
N. Am., Inc., 833 F.2d 1342, 1348-51 (9th Cir. 1987)
(upholding verdict for defendant because the tie may
have been found to be the least expensive and most
effective means of policing quality); Dehydrating
Process Co. v. A. O. Smith Corp., 292 F.2d 653, 655-57
(1st Cir. 1961) (affirming a judgment of a district court
that directed a verdict in favor of the defendant
because a tie was necessary to assure utility of two
products when separate sales led to malfunctions and
widespread customer dissatisfaction).
25
Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd. of Realtors,
850 F.2d 803, 815 (1st Cir. 1988) (“The tying claim
must fail absent any proof of anti-competitive effects
in the market for the tied product.”); Fox Motors, Inc.
v. Mazda Distribs. (Gulf), Inc., 806 F.2d 953, 958 (10th
Cir. 1986) (declining to apply the per se rule to a tie
that “simply does not imply a sufficiently great
likelihood of anticompetitive effect”).
26
371 U.S. 38 (1962).
27
Id. at 41-43 (noting the blocks contained as many as
754 separate titles); id. at 44, 49-50 (treating block
booking as tying).
28
Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 16.
107
Tying and Bundling of IP Rights
or separate prices are charged, and
whether the linkage is accomplished
contractually or technologically. Classic
“contractual” patent tying occurs when
the tying product (such as a mimeograph
machine) is patented, the tied product is
an unpatented commodity used as an
input for the tying product (such as ink or
paper), and the sale of the patented
product is conditioned on the purchase of
the unpatented product. A “technological
tie” may be defined as one in which “the
tying and tied products are bundled
together physically or produced in such a
way that they are compatible only with
each other.”
29
The government’s tying
claim against Microsoft involved both the
contractual and technological bundling of
the Internet Explorer web browser (the
tied product) with its Windows operating
system (the tying product).
30
Multiple intellectual property
rights may themselves be combined into
bundles or packages. Mandatory package
licensing occurs when a patent owner
refuses to license a particular patent
unless a licensee accepts an entire
package (or where the patent owner’s
royalty scale has this effect).
31
It also
includes “block booking” of motion
pictures or television shows. Panelists
explored the economic, legal, and
practical issues raised by these various
practices, all of which involve intellectual
property tying or bundling.
A. The Economics of Bundling
Involving Intellectual Property
Economists on the panel discussed
features that may distinguish intellectual
property from tangible property. One
such feature is that the development and
exploitation of intellectual property
typically involves high fixed costs but low
marginal costs, but the panel discussion
did not make the relevance of this
distinction to the analysis of bundling
clear. One panelist suggested that
predicting anticompetitive effects may be
more difficult in cases involving
intellectual property bundling than in
cases involving the bundling of tangible
property.
32
Another panelist stated that it
is difficult to determine whether
intellectual property bundling in a
particular case is driven by efficiencies
and, as a result, the analysis is ultimately
fact-intensive.
33
Two economists have considered
the bundling of so-called information
goods, such as copyrighted music,
programming, and other online content
on the Internet.
34
They observe that the
29
1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 21.5b2, at
21-104 to -05. An example would be a razor and
razor blade cartridge.
30
Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 45; see also Complaint paras.
18, 20, 103-23, Microsoft, 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C.
2000) (No. 98-1232), aff’d in part, rev’d in part, 253 F.3d
34, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/
f1700/1763.pdf.
31
Richard Gilbert & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Issues in
the Licensing of Intellectual Property: The Nine No-No’s
Meet the Nineties, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON.
ACTIVITY, MICROECONOMICS 283, 317.
32
May 14 Tr. at 41-42 (Sidak). This panelist also cited
Microsoft’s bundling of a browser with its operating
system and suggested that the mechanism through
which viable and independently-owned
complementary products may facilitate competitive
entry into each other’s markets is imperfectly
understood and deserving of more careful economic
analysis. Id. at 45-47.
33
Id. at 24-25 (Vistnes).
34
See Yannis Bakos & Eric Brynjolfsson, Bundling and
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION108
marginal cost of adding additional units
of an information good to a bundle of
other information goods typically is very
low. They also observe that demand for
bundles of goods across customers can be
more homogeneous than the demand for
the individual components. In such
circumstances, it can be more profitable to
offer such goods only in a bundle. In
their analysis, competition between two
firms that each offer sufficiently large
bundles can make consumers better off,
35
and bundling by a firm facing no
competition can increase total welfare but
increase or decrease consumer welfare.
36
Another distinction between
intellectual and tangible property is that
the validity of patents can be challenged.
It is widely believed that intellectual
property bundling “is apt to affect private
incentives to challenge the IP”
37
—most
likely decreasing incentives to challenge
it. Some find it difficult to assess the
likely welfare effects of this decrease,
however, because the optimal level of
incentive to challenge intellectual
property rights is not clearly known.
38
B. Legal Issues Relevant to
Intellectual Property Bundling
Courts have not taken a consistent
analytical approach to tying and bundling
cases involving intellectual property. In
1999, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the
Eleventh Circuit applied the per se rule to
a package license for television
programming because the package at
issue could not be distinguished from the
block booking that the Supreme Court
declared to be illegal per se in Loew’s.
39
By contrast, the U.S. Court of
Appeals for the D.C. Circuit’s 2001
decision in United States v. Microsoft
rejected application of the per se rule to
“platform software,”
40
thereby “carving
Competition on the Internet, 19 MARKETING SCI. 63
(2000); Yannis Bakos & Eric Brynjolfsson, Bundling
Information Goods: Prices, Profits, and Efficiency, 45
MGMT. SCI. 1613 (1999).
35
Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 19 MARKETING SCI. at 71-74
(showing that customers are able to purchase goods
from competing firms selling large enough bundles at
a lower effective per unit price than the price they
would pay for each good if all goods are sold
separately).
36
Id. at 72. The intuition behind this result is that
bundling allows the monopolist to sell more units to
customers which increases total welfare, but also
allows the monopolist to charge higher average prices
which extracts surplus from customers. Depending
on the parameters of the model, the latter effect could
be either greater or less than the former effect.
37
May 14 Tr. at 89-90 (Farrell).
38
Id. at 90, 220-27 (Farrell) (describing the complexity
of determining the efficient incentives to challenge
intellectual property, but expressing his belief that
“private incentives to challenge intellectual property
may be badly inadequate”); id. at 295-300 (Miller)
(discussing ideas for increasing incentives assuming
they are too low); see also id. at 158 (Katz) (“[E]ven in
the case where it’s said that by having the package
it’s either diminishing the incentives to invent around
or diminishing the incentives to challenge validity or
enforceability . . . , work I’ve done and others have
done suggests [that assessment] actually is very
delicate.”). For example, one panelist argued that a
successful challenge both eliminates the mark-up
attributable to intellectual property and also reduces
potential innovators’ expectations of how much they
might earn on the basis of intellectual property in the
future. Id. at 91 (Farrell).
39
MCA Television Ltd. v. Pub. Interest Corp., 171 F.3d
1265, 1277-78 (11th Cir. 1999) (citing Loew’s, 371 U.S.
at 50).
40
253 F.3d at 95. In deciding a tying patent misuse
claim, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal
Circuit recently rejected a per se approach and applied
tying case law to find that a package license
combining alleged “essential” with “nonessential”
patents did not constitute patent misuse because there
109
Tying and Bundling of IP Rights
out what might be called a ‘technology
exception to that rule,
41
as one
submission suggested. The court
reasoned that application of traditional
per se analysis in the “pervasively
innovative platform software industry
risks condemning ties that may be
welfare-enhancing and procompetitive.
42
According to one panelist, however, “the
rationale [that the court] articulated for
abandoning per se condemnation applies
well beyond just the software industry,”
notwithstanding “the court’s
protestations to the contrary.”
43
Although
in Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent
Ink, Inc. the Supreme Court recognized
that many tying arrangements, “even
those involving patents and requirements
ties,” can be procompetitive,
44
that case
did not present a vehicle for the Court to
revisit its conclusion that some tying
arrangements constitute per se
violations.
45
The Agencies’ rule of reason
approach to intellectual property
bundling is reflected in the Antitrust
Guidelines for the Licensing of
Intellectual Property (“Antitrust-IP
Guidelines”). The Antitrust-IP Guidelines
recognize that “[c]onditioning the ability
of a licensee to license one or more items
of intellectual property on the licensee’s
purchase of another item of intellectual
property or a good or a service has been
held in some cases to constitute illegal
tying,”
46
but also state that “[a]lthough
tying arrangements may result in
a nticompetitive effects, such
was no separate demand for the “nonessential”
patents, and, thus, no separate product market in
which competition could have been foreclosed. U.S.
Philips Corp. v. Int’l Trade Comm’n, 424 F.3d 1179,
1193-97 (Fed. Cir. 2005). The court rejected a per se
approach “[i]n light of the efficiencies of package
patent licensing and the important differences
between product-to-patent tying arrangements and
arrangements involving group licensing of
patents . . . .” Id. at 1193.
41
Jonathan M. Jacobson & Abid Qureshi, Did the Per
Se Rule on Tying Survive ‘Microsoft’? (May 14, 2002
Hr’g R.) at 1, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020514jacobson2.pdf [hereinafter Jacobson
Submission]; cf. Warren S. Grimes, The Antitrust Tying
Law Schism: A Critique of Microsoft III and a Response
to Hylton and Salinger, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 199, 202
(2002) (“[C]iting the novelty of the issues and the
possibility of procompetitive effects, [the D.C. Circuit]
imposed a rule of reason to measure Microsoft’s
software bundling practices.”); William J. Kolasky,
GE/Honeywell: Continuing the Transatlantic Dialogue,
23 U. PA. J. INTL ECON. L. 513, 532 & n.66 (2002)
(citing Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 84-97, to support a
statement that technological ties “are generally
evaluated under the rule of reason”); Edward G.
Biester III, An Overview of the IP-Antitrust Intersection:
Reevaluating the 1995 Antitrust Guidelines for the
Licensing of Intellectual Property, ANTITRUST, Summer
2002, at 8, 10 [hereinafter Biester, An Overview of the
IP-Antitrust Intersection].
42
253 F.3d at 93.
43
Jacobson Submission at 1; Herbert Hovenkamp, IP
Ties and Microsoft’s Rule of Reason, 47 ANTITRUST
BULL. 369, 413 (2002) (“[W]hile developing a rule of
reason for OS/application is laudable, the court’s
rationale for distinguishing such ties from the general
run of tying arrangements cannot be supported.”); see
also Biester, An Overview of the IP-Antitrust Intersection
at 10 (“Basic antitrust principles like the traditional
per se rule against tying where there is market power
in the tying product become complicated in markets
that are difficult to define because of the moving
target of constantly developing technology.”).
44
Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1292 (recognizing that price
discrimination occurs in fully competitive markets);
see also supra note 21 and accompanying text.
45
See Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 9 (acknowledging
that certain tying arrangements are per se illegal).
46
U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN,
ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY § 5.3 & n.34 (1995), available
at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/
0558.pdf [hereinafter ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES]
(citing United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334
U.S. 131, 156-58 (1948) (copyrights); Int’l Salt, 332 U.S.
392 (patent and related product)).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION110
arrangements can . . . result in significant
efficiencies and procompetitive
benefits.”
47
Pursuant to the Antitrust-IP
Guidelines, the Agencies, as a matter of
prosecutorial discretion, consider both the
anticompetitive effects and the efficiencies
attributable to a tie. The Agencies would
be likely to challenge a tying arrangement
if: “(1) the seller has market power in the
tying product, [which the Agencies will
not presume necessarily to be conferred
by a patent, copyright, or trade secret]; (2)
the arrangement has an adverse effect on
competition in the relevant market for the
tied product; and (3) efficiency
justifications for the arrangement do not
outweigh the anticompetitive effects.”
48
If
a package license constitutes tying,
49
the
Agencies will evaluate it pursuant to the
same rule of reason principles they use to
analyze other tying arrangements.
Whether the legal analysis applied
to intellectual property bundling is some
form of the per se rule or the more
searching rule of reason, a plaintiff will
have to establish that a defendant has
market power in the tying product.
Recognizing that “Congress, the antitrust
enforcement agencies, and most
economists have all reached the
conclusion that a patent does not
necessarily confer market power upon the
patentee,” the Supreme Court has held
that in all cases involving a tying
arrangement, the plaintiff must prove that
the defendant has market power in the
tying product.
50
Thus, market power
should not be presumed merely from the
existence of a patent.
51
As the Court
explained:
[W]e conclude that tying
arrangements involving patented
products should be evaluated
under the standards applied in
cases like Fortner II and Jefferson
Parish rather than under the per se
rule applied in Morton Salt and
Loew’s. While some such
arrangements are still unlawful,
such as those that are the product
of a true monopoly or a market
wide conspiracy, that conclusion
must be supported by proof of
power in the relevant market
rather than by a mere presumption
thereof.
52
The Agencies, as a matter of sound
economics, had chosen not to rely on such
a presumption prior to Illinois Tool.
53
As
47
Id. § 5.3.
48
Id. (footnotes omitted); see also id. § 2.2 (“[The]
Agencies will not presume that a patent, copyright, or
trade secret necessarily confers market power upon
its owner.”).
49
The Antitrust-IP Guidelines describe package
licensing as “the licensing of multiple items of
intellectual property in a single license or in a group
of related licenses,” which “may be a form of tying . .
. if the licensing of one product is conditioned upon
the acceptance of a license for another, separate
product.Id. § 5.3.
50
Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. at 1293.
51
Id.
52
Id. at 1291 (citations omitted).
53
The Solicitor General filed an amicus brief in
Illinois Tool asserting that the market power
presumption was contrary to modern tying
jurisprudence and sound economics. Brief for the
United States as Amicus Curiae Supporting
Petitioners, Ill. Tool, 126 S. Ct. 1281 (No. 04-1329),
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/
2005/3mer/1ami/2004-1329.mer.ami.pdf. The
Solicitor General noted that “[a]s a matter of
longstanding antitrust policy, both the Department of
Justice and the Federal Trade Commission have
rejected the presumption that patents confer market
111
Tying and Bundling of IP Rights
the Antitrust-IP Guidelines explain, the
Agencies “will not presume that a patent,
copyright, or trade secret necessarily
confers market power upon its owner.
Although the intellectual property right
confers the power to exclude with respect
to the specific product, process, or work in
question, there will often be sufficient
actual or potential close substitutes . . . to
prevent the exercise of market power.”
54
The Agencies therefore investigate the
relevant market to determine whether the
intellectual property at issue grants any
market power in the economic sense. If
such market power is found, the Agencies
further investigate whether the business
practice under scrutiny is likely to be
anticompetitive on balance.
C. Practical Issues Regarding
Intellectual Property Bundling
Panelists addressed several issues
that attorneys confront when counseling
clients with regard to intellectual
property bundling. One panelist noted
that, in addition to the courtsinconsistent
treatment of cases involving intellectual
property bundling, courts have also
differed in ordinary tying cases as to
whether: (1) a plaintiff must show harm
to competition in the tied product market;
and (2) a defendant’s evidence of business
justification is admissible.
55
“The result of
this is when the client asks you about
what the rules are governing bundling of
intellectual property . . . you cannot give
a clear answer. [Lawyers have to give]
the cautious advice . . . please, don’t do it;
the risk [of litigation] is too great.”
56
The panel also discussed the extent
to which attorneys counseling their clients
will consider the likelihood that an
enforcement agency or private party will
challenge intellectual property bundling.
57
Due in part to the rules on antitrust injury
and standing, the probability of being
sued may be small, but one panelist
expressed the view that, “given the state
of the law today you just can’t advise a
client that has an intellectual property
right that it’s okay to tie . . . . It’s just too
dangerous.”
58
Counseling about potential
antitrust liability also occurs when a client
is about to bring an infringement suit,
because such a suit may trigger an
antitrust counterclaim even when an
antitrust suit would otherwise be
unlikely. One panelist expressed the
view that “it’s per se malpractice to fail to
advise a client who is considering an
intellectual property infringement suit
that he must be prepared to litigate any
manner of crazy antitrust or misuse
power for the simple reason that the presumption is
so demonstrably unsound.” Id. at 13. The Solicitor
General observed that “the Patent and Trademark
Office has issued scores of patents for such items as
bottle openers, toothbrushes, and paper clips . . . [but]
[i]t would be implausible to presume that the owner
of such a patent possesses market power merely by
virtue of the patent.” Id. at 12.
54
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.2.
55
May 14 Tr. at 29-30 (Jacobson); see also supra notes
22-25, 50-52 and accompanying text (discussing types
of proof required by some courts in tying cases
including market definition, business justifications,
and anticompetitive effects).
56
May 14 Tr. at 30-31 (Jacobson). Such results can
harm consumers. Cf. Hovenkamp, 47 ANTITRUST
BULL. at 382 ([Socially costly rules include] “the
enormous compliance costs of those who are denied a
more efficient method of doing business for fear of
breaching a senseless antitrust rule.”).
57
May 14 Tr. at 107-13 (Jacobson, Lipsky).
58
Id. at 108 (Jacobson).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION112
counterclaim – or misuse defense.”
59
Another panelist observed that
firms that have been advised by counsel
will often offer alternatives to a package
license. He suggested that “one way to
[offer] package licenses and not get
immediately hauled into [f]ederal
[d]istrict [c]ourt is to make sure there’s an
alternative available.”
60
When another
panelist questioned the wisdom of
advising clients “that they are essentially
home free on bundling pricing where
intellectual property is involved,”
61
the
other replied that, although this practice
does not provide a complete safety zone,
“the difficulty of proving that the pricing
bundle is sufficiently coercive . . . given
the expense of bringing an antitrust case
. . . gives you a measure of comfort . . . .”
62
Finally, one panelist argued that,
although defendants in many cases could
“devise ways of achieving the same
efficiencies without tying,”
63
the per se
rule creates “enormous cost in terms of
firms without market power and with
intellectual property rights trying to
figure out the best way to exploit those
rights,” such as small firms trying to enter
a market in which metering through tying
may work best.
64
Another panelist
suggested that “product combination
decisions[,] like things that can be
characterized as ties[,] ought to be
presumptively lawful” and that the real
problem with the per se rule against tying
is that it is “potentially applicable to an
enormous range of harmless commercial
decisions which nevertheless tend to
attract involvement with law enforcement
and the civil justice system.”
65
D. Suggested Approaches to
Improving the Law on
Intellectual Property Bundling
The panel explored ways to
improve the law on tying in general and
with regard to intellectual property
bundling in particular. One panelist
highlighted three approaches.
66
First, he
suggested that the courts, instead of
carving out exceptions to the per se rule
against tying (as the D.C. Circuit did for
“platform software” products in
Microsoft
67
), should follow the approach
taken by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the
Seventh Circuit in Khan v. State Oil Co.,
68
59
Id. at 109 (Lipsky).
60
Id. at 110-11 (Jacobson); cf. Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S.
at 12 n.17 (quoting N. Pac. Ry. Co., 356 U.S. at 6 n.4
(“Of course where the buyer is free to take either
product by itself there is no tying problem even
though the seller may also offer the two items as a
unit at a single price.”)). Where, however, a firm
offers products A (the tying product) and B at a
bundled price but also offers product A separately, a
court may determine whether an unbundled price for
product A may be so high as to demonstrate that no
real alternative to the bundle of products A and B is
being offered. May 14 Tr. at 46-52 (Sidak) (noting
that courts may face such questions in fashioning
relief in instances in which liability for tying has been
found).
61
May 14 Tr. at 112 (Lipsky).
62
Id. at 113 (Jacobson).
63
Id. at 36 (Jacobson).
64
Id. at 40-41 (Jacobson); cf. Hovenkamp, 47
ANTITRUST BULL. at 382.
65
May 14 Tr. at 42-44 (Lipsky).
66
See Jonathan M. Jacobson, Counseling in
Uncertainty: The Law of Tying & Intellectual Property
(May 14, 2002 Hr’g R.) (slides), http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020514jacobson.pdf [hereinafter
Jacobson Presentation].
67
253 F.3d at 95-96.
68
93 F.3d 1358, 1362-64 (7th Cir. 1996).
113
Tying and Bundling of IP Rights
which applied the per se rule against
vertical maximum price-fixing while
carefully explaining the shortcomings of
the approach and inviting the Supreme
Court to overturn it, as the Court
ultimately did.
69
Second, testifying prior
to Illinois Tool, he suggested that Congress
should consider legislation mandating
that there shall be no presumption of
market power from the mere possession
of a patent or copyright in antitrust
cases.
70
Third, he suggested that the
Agencies should advocate improvements
in the law through amicus participation in
cases involving intellectual property
bundling, both in the district courts and
courts of appeals, with the hope that the
decisions of these courts may eventually
be reviewed by the Supreme Court.
71
Panelists acknowledged that
conducting a rule of reason analysis of
intellectual property bundling or other
practices results in a very fact-intensive
inquiry, the outcome of which will likely
be difficult to predict.
72
An economist on
69
State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 7 (1997); see also
Hovenkamp, 47 ANTITRUST BULL. at 383 n.33 (noting
with approval Judge Posner’s invitation for reversal).
Such invitations, however, are not always accepted.
After this Hearing took place, Judge Posner took a
similar approach in applying the per se rule against
post-expiration royalties, based on Brulotte v. Thys
Co., 379 U.S. 29, 32 (1964), while inviting the Supreme
Court to reconsider the rule. Scheiber v. Dolby Labs.,
Inc., 293 F.3d 1014, 1018-19 (7th Cir. 2002). The Court,
however, denied certiorari. 537 U.S. 1109 (2003). By
contrast, believing the court bound by Supreme Court
precedent, Judge Dyk made a similar invitation in
Illinois Tool which the Court accepted. Indep. Ink, Inc.
v. Ill. Tool Works, Inc., 396 F.3d 1342, 1351 (Fed. Cir.
2005), rev’d, 126 S. Ct. 1281 (2006).
70
May 14 Tr. at 32-34 (Jacobson). Such legislation is
now unnecessary in light of the Supreme Court’s
decision in Illinois Tool rejecting such a presumption.
126 S. Ct. 1281. Cf. Hovenkamp, 47 ANTITRUST BULL.
at 373 (“We might be better off if Congress legislated
prescriptions about the domain of intellectual
property rights directly into the federal intellectual
property statutes themselves and occasionally it has
done so.”).
71
May 14 Tr. at 34-35 (Jacobson); Jacobson
Presentation at 14. The Agencies have a long history
of advising the courts on intellectual property issues
relevant to competitive concerns. See, e.g., Brief for
the United States as Amicus Curiae Supporting
Respondent, eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S.
Ct. 1837 (2006) (No. 05-130), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2005/3mer/1ami
/2005-0130.mer.ami.pdf; Brief for the United States as
Amicus Curiae Supporting Petitioners, Ill. Tool, 126 S.
Ct. 1281 (No. 04-1329); Brief for the United States as
Amicus Curiae Supporting Respondent, Pfaff v. Wells
Elecs., Inc., 525 U.S. 55 (1998) (No. 97-1130), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/ cases/f1800/1836.pdf;
Brief Amicus Curiae of the United States of America
Urging Reversal in Support of Appellant Kanebridge
Corp., Southco, Inc. v. Kanebridge Corp. (Southco I), 258
F.3d 148 (3d Cir. 2001) (No. 00-1102), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f4900/4953.pdf;
Brief Amicus Curiae of the United States of America
in Support of Appellee Kanebridge Corp., Southco,
Inc. v. Kanebridge Corp. (Southco II), 390 F.3d 276 (3d
Cir. 2004) (en banc) (No. 02-1243), cert. denied, 126 S.
Ct. 336 (2005), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/
atr/cases/f201000/201034.pdf; Brief for Amicus
Curiae United States of America in Support of
Appellees, Matthew Bender & Co. v. West Publ’g Co.,
158 F.3d 693 (2d Cir. 1998) (No. 97-7430), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f1100/1191.pdf.
72
One of the panelists discussed how, if the per se
rule for tying is ultimately abandoned, courts can best
deal with complex issues so as both to reach the right
answers in individual cases and to provide some
predictability as to how business practices will be
analyzed. May 14 Tr. at 54-63 (Lipsky); Abbott B.
Lipsky, Amateurs in Black (May 14, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 6-
12, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020514abbottblipskyjr.pdf [hereinafter Lipsky
Submission]. Lipsky said that the Supreme Court, in
a series of four cases beginning with Daubert v.
Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc, 509 U.S. 579 (1993),
has mandated that the district courts assume the
position of gatekeepers and make independent
evaluations (subject to review for abuse of discretion)
of the relevance, reliability, and fit of expert
testimony. He suggested that this procedure has
revolutionized the presentation of expert testimony
and noted that in a number of antitrust cases expert
testimony has been rejected. He maintained that,
when courts evaluate particular patent licensing
practices, they will need institutions superior to those
currently available in order to generate
improvements in the quality of economic analysis.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION114
the panel suggested that, rather than
attempting to categorize the conduct (e.g.,
as tying or not) or looking at cost
standards, a better approach would be “to
ask why are you doing this; what are the
efficiencies, are there other ways to
achieve the efficiencies; do you expect it
to block competition[?]”
73
IV. CONCLUSION
Legal and policy analysis of
intellectual property bundling has
evolved over time. Older case law, with
its per se rule and presumption of market
power, contends with the current analysis
of the Agencies and some more recent
lower court decisions that embody, in
essence, a rule of reason approach.
Moreover, the Supreme Court recently
eliminated its rule presuming market
power based on intellectual property.
Panelists noted that, although intellectual
property bundling may have
anticompetitive potential in certain
circumstances, there may also be
significant efficiency justifications for
such bundling in some cases. Thus, as a
matter of their prosecutorial discretion,
the Agencies will apply the rule of reason
when evaluating intellectual property
tying and bundling agreements.
74
Given
the ubiquitous use of these arrangements
by businesses lacking in market power
and the efficiencies that such
arrangements can often entail, these
practices usually are not anticompetitive.
When the Agencies do identify
anticompetitive situations, however, they
will pursue them.
Possible approaches that he described include
certification by an expert body, such as the National
Academy of Sciences or American Economic
Association, appointment by the court of an expert
under rule 706(a) of the Federal Rules of Evidence, or
use of a law clerk particularly skilled in economics.
May 14 Tr. at 54-63 (Lipsky); see also Lipsky
Submission at 7-12.
73
May 14 Tr. at 103 (Farrell).
74
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.3 (stating that, in
exercising their prosecutorial discretion, the Agencies
“consider both the anticompetitive effects and the
efficiencies attributable to a tie-in”).
115
CHAPTER 6
COMPETITIVE ISSUES REGARDING PRACTICES THAT EXTEND
THE MARKET POWER CONFERRED BY A PATENT BEYOND ITS
STATUTORY TERM
A portion of the Hearings focused
on the competitive impact of practices
that firms may use to extend the reach of
a patent beyond the expiration of a
patent’s statutory term.
1
Such practices
traditionally have been challenged under
the doctrine of patent misuse.
2
By
contrast, there have been few antitrust
challenges to these practices, perhaps
because they cause competitive concern
only if the patent in question has
conferred market power, i.e., the patent
holder can profitably “maintain prices
above, or output below, competitive
levels for a significant period of time,”
3
and the practice unreasonably extends
that market power beyond the patent’s
expiration.
4
1
Utility patents have a statutory term of twenty
years from the date of filing. 35 U.S.C. § 154 (2000).
A design patent has a term of fourteen years from the
date of grant. 35 U.S.C. § 173 (2000). The value of a
patent declines for one of two reasons: either its term
expires or new noninfringing products or processes
become available that “diminish any market power
the [patent] may have commanded.” May 14, 2002
Hr’g Tr., Antitrust Analysis of Specific Intellectual
Property Licensing Practices: Bundling, Grantbacks
and Temporal Extensions (Morning Session) at 119
(Dick), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
020514trans.pdf [hereinafter May 14 Tr.]; see also
Richard C. Levin, Alvin K. Klevorick, Richard R.
Nelson & Sidney G. Winter, Appropriating the Returns
from Industrial Research and Development, 1987
BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY 783, 808, 810-
11 (explaining that one to three years was the median
estimate by industry respondents surveyed about the
time required for imitators to duplicate a major
patented new process or product and “to have a
significant impact on the market”) (internal quotation
marks omitted). This Chapter does not address these
and other complex issues that may arise when patent-
conferred market power may decline due to the entry
of noninfringing substitutes before patent expiration.
2
See 1 HERBERT HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS & MARK
A. LEMLEY, IP AND ANTITRUST: AN ANALYSIS OF
ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY LAW § 3.2c, at 3-8 to -10 (2002 & Supp. 2005)
[hereinafter 1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST];
see also infra note 12 and accompanying text. See
generally 1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST §
3.3b, at 3-12 to -36 (Supp. 2005).
3
“The Agencies will not presume that a patent . . .
confers market power upon its owner.” U.S. DEPT OF
JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, ANTITRUST
GUIDELINES FOR THE LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY § 2.2 (1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep.
(CCH) ¶ 13,132, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/
atr/public/guidelines/0558.pdf [hereinafter
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES]. The U.S. Supreme Court
recently confirmed that market power should not be
presumed merely from the existence of a patent. Ill.
Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281, 1293
(2006) (“Congress, the antitrust enforcement agencies,
and most economists have all reached the conclusion
that a patent does not necessarily confer market
power upon the patentee. Today, we reach the same
conclusion . . . .”).
4
The Agencies have stated that “[i]f a patent or other
form of intellectual property does confer market
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION116
This Chapter discusses certain
practices that have been alleged to have
the potential to harm competition by
unreasonably extending market power
conferred by a patent beyond the patent’s
expiration: collecting royalties beyond
the statutory term, the use of exclusive
contracts that deprive rivals or potential
entrants of a source of supply or access to
customers, or bundling trade secrets with
patents.
5
Most of the practices discussed
in the Chapter, such as exclusive dealing,
are not unique to patent licenses.
Moreover, although some of these
practices may have the potential to extend
the ability to exercise the market power
conferred by a patent, most practices do
not actually do so, and as many Hearings
panelists
6
observed, many may, in fact,
offer significant efficiencies.
7
Accordingly, panelists identified the
fundamental question for assessing
competitive harm that may result from
such practices to be whether the patent
holder is exercising market power arising
solely from the patent beyond its
statutory term to prevent expansion by
those already in the market or to deter the
entry of substitute products or processes
into the market.
8
I. COLLECTING ROYALTIES
BEYOND THE STATUTORY
TERM
Some have viewed a requirement
that a licensee pay royalties beyond a
patent’s expiration as unreasonably
extending the market power conferred by
the patent. Panelists discussed whether
such a requirement can actually extend a
patent’s market power.
9
One panelist
power, that market power does not by itself offend
the antitrust laws.” ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.2.
5
Other practices might also extend the market power
of a patent beyond the end of that patent’s statutory
term. E.g., May 14 Tr. at 129-33 (Dick) (discussing a
covenant not to compete that was entered in
connection with a joint venture, but extended beyond
the life of the joint venture and any intellectual
property associated with the joint venture); id. at 138
(Dick) (noting that grantbacks may raise the question
whether the acquisition of rights in improvement
patents by the original patentee may enable that
patentee to use its expired core patents as a means to
obtain control over later-generation products); id. at
133-37 (Dick) (discussing a patent holder that
includes unnecessary, but later-expiring patents in a
pool, or that makes unwarranted modifications to a
standard in order to justify inclusion of later-expiring
patents); id. at 128-29 (Dick) (discussing rebate
programs and incentive sales agreements that extend
beyond the life of the patented technology and have
the potential to extend the market power conferred
by the patent).
6
Panelists addressing this topic at the May 14, 2002
Hearing were: Rebecca P. Dick, Of Counsel, Swidler
Berlin Shereff Friedman, LLP; Joseph Farrell,
Professor of Economics and Chair of the Competition
Policy Center, University of California, Berkeley; and
David S. Sibley, John Michael Stuart Professor of
Economics, University of Texas at Austin. The
session was moderated by Michael L. Katz, then-
Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust
Division, U.S. Department of Justice and David L.
Scheffman, then-Director, Bureau of Economics, U.S.
Federal Trade Commission. They were joined by C.
Edward Polk, Jr., then-Associate Solicitor, U.S. Patent
and Trademark Office.
7
See, e.g., infra notes 24-25 and accompanying text
(discussing the efficiencies of contract provisions
involving exclusivity).
8
See generally Rebecca P. Dick, Extending the Useful
Life of Intellectual Property: Antitrust Risks and Safety
Zones (May 14, 2002 Hr’g R.) (slides),
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020514dick.pdf
[hereinafter Dick Presentation]; May 14 Tr. at 119-45
(Dick); id. at 146-49 (Sibley).
9
At the Hearings, panelists considered, for example,
whether reach-through royalty agreements that
continue beyond the life of a research tool patent raise
antitrust concerns. See, e.g., Nov. 6, 2002 Hr’g Tr.,
Relationships Among Competitors and Incentives to
Compete: Cross-Licensing of Patent Portfolios,
Grantbacks, Reach-Through Royalties, and Non-
Assertion Clauses (Afternoon Session) at 157-58
117
Extending a Patent’s Market Power
suggested that agreements that seek
“royalties that run past the lifetime of a
patent” may pose an antitrust problem
because a patent licensor with market
power may be using the agreement to
extend royalty payments beyond the
patent term and get the same royalty “for
50 years instead of 20.”
10
Over forty years
ago, in Brulotte v. Thys Co.,
11
the U.S.
Supreme Court condemned an agreement
in which the licensor demanded royalties
for practicing an invention beyond the life
of its patents as per se patent misuse.
12
Brulotte, however, did not involve an
antitrust claim,
13
and its holding reaches
only agreements in which royalties
actually accrue on post-expiration use.
14
Thus, courts tend to apply the opinion
narrowly.
15
In addition, Brulotte has been
strongly criticized on the ground that
(Fromm), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/
021106ftctrans.pdf [hereinafter Nov. 6 Tr.]; id. at 162
(Shapiro); id. at 170-72 (Rule). In a reach-through
royalty agreement, the royalty is based on
downstream sales of a product that was created with
the use of the research tool patent. See supra Chapter
4, Variations on Intellectual Property Licensing Practices
Part IV. See generally Michael A. Heller & Rebecca S.
Eisenberg, Can Patents Deter Innovation? The
Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280 SCIENCE 698
(1998). Questions related to the duration of market
power conferred by the patent arise when the product
continues to be sold, subject to royalties, beyond the
expiration date of the research tool patent. See Robin
C. Feldman, The Insufficiency of Antitrust Analysis for
Patent Misuse, 55 HASTINGS L.J. 399, 443-47 (2003);
Nov. 6 Tr. at 157-58, 163 (Fromm).
10
Nov. 6 Tr. at 163 (Fromm); see also supra Chapter 4,
Variations on Intellectual Property Licensing Practices
Part IV.
11
379 U.S. 29 (1964).
12
Id. at 30-32. “Patent misuse is an equitable defense
to patent infringement” and is not a separate cause of
action. U.S. Philips Corp. v. Int’l Trade Comm’n, 424
F.3d 1179, 1184 (Fed. Cir. 2005). Patent misuse is said
to be broader than antitrust liability as it extends to
“some sorts of conduct antitrust law would not
reach.” 1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST §
3.2c, at 3-10. Over the years, however, patent misuse
has become more “coextensive” with antitrust
doctrine, see id., and the United States Court of
Appeals for the Federal Circuit applies antitrust
principles in deciding cases involving allegations of
patent misuse. See id. § 3.2a, at 3-6.
13
In Brulotte, the patent owner sued the licensee to
recover royalty payments. 379 U.S. at 29-30.
14
See Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395
U.S. 100, 136-37 (1969) (“Recognizing that the
patentee [in Brulotte] could lawfully charge a royalty
for practicing a patented invention prior to its
expiration date and that the payment of this royalty
could be postponed beyond that time, we noted that
the post-expiration royalties were not for prior use
but for current use, and were nothing less than an
effort by the patentee to extend the term of his
monopoly beyond that granted by law. Brulotte thus
articulated in a particularized context the principle
that a patentee may not use the power of his patent to
levy a charge for making, using, or selling products
not within the reach of the monopoly granted by the
Government.”).
15
See Bayer AG v. Housey Pharms., Inc., 228 F. Supp.
2d 467, 472-73 (D. Del. 2002) (finding it permissible
for a patentee to agree to postpone royalty payments
when the payments were clearly in exchange for
practicing the patented technology prior to the
expiration of the patent); see also Aronson v. Quick
Point Pencil Co., 440 U.S. 257, 264-66 (1979)
(permitting, consistent with Brulotte, enforcement of a
royalty agreement that required payment for use of
an invention for which a patent never issued because
the agreement was “freely undertaken . . . with no
fixed reliance on a patent or a probable patent
grant”); cf. Pitney Bowes, Inc. v. Mestre, 701 F.2d 1365,
1373 (11th Cir. 1983) (holding that licensing rights
and obligations applying in both the pre- and post-
expiration period signaled that “at least some part of
the post-expiration payment” compensated “for
patent rights beyond the patent period”), cert. denied,
464 U.S. 893 (1983); Meehan v. PPG Indus., Inc., 802
F.2d 881, 886 (7th Cir. 1986) (holding licensing terms
unlawful per se because contract “fail[ed] to
distinguish between pre-expiration and post-
expiration royalties”), cert. denied, 479 U.S. 1091
(1987); Boggild v. Kenner Prods., 776 F.2d 1315, 1321
(6th Cir. 1985), cert. denied, 477 U.S. 908 (1986) (same).
See generally 1 HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST
§§ 23.2a-e, at 23-5 to 23-22.3 (2002 & Supp. 2005)
(discussing, inter alia, the treatment of post-expiration
royalties and royalties collected on unissued patents
in light of Brulotte).
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION118
“post-expiration royalties merely
amortize the price of using patented
technology.
16
According to Judge
Posner, writing for the court in Scheiber v.
Dolby Laboratories, Inc., “[f]or a licensee . .
. to go on paying royalties after the patent
expires does not extend the duration of
the patent . . . because . . . if the licensee
agrees to continue paying royalties after
the patent expires the royalty rate will be
lower.”
17
Economists agree, contending
that agreements that extend royalty
payments beyond the patent term
actually can “reduce the deadweight loss
from a patent monopoly” because per-
period royalties are low, and yet the
licensor recoups the same present value
rent from licensing the patent.
18
This
point was reiterated at the Hearings.
19
It
is generally better, one panelist asserted,
to have a “long[,] small stream of
royalties rather than a short[,] large
stream” because the former collects the
same intellectual property rent with the
same incentives for innovation but with a
lower deadweight loss.
20
Another
panelist suggested that collecting royalty
payments beyond the patent’s enforceable
life is not an antitrust concern because a
patentee is entitled to appropriate value
from its intellectual property and a
licensee will not pay a royalty that
exceeds the value of that intellectual
property.
21
Because the purpose of patent
protection is to provide incentives for
innovation, measures that permit a
patentee to capture more fully the value
of its patent may lead to a more efficient
level of innovation, this panelist opined.
22
Another possibility is that
agreements that require royalties to be
16
10 PHILLIP E. AREEDA, EINER ELHAUGE & HERBERT
HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ANALYSIS OF
ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION §
1782c, at 492 (2004); Richard Gilbert & Carl Shapiro,
Antitrust Issues in the Licensing of Intellectual Property:
The Nine No-No’s Meet the Nineties, 1997 BROOKINGS
PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY, MICROECONOMICS 233,
322 (“Legal reasoning here . . . although rhetorically
appealing, does not seem to reflect commercial reality
or basic economics.”).
17
293 F.3d 1014, 1017 (7th Cir. 2002). The Scheiber
court strongly criticized the holding in Brulotte, but
felt compelled to follow it and hold the patent license
agreement at issue unenforceable. The U.S. Court of
Appeals for the Seventh Circuit invited the Supreme
Court to reconsider the matter. Id. at 1018 (“[W]e
have no authority to overrule a Supreme Court
decision no matter how dubious its reasoning strikes
us, or even how out of touch with the Supreme
Court’s current thinking the decision seems.”). But
the Supreme Court declined to grant certiorari.
Scheiber v. Dolby Labs., Inc., 537 U.S. 1109 (2003).
18
Gilbert & Shapiro, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON
ECON. ACTIVITY, MICROECONOMICS at 322. Once a
patent expires, a licensee can use the patent for no
charge. It is therefore unclear how a licensor could
persuade a licensee to pay more than the amount the
licensee would be willing to pay to use the patent
during its term. Scheiber, 293 F.3d at 1017; Gilbert &
Shapiro, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY,
MICROECONOMICS at 322.
19
See, e.g., Nov. 6 Tr. at 162-64 (Shapiro)
(“[S]preading out royalties over a larger brace and a
lower rate could be better.”).
20
May 14 Tr. at 149-50 (Farrell) (discussing Gilbert &
Shapiro’s analysis); see also Stephen M. Law, Inter-
temporal Tie-ins: A Case for Tying Intellectual Property
Through Licensing, 11 INTL J. ECON. BUS. 3, 15 (2004)
(“The countervailing benefit to society from allowing
the licensor greater freedom to contract is the
reduction in royalty rate, and hence prices, during the
patent period that occurs as the licensor adjusts the
license to induce a licensee to accept the longer
term.”). Moreover, the antitrust laws are not
concerned with agreements that allow a licensee to
amortize royalty payments beyond the life of the
licensed patent if the patent itself does not confer
market power.
21
Nov. 6 Tr. at 171-72 (Rule).
22
See, e.g., id. at 171 (Rule) (using metering to capture
the value created by intellectual property “is a good
thing” because “[i]t tends to disseminate technology
broader oftentimes than a single price”).
119
Extending a Patent’s Market Power
paid beyond the statutory term may
enable a licensor to overcome incomplete
contracting. Incomplete contracting
occurs when imperfect contracting
conditions prevent a licensor from
negotiating a satisfactory royalty rate that
reflects the patent’s true value. To resolve
this problem, there may be an incentive
and ability to require the payment of
royalties after the patent expires as a
condition of licensing during the patent
period, thus allowing a licensor to capture
the patent’s full value.
23
II. LONG TERM CONTRACTS
INVOLVING EXCLUSIVITY
An exclusive patent license can
offer significant efficiencies. Such a
license can, for example, encourage the
exclusive licensee to commercialize and
distribute the patented invention to
consumers and make improvements
without the threat of free-riding by the
patent holder or its other licensees.
24
Exclusivity provisions, such as field-of-
use or territorial restrictions, can ease the
threat of misappropriation, which can
mitigate competitive concerns over a
potentially anticompetitive agreement.
25
Panelists discussed how
agreements involving exclusivity might
be used instead to extend a patent’s
market power beyond the patent’s
statutory term. One panelist used the
example of long-term contracts that
extend past patent expiration to
demonstrate that such activities can cause
competitive harm.
26
The panelist
explained that exclusive dealing can
profitably deter entry if an incumbent
firm can convince enough customers to
carry its product exclusively, leaving too
few customers for a new entrant to reach
a minimum viable scale. For example, the
panelist said that it might be in the
interest of the incumbent seller to give
hefty inducements to one or more buyers
to sign long-term contracts instead of
awaiting new entry. Once a critical mass
of buyers has signed up, later buyers may
be willing to sign contracts at higher
prices. These buyers would not receive
the price inducements from the
incumbent seller nor enjoy the prospect of
new entry because they know that their
contracting decisions cannot attract new
entrants who need to have a minimum
number of buyers in order to enter.
27
23
For example, if a licensee valued a patent at $100
during the patent period, but imperfect contracting
conditions would allow the patent holder to extract
only $70 during the patent period, the licensee would
be willing ex ante to agree to pay up to $30 of royalties
after the patent expired, even though the patent then
could be used at no charge. An analogous incentive
is well recognized, for example, in regulated
industries in which a seller has an incentive to tie a
regulated service, whose regulated price is below the
maximum value a customer would pay, with an
unregulated service to raise the price of that
unregulated service and extract additional rents. See
DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN
INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 319-20 (4th ed. 2005).
24
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 2.3.
25
Id. §§ 2.3, 4.1.2.
26
May 14 Tr. at 146-49 (Sibley); see also George G.
Gordon & James P. Denvir, III, Is There Life After a
Patent?: Strategies to Maximize the Value of Product
Life-Cycles After a Patent Expires, Presentation
Before the American Bar Association, Antitrust
Section 281-84 (May 3-4, 2001) (on file with the
Department of Justice and Federal Trade
Commission) [hereinafter Gordon & Denvir, Is There
Life After a Patent?].
27
May 14 Tr. at 146-49 (Sibley); see also David S.
Sibley, Long Term Contracts as a Barrier to Entry (May
14, 2002 Hr’g R.) at 2-3, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/
intellect/020514sibley.pdf.
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION120
Others have explored the
conditions that would induce a consumer
to sign a long-term contract with an
incumbent monopolist.
28
If enough
consumers sign such an agreement, the
probability of entry may become very
low, allowing the incumbent to continue
charging higher prices. However, the
individual buyer, in signing a long-term
contract—perhaps in return for a
discount—may ignore the resulting lower
probability of entry that its contract
causes. The reduced probability of entry
gives the incumbent more scope to get
buyers to accept higher prices for a long-
term contract.
29
This activity could
extend the market power conferred by the
patent beyond patent expiration.
In addition, one panelist addressed
how the discounts associated with
incentive sales agreements or rebate
programs could be used to extend the
market power conferred by a patent
beyond the patent’s expiration.
30
In an
incentive sales agreement or rebate
program, the price a licensee pays over
time can be based on the use of the
patented technology both during the life
of the patent and after the patent has
expired. To illustrate how such programs
might be used to extend the market
power conferred by a patent beyond the
patent’s expiration, this panelist pointed
to one district court case in which an
aggrieved competitor argued that its
rival’s rebate program was an
anticompetitive attempt to extend the
monopoly conferred by a valuable patent
beyond its expiration. According to the
panelist, the program was designed so
that a customer would forfeit rebates on
prior purchases of the patented product if
the customer’s purchasing volume fell
after the patent expired and generic
alternatives were available;
31
the risk of
forfeiture allegedly coerced the customer
into using the branded product
exclusively.
32
This panelist stated that in
analyzing such practices antitrust
enforcers should consider, inter alia,
whether “calculating a total discount
based on purchases both pre- and post-
expiration improperly extends the term of
the patent.”
33
III. BUNDLING PATENTS WITH
TRADE SECRETS
The panel also discussed whether
antitrust issues can arise if a patent holder
tries to extend the market power
conferred by a patent beyond its
expiration by bundling the patent license
with trade secrets or know-how.
34
Unlike
28
See, e.g., Philippe Aghion & Patrick Bolton,
Contracts as a Barrier to Entry, 77 AM. ECON. REV. 388
(1987); Eric B. Rasmusen, J. Mark Ramseyer & John S.
Wiley, Jr., Naked Exclusion, 81 AM. ECON. REV. 1137
(1991); Ilya R. Segal & Michael D. Whinston, Naked
Exclusion: Comment, 90 AM. ECON. REV. 296 (2000);
John Simpson & Abraham Wickelgren, The Use of
Exclusive Contracts to Deter Entry (Bureau of Econ.,
Fed. Trade Comm’n, Working Paper No. 241, 2001),
available at http://www.ftc.gov/be/workpapers/
wp241.pdf.
29
Aghion & Bolton, 77 AM. ECON. REV. at 396-97.
30
See May 14 Tr. at 126-28 (Dick).
31
See id. at 127-28 (Dick) (discussing private litigation
against Monsanto involving its incentive sales
agreements regarding its patented Roundup
herbicide); see also Complaint and Jury Demand
paras. 3, 24-27, Chem. Prods. Techs., LLC v. Monsanto
Co., No. 4:01-4384-12 (D.S.C. Nov. 13, 2001) (settled
Nov. 2002).
32
Complaint and Jury Demand paras. 25, 54-56, 69,
73-74, 83, Chem. Prods. Techs., No. 4:01-4384-12.
33
May 14 Tr. at 128-29 (Dick).
34
Id. at 121-26 (Dick); see also Gilbert & Shapiro, 1997
121
Extending a Patent’s Market Power
patents, trade secrets enjoy perpetual
protection provided the proprietary
information remains secret.
35
If the patent
in such a “hybrid agreement” expires, or
if the trade secrets hold little or no value,
the licensing of these rights may
incorporate restrictions that effectively
establish a cartel. That was the
Department of Justice’s allegation in
United States v. Pilkington plc.
36
Pilkington
had once held patents on a process for
making flat glass. During the life of those
patents, Pilkington set up a worldwide
licensing regime with exclusive territories
in which each licensee could practice the
patent. By the early 1980s, the principal
U.S. patents on the process had expired.
Nevertheless, Pilkington continued to
enforce a worldwide licensing scheme
with exclusive territories based solely on
the licensing of trade secrets. The
Department challenged this scheme in
1994, alleging that any remaining trade
secrets consisted of engineering solutions
with no substantial value over equally
efficacious engineering alternatives. The
Department argued that the licensing of
the know-how was a sham, and it had
simply become a device for implementing
a cartel.
37
Most intellectual property
bundling agreements, in contrast, are not
sham agreements, and they often serve as
mechanisms for reducing transaction
costs, alleviating blocking positions, or
creating other efficiencies.
38
BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY,
MICROECONOMICS at 322 (stating such “hybrid”
bundling agreements are a “common tactic” that is
used to extend the term of the agreement beyond the
patent’s expiration); Pitney Bowes, 701 F.2d 1365
(involving a “hybrid” patent and a know-how
license); Indus. Promotion Co. v. Versa Prods., Inc., 467
N.W.2d 168, 169 (Wis. Ct. App. 1991) (same).
35
Trade secrets can be licensed to others, much like
patents and copyrights. As one panelist explained,
trade secret protection offers the benefit of no
expiration of the rights as long as the trade secrets are
not disclosed in the public domain. Trade secrets
have no fixed term and are governed by state law,
operating entirely outside the federal patent or
copyright regimes. (Although the Model Uniform
Trade Secrets Act drafted by the National Conference
of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws, provides
some guidance about what constitutes know-how
and how rights to it can be enforced, there are
variations in the state schemes and some states have
not adopted the Act in any form.) Trade secrets,
however, usually leak out. Apart from Coca-Cola’s
close holding of its secret formula, few firms have
been able to protect their trade secrets for long
periods, the panelist stated. May 14 Tr. at 121-22
(Dick); see also Edwin Mansfield, How Rapidly Does
New Industrial Technology Leak Out?, 34 J. INDUS.
ECON. 217, 219-21 (1985) (explaining that information
about the detailed nature and operations of a new
product or process is in the hands of at least some
rival firms within a year, on the average, after a new
product is developed, and sometimes within six
months).
36
Complaint paras. 26-31, United States v. Pilkington
plc, No. 94-345, 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 70,842,
1994 WL 750645 (D. Ariz. Dec. 22, 1994), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f0000/0014.pdf;
see also United States v. Pilkington plc and Pilkington
Holdings Inc.; Proposed Final Judgment and
Competitive Impact Statement, 59 Fed. Reg. 30,604,
30,508-10 (June 14, 1994), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f220800/220860.
pdf, http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f220800/
220861.pdf.
37
Dick Presentation at 4-5; May 14 Tr. at 122-24
(Dick). The consent decree eliminated all territorial
and use limitations Pilkington imposed on U.S.
licensees and allowed them to manufacture on their
own or sublicense any third party to do so anywhere
in the world, free of charge, using the float
technology disclosed and licensed to those licensees.
The decree also provided, in effect, a similar “safe
harbor” for any other American individual or firm
who was not a Pilkington float glass licensee to use
any float technology in its possession without liability
to Pilkington. Pilkington, 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶
70,842, at 73,668-71, 1994 WL 750645, at *2-5.
38
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 5.3; Philips, 424 F.3d at
1192-93 (noting the efficiencies of package licensing);
May 14 Tr. at 133 (Dick) (stating package licenses can
be “a very efficient means for transferring IP rights”);
see also id. at 19-20, 25 (Vistnes) (stating there are
greater, or at least a greater potential for, efficiencies
PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION122
IV. THE AGENCIES’ ANALYSIS
The Agencies review most
agreements that have the potential to
extend the market power conferred by a
valuable patent beyond that patent’s
expiration pursuant to the rule of
reason.
39
The first step in the Agencies’
analysis is to assess whether the patent at
issue confers market power upon its
holder, and if so, whether the patent
holder’s conduct unreasonably extends
that market power beyond the patent’s
statutory term. In performing that
inquiry, the Agencies consider, as
panelists suggested, whether a firm is
exercising such market power beyond the
patent’s statutory term so as to prevent
expansion by those already in the market,
or deter entry of substitute products or
processes.
40
Few antitrust cases involving the
improper extension of patent rights have
been brought in recent years. Panelists at
the Hearings explained that this may be
because few practices that could extend
the market power conferred by a patent
beyond the patent’s expiration actually do
so.
41
Moreover, many restrictions that
have the potential to extend the market
power conferred by a valuable patent
beyond its term can have demonstrable
efficiencies. The Agencies have
recognized, for example, that contracts
that require exclusive dealing may
encourage a licensee to further develop
the licensed technology. It is also possible
that collecting royalties over a longer
term than the patent grant will reduce the
deadweight loss associated with a patent
monopoly and allow the patent holder to
recover the full value of the patent,
thereby preserving innovation incentives.
Although some agreements may have
anticompetitive effects, patent licenses
can often be “expected to contribute to an
efficiency-enhancing integration of
economic activity,”
42
and thus the
Agencies generally analyze them
pursuant to the rule of reason. Of course,
with regard to any of these practices, per
se treatment would be warranted if a
particular practice is a sham—if, for
associated with intellectual property bundles); 1
HERBERT HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 22.5,
at 22-32 (making a similar observation); Evans &
Salinger, 22 YALE J. ON REG. at 41 (“Bundling . . . can
provide efficiencies such as marginal cost savings,
quality improvements, and customer convenience.”).
39
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.4 (“In the vast
majority of cases, restraints in intellectual property
licensing arrangements are evaluated under the rule
of reason. . . . If there is no efficiency-enhancing
integration of economic activity and if the type of
restraint is one that has been accorded per se
treatment, the Agencies will challenge the restraint
under the per se rule. Otherwise, the Agencies will
apply a rule of reason analysis.”).
40
See supra note 8 and accompanying text.
41
See, e.g., May 14 Tr. at 149-50 (Farrell); id. at 156
(Katz). In addition, legal doctrines may limit antitrust
challenges in this area. For example, successful
lobbying that leads to enactment of a legislative or
regulatory regime with rules inhibiting entry might
well extend the duration of patent-conferred market
power. See id. at 145 (Dick) (noting copyright holders
successful efforts to extend copyright protection for
an additional number of years which resulted in the
Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act, Pub. L.
No. 105-298, 112 Stat. 2827 (1998)); see also Gordon &
Denvir, Is There Life After a Patent? at 279-81
(discussing an antitrust challenge to a branded firm’s
activities and related publicity campaigns directed at
excluding generic competition). The Noerr-Pennington
doctrine exempts from antitrust enforcement certain
bona fide petitioning conduct directed toward a
governmental decision maker. See United Mine
Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965); E. R.R.
Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365
U.S. 127 (1961).
42
ANTITRUST-IP GUIDELINES § 3.4.
123
Extending a Patent’s Market Power
example, it is designed to implement a
market division agreement among
competitors.
43
43
Id.
125
APPENDIX A
HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS
Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Economy February 6 - November 6, 2002
Primary source: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/index.htm
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Aharonian, Greg Publisher, Internet Patent News Service Panel: 2/27/02
Submission:
2/27/02
Alderrucci, Dean Chief Counsel of Intellectual Property,
Walker Digital Management LLC
Panel: 4/9/02
Alexiadis, Peter Partner, Squire, Sanders & Dempsey LLP,
Brussels
Panel: 5/22/02
Allen, Gwilliym Senior Economist and Strategic Policy
Advisor, Competition Policy Branch,
Canadian Competition Bureau
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Alstadt, Lynn J. Shareholder, Buchanan Ingersoll PC;
Adjunct Professor, Duquesne University
Panel: 3/19/02
American Bar
Association, Section of
Antitrust Law
Public Comments
American Bar
Association, Section of
Intellectual Property
Law
Public Comments
American Intellectual
Property Law
Association
Public Comments
American National
Standards Institute
Public Comments
Anderman, Steven D. Professor of Law, University of Essex,
England
Submission:
5/22/02
Antalics, Michael Partner, O’Melveny & Myers LLP Panel: 4/18/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS126
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Armbrecht, F.M. Ross,
Jr.
President, Industrial Research Institute Panel: 3/19/02
Armitage, Robert A. Vice President and General Patent Counsel,
Eli Lilly and Company
Panel: 3/19/02
Arora, Ashish Visiting Associate Professor of Economics,
Stanford University; Associate Professor of
Economics and Public Policy, Carnegie
Mellon University
Panels: 2/25/02,
5/1/02
Submissions:
2/25/02, 5/01/02
Arrow, Kenneth J. Nobel Memorial Prize and Joan Kenney
Professor of Economics Emeritus, and
Professor of Operations Research Emeritus,
Stanford University
Panel: 2/25/02
Submission:
2/25/02
Arthur D. Little, Inc. Public Comments
Aventis
Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
Public Comments
Baker, Charles P. Partner, Fitzpatrick, Cella, Harper & Scinto Panel: 7/11/02
Submission:
7/11/02
Balto, David A.
(with Daniel I.
Prywes)
Partner, White & Case LLP Public Comments
Banner, Mark T. Banner & Witcoff, Ltd.; Chair, American
Bar Association, Intellectual Property Law
Section
Panel: 10/30/02
Barnes, E. Bruce Public Comments
Barnett, Thomas O. Partner, Covington & Burling Panel: 5/02/02
Barr, Robert Vice President and Worldwide Patent
Counsel, Cisco Systems, Inc.
Panels: 2/28/02,
10/30/02
Submission:
2/28/02
Barton, John H. George E. Osborne Professor of Law,
Stanford University Law School
Panel: 2/26/02
Submission:
2/26/02
Public Comments
Beeney, Garrard R. Partner, Sullivan & Cromwell Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 127
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Beier, David W. Partner, Hogan & Hartson LLP; Counsel to
Biotechnology Industry Organization;
Senior Fellow, Wharton School of Business,
University of Pennsylvania
Panel: 2/26/02
Submission:
2/26/02
Bendekgey, Lee General Counsel and Executive Vice
President, Incyte Genomics
Panel: 2/26/02
Besen, Stanley M. Vice President, Charles River Associates Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Bessen, James
(with Eric Maskin)
Public Comments
Bhaskar, R. Senior Research Fellow, Harvard Business
School
Panels: 7/11/02,
10/25/02
Submission:
7/11/02
Black, Edward J. President and CEO, Computer &
Communications Industry Association
Panel: 3/20/02
Submission:
3/20/02
Blackburn, Robert Vice President, Chief Patent Counsel,
Chiron Corp.; Distinguished Scholar,
Berkeley Center for Law and Technology
Panel: 2/26/02
Boast, Molly S. Partner, Debevoise & Plimpton LLP Panel: 5/14/02
Boulware, Margaret
A.
Shareholder, Jenkens & Gilchrist PC Panel: 10/30/02
Boyce, John R.
(with Aidan Hollis)
Professor, Department of Economics,
University of Calgary
Public Comments
Brodley, Joseph F. Professor, Kennison Distinguished Scholar
of Law, Boston University School of Law
Panel: 5/2/02
Submission: 5/2/02
Browder, Monte R. Senior Intellectual Property Counsel, Ivax
Corp.
Panel: 3/19/02
Brunt, George B. Senior Vice President, General Counsel and
Secretary, Alcatel USA
Panel: 3/20/02
Submission:
3/20/02
Buddington, Eric Semi-Professional Programmer Public Comments
Burchfiel, Kenneth J. Partner, Sughrue Mion, PLLC Panel: 4/11/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS128
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Burk, Dan L. Julius E. Davis Professor of Law, University
of Minnesota Law School
Panels: 3/20/02,
7/10/02
Submissions:
3/20/02, 7/10/02
Burtis, Michelle Director, LECG, LLC Panel: 11/6/02
Busey, Roxanne C. Partner, Gardner Carton & Douglas; Chair,
American Bar Association Section of
Antitrust Law
Panel: 7/11/02
Submission:
7/11/02
Cargill, Carl Director of Standards, Sun Microsystems,
Inc.
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Carlin, Fiona Partner, European Law Center, Baker &
McKenzie, Brussels
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Carrier, Michael A. Assistant Professor, Rutgers University
School of Law–Camden
Public Comments
Cary, George S. Partner, Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen & Hamilton Panel: 5/2/02
Submission: 5/2/02
Casamento, Gregory
John
Software Engineer Public Comments
Casey, Timothy D. Partner and Chairman of Intellectual
Property and Technology Transactions
Department, Fried, Frank, Harris, Shriver &
Jacobsen
Panel: 4/9/02
Caulfield, Barbara A. Executive Vice President and General
Counsel, Affymetrix, Inc.
Panel: 3/19/02
Submission:
3/19/02
Chaikovsky, Yar R. General Counsel, Zaplet, Inc. Panel: 2/27/02
Chambers, Scott A. M. Associate, Arnold and Porter; Adjunct
Faculty Member at Georgetown Law Center
and the George Washington University
School of Law
Panels: 2/8/02,
10/25/02
Submission: 2/8/02
Chin, Yee Wah Senior Counsel, Mintz, Levin Cohn, Ferris,
Glovsky and Pompeo, PC
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Coffin-Beach, David President, Torpharm, Inc. Panel: 3/19/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 129
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Cohen, Wesley M. Professor of Economics and Social Science,
Carnegie Mellon University; Professor of
Economics and Management, Fuqua School
of Business, Duke University; Research
Associate, National Bureau of Economic
Research
Panels: 2/20/02,
10/30/02
Submission:
2/20/02
Cook, Robert N. Partner, Drinker, Biddle & Reath LLP Panel: 5/2/02
Submission: 5/2/02
Craft, James A. Gammage & Burnham Public Comments
Crossman, Colin
(with Thomas Griffin,
David Silverstein, &
Mark Webbink)
Student, Duke University School of Law Public Comments
Delrahim, Makan Republican Chief Counsel, Senate
Committee on the Judiciary
Panel: 3/19/02
Detkin, Peter N. Vice President, Legal and Government
Affairs and Assistant General Counsel, Intel
Corp.
Panel: 2/28/02
Submission:
2/28/02
Deutsch, Donald R. Vice President, Standards Strategy and
Architecture, Oracle Corp.
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Dick, Rebecca P. Of Counsel, Swidler Berlin Shereff
Friedman, LLP
Panel: 5/14/02
Submission:
5/14/02
Dickinson, Q. Todd Partner, Howrey, Simon, Arnold & White Panels: 2/6/02,
10/25/02
Dolmans, Maurits Partner, Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen & Hamilton,
Brussels
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Dreyfuss, Rochelle C. Pauline Newman Professor of Law, New
York University School of Law
Panels: 7/10/02,
7/11/02
Duffy, John F. Associate Professor of Law, William &
Mary Marshall-Wythe School of Law
Panels: 7/10/02,
10/30/02
Submission:
7/10/02
Earp, David J. Vice President of Intellectual Property,
Geron Corp.
Panel: 2/26/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS130
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Egan, James J. Senior Vice President, Novirio
Pharmaceuticals
Panel: 5/2/02
Ellis, Mark Public Comments
Ellis, The Honorable
T.S., III
Judge, U.S. District Court for the Eastern
District of Virginia
Panel: 7/11/02
Ergas, Henry Managing Director, Network Economics
Consulting Group Pty Ltd, Australia
Panels: 5/22/02,
5/23/02
Submissions:
5/22/02, 5/23/02
Evenson, Robert E. Professor of Economics, Yale University Panel: 2/20/02
Submission:
2/20/02
Farrell, Joseph Professor of Economics and Chair of the
Competition Policy Center, University of
California, Berkeley
Panels: 2/28/02,
5/14/02, 11/6/02
Submissions:
2/28/02
5/14/02
Feinstein, Richard A. Partner, Boies, Schiller & Flexner LLP Panel: 5/02/02
Submission:
5/02/02
Fine, Frank Partner, DLA Public Comments
Forrester, Ian S. Executive Partner, White & Case LLP,
Brussels; Visiting Professor, University of
Glasgow
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Fox, Stephen P. Associate General Counsel and Director,
Intellectual Property, Hewlett-Packard
Company
Panel: 2/28/02
Submission:
2/28/02
Frankel, Kenneth M. Partner, Finnegan, Henderson, Farabow,
Garrett & Dunner LLP; Chairman, Antitrust
Law Committee, Intellectual Property Law
Association
Panel: 4/10/02
Submission:
4/10/02
Friedman, Bradford L. Director of Intellectual Property, Candence
Design Systems, Inc.
Panel: 2/27/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 131
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Fromm, Jeffery Senior Managing Counsel, Hewlett-Packard
Company
Panels: 4/17/02
11/6/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Futa, Baryn S. Manager and Chief Executive Officer,
MPEG LA, LLC
Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Gable, R. Lewis Partner, Cowan, Liebowitz & Latman, P.C. Panel: 3/20/02
Gambrell, James B. Visiting Professor, The University of Texas
School of Law
Panel: 10/25/02
Garner, Melvin C. Partner, Darby & Darby; Second Vice
President, American Intellectual Property
Law Association
Panel: 10/25/02
Gellhorn, Ernest Professor of Law, George Mason University
School of Law
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Gifford, Daniel J. Robins, Kaplan, Miller & Ciresi Professor of
Law, University of Minnesota School of
Law
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Gilbert, Richard J. Professor of Economics, University of
California, Berkeley
Panels: 2/6/02,
2/25/02
Submissions:
2/6/02, 2/25/02
Gleklen, Jonathan I. Partner, Arnold & Porter Panel: 5/1/02
Submission: 5/1/02
Glover, Gregory J. Partner, Ropes & Gray, Counsel to
Pharmaceutical Research & Manufacturers
of America
Panel: 3/19/02
Submission:
3/19/02
Gordon, George G. Partner, Dechert Panel: 7/11/02
Submission:
7/11/02
Greenhall, R. Jordan Co-founder and Chief Executive Officer,
DivX Networks
Panel: 2/27/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS132
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Greenstein, Shane
Mitchell
Elinor and Wendall Hobbs Professor,
Kellogg School of Management,
Northwestern University
Panel: 2/20/02
Submission:
2/20/02
Griffin, Thomas
(with Colin Crossman,
David Silverstein &
Mark Webbink)
Student, Duke University School of Law Public Comments
Grindley, Peter Senior Managing Economist, LECG, Ltd.,
London
Panels: 4/17/02,
4/18/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Guerin-Calvert,
Margaret E.
Principal, Economists, Inc. Panel: 2/20/02
Submission:
2/20/02
Hall, Bronwyn H. Professor of Economics, University of
California, Berkeley
Panel: 2/26/02,
2/28/02
Submission:
2/26/02
Harris, H. Stephen, Jr. Partner, Alston & Bird LLP Panel: 5/23/02
Submission:
5/23/02
Hart, Leslie J. Vice President of Intellectual Property,
Harris Corp.
Panel: 4/9/02
Hayes-Rines, Joanne
M.
Vice President, United Investors
Association
Panel: 3/19/02
Hoerner, Robert J. Former Partner, Jones, Day, Reavis & Pogue Panel: 7/11/02
Submission:
7/11/02
Holleman, Richard J. Industry Standards Consultant; Treasurer,
IEEE Standards Association
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02 Public
Comments
Hollis, Aidan
(with John R. Boyce)
Associate Professor, Department of
Economics, University of Calgary
Public Comments
Horton, Thomas J. Partner, Orrick, Herrington & Sutcliffe LLP Public Comments
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 133
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Hughes, James W.
(with Edward A.
Snyder & Michael J.
Moore)
Associate Professor, Economics
Department, Bates College
Public Comments
Hughes, Justin Visiting Professor of Law, University of
California, Los Angeles
Panel: 2/28/06
Hull, David W. Partner, Covington & Burling, Brussels Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Hunt, Robert M. Economist, Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Public Comments
Institute of Electrical
and Electronics
Engineers, Inc.
Public Comments
Intellectual Property
Owners Association
Public Comments
Jacobson, Jonathan M. Partner, Akin, Gump, Strauss, Hauer &
Feld, LLP
Panel: 5/14/02
Submission:
5/14/02
James, Charles Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust,
U.S. Department of Justice
Speech: 2/6/02
Submission: 2/6/02
Janis, Mark D. Professor of Law, University of Iowa
College of Law
Panels: 4/10/02,
4/11/02, 5/22/02
Japan Fair Trade
Commission
Submission:
5/23/02
Jorda, Karl F. David Rines Professor of Intellectual
Property Law and Industrial Innovation,
Franklin Pierce Law Center
Panel: 5/23/02
Kahin, Brian Director, Center for Information Policy,
Visiting Professor, College of Information
Studies, University of Maryland
Panels: 3/19/02,
4/11/02, 10/25/02,
10/30/02
Submissions:
3/19/02, 4/11/02
Public Comments
Kantor, David A.
(with Sal Racciardi)
President, Victory Wholesale Grocers Public Comments
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS134
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Kaplan, Joshua President and Chief Executive Officer,
Founder Intouch Group, Inc.
Panel: 2/27/02
Katsh, Salem M. Partner, Shearman & Sterling Panels: 4/10/02,
5/14/02
Submissions:
4/10/02, 5/14/02
Kattan, Joseph Partner, Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher Panels: 5/14/02,
11/6/02
Submission:
5/14/02
Katz, Ronald S.
(with Adam J. Safer)
Antitrust Litigator, Coudert Bros. Public Comments
Kelly, Christopher J. Special Counsel, Litigation Department,
Kaye Scholer LLP
Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Kesan, Jay P. Assistant Professor of Law, University of
Illinois College of Law
Panels: 4/10/02,
10/25/02
Submission:
4/10/02
Kieff, F. Scott John M. Olin Senior Research Fellow in
Law, Economics and Business, Harvard
Law School; Associate Professor of Law,
Washington University School of Law
Panel: 4/10/02
Public Comments
Kim, Byungbae Competition Policy Counselor and Director
General, Korean Fair Trade Commission
Panel: 5/23/02
Submission:
5/23/02
Kirsch, Paul F. Partner, Townsend and Townsend and
Crew LLP
Panel: 5/1/02
Submission: 5/1/02
Kirschner, Michael K. Vice President for Intellectual Property,
Immunex Corp.
Panel: 2/26/02
Kitch, Edmund W. Joseph M. Hatfield Professor of Law,
University of Virginia School of Law;
Visiting Professor, Georgetown University
Law Center
Panels: 2/20/02,
10/30/02
Klein, Benjamin Professor of Economics, University of
California Los Angeles
Panel: 5/1/02
Submission: 5/1/02
Kobak, James B., Jr. Partner, Hughes Hubbard & Reed LLP Panel: 7/11/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 135
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Kohn, Robert H. Vice Chairman and Director, Borland
Software Corp.
Panel: 2/27/02
Konovalov, Zoe Public Comments
Kovacic, William E. General Counsel, Federal Trade
Commission
Panel: 2/8/02
Submission: 2/8/02
Koyanagi, Masayuki Director, Institute of Intellectual Property,
JETRO
Panel: 5/23/02
Submission:
5/23/02
Kuester, Jeffrey R.
(with Lawrence E.
Thompson)
Partner, Thomas, Kayden, Horstemeyer &
Risley, LLP
Panel: 4/11/02
Public Comments
Kulbaski, James J. Partner, Oblon, Spivak, McClelland, Maier
& Neustadt, P.C.
Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Public Comments
Kunin, Stephen G. Deputy Commissioner for Patent
Examination Policy, U.S. Patent and
Trademark Office
Panels: 4/10/02,
7/10/02, 7/11/02
Kushan, Jeffrey P. Partner, Powell, Goldstein, Frazer &
Murphy, LLP; currently Partner, Sidley
Austin Brown & Wood LLP
Panels: 4/11/02,
10/25/02
Submission:
4/11/02
Lang, John Temple Counsel, Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen &
Hamilton, Brussels; Visiting Professor,
Trinity College; Senior Research Fellow,
Oxford
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Langenfeld, James A. Director, LECG, LLC Panel: 2/20/02
Submission:
2/20/02
League for
Programming
Freedom
Public Comments
Leavy, James Member, Serra Leavy & Cazals Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Lee, Rusty Small Business Owner and Professional
Software Developer
Public Comments
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS136
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Leggett, Nickolaus E. Independent Inventor and U.S. patent
holder
Public Comments
Lemley, Mark Professor of Law and Director, Berkeley
Center for Law & Technology, Boalt Hall
School of Law, University of California,
Berkeley; Of Counsel, Keker & Van Nest
Panels: 2/25/02,
4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Lennros, Hans Public Comments
Lerner, Josh Jacob H. Schiff Professor of Investment
Banking, Harvard Business School
Panels: 2/20/02,
4/17/02
Submissions:
2/20/02, 4/17/02
Public Comments
Levin, Jonathan D. Assistant Professor of Economics, Stanford
University; National Fellow, Hoover
Institution
Panel: 10/25/02
Levin, Richard C. President, Yale University Panel: 2/6/02
Submission: 2/6/02
Public Comments
Liebowitz, Stan Professor of Managerial Economics, School
of Management, The University of Texas at
Dallas
Panel: 2/20/02
Submission:
2/20/02
Linck, Nancy J. Senior Vice President, General Counsel and
Secretary, Guilford Pharmaceuticals
Panels: 4/9/02,
10/25/02
Lipsky, Abbott B., Jr. Partner, Latham & Watkins Panels: 5/14/02,
5/23/02
Submission:
5/14/02
Liu, Dr. Len-yu Commissioner, Taiwan Fair Trade
Commission
Panel: 5/23/02
Submission:
5/23/02
Lo, Allen M. Director of Intellectual Property, Juniper
Networks, Inc.
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Love, James Director, Consumer Project on Technology Panel: 3/19/02
Submission:
3/19/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 137
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Love, John J. Director, Technology Center 2100, U.S.
Patent and Trademark Office
Panels: 2/27/02,
2/28/02
Submission:
2/27/02
Lunney, Glynn S., Jr. Professor of Law, Tulane Law School Panel: 7/10/02
Submission:
7/10/02
MacKie-Mason,
Jeffrey K.
Arthur W. Burks Professor of Information
and Computer Science, Professor of
Economics and Public Policy, University of
Michigan
Panel: 5/01/02
Submission:
5/01/02
Maebius, Stephen B. Partner, Foley & Lardner Panel: 4/11/02
Submission:
4/11/02
Marasco, Amy A. Vice President and General Counsel,
American National Standards Institute
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Mar-Spinola, Julie Chief Litigation and Intellectual Property
Counsel, Atmel Corporation
Panel: 2/28/02
Maskin, Eric
(with James Bessen)
Harvard University and Massachusetts
Institute of Technology
Public Comments
McCurdy, Daniel President and Chief Executive Officer,
ThinkFire
Panel: 3/20/02
McFalls, Michael Associate, Jones Day Reavis & Pogue Panel: 11/06/02
McGarey, Barbara M. Chief Counsel, National Institutes of Health Panel: 11/06/02
McGowan, David Associate Professor of Law, University of
Minnesota Law School
Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Mehta, Kirtikumar Director, Directorate General for
Competition, European Commission
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Mejia, Luis Senior Associate, Office of Technology
Licensing, Stanford University
Panel: 2/27/02
Melamed, A. Douglas Partner, Wilmer, Cutler & Pickering Panels: 5/01/02,
5/14/02
Submission: 5/1/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS138
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Merges, Robert P. Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati
Distinguished Professor of Law and
Technology, Boalt Hall School of Law;
Director, Berkeley Center for Law and
Technology, University of California,
Berkeley
Panels: 2/26/02,
2/28/02
Submissions:
2/26/02, 2/28/02
Merrill, Stephen A. Executive Director, Board on Science
Technology and Economic Policy, National
Research Council/National Academy of
Sciences
Panels: 10/25/02,
10/30/02
Microsoft Corporation Public Comments
Miller, Joseph Scott Assistant Professor, Lewis & Clark Law
School
Panel: 5/14/02
Submission:
5/14/02
Misener, Paul Vice President, Global Public Policy,
Amazon.com
Panel: 2/27/02
Mitchell, John T. Partner, Seyfarth Shaw LLP Public Comments
Moltenbrey, M.J. Partner, Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer Panel: 5/14/02
Moore, Michael J.
(with Edward A.
Snyder & James W.
Hughes)
Bank of America Research Professor of
Business Administration, Darden School,
University of Virginia
Public Comments
Moree, Jeremiah T. PC Xperience Public Comments
Morgan, Paul F. Public Comments
Morse, M. Howard Partner, Drinker, Biddle & Reath, LLP Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Mossinghoff, Gerald J. Senior Counsel, Oblon Spivak, McClelland,
Maier & Neustadt; Visiting Professor of
Intellectual Property, The George
Washington School of Law
Panels: 2/6/02,
10/30/02
Submission: 2/6/02
Public Comments
Mowery, David C. Milton W. Terrill Professor of Business, and
Director of the Haas School of Business
Ph.D. Program, University of California,
Berkeley
Panel: 2/27/02
Muris, Timothy Chairman, Federal Trade Commission Speech: 2/6/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 139
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Musacchia, Mary U. Counsel to the President/CEO and
Director, Government Relations & Public
Policy, SAS Institute Inc.
Panel: 4/9/02
Submission: 4/9/02
Public Comments
Myrick, Ronald Chief Patent Counsel, General Electric;
President-Elect, American Intellectual
Property Law Association; President,
Monogram Licensing, Inc.
Panels: 3/19/02,
10/30/02
Submission:
3/19/02
Nelson, Philip B. Principal, Economists, Inc. Panel: 2/20/02
Submission:
2/20/02
Newberg, Joshua A. Assistant Professor, Robert H. Smith School
of Business, University of Maryland
Panels: 4/17/02,
5/23/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Newman, The
Honorable Pauline
Judge, U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal
Circuit
Panel: 2/6/02
Nydegger, Rick D. Shareholder, Workman, Nydegger &
Seeley; First Vice President, American
Intellectual Property Association
Panels: 2/27/02,
4/11/02
Submissions:
2/27/02, 4/11/02
O’Brien, Vincent E. Director, LECG, LLC Public Comments
Oehler, Ross Vice President, U.S. Patent Operations,
Aventis Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
Panel: 2/26/02
Olshove, DonPaul Public Comments
Ordover, Janusz A. Professor of Economics, New York
University
Panels: 2/20/02,
11/6/02
Submission:
2/20/02
O’Rourke, Maureen A. Professor of Law, Boston University School
of Law
Panel: 2/20/02
Open GIS
Consortium, Inc.
Public Comments
Parkhurst, Roger W. Partner, Parkhurst & Wendel, LLP;
President, American Intellectual Property
Law Association
Panel: 4/10/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS140
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Patterson, Mark R. Associate Professor of Law, Fordham
University School of Law
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Peterson, Scott K. Corporate Counsel for Intellectual Property,
Hewlett-Packard Company; Chair,
American National Standards Institute
Patent Committee
Panels: 4/18/02,
11/6/02
Submissions:
4/18/02, 11/6/02
Pharmaceutical
Research and
Manufacturers of
America
Public Comments
Pitofsky, Robert Professor of Law, Georgetown University
Law Center; Member, Board of Directors,
American Intellectual Property Association
Panel: 2/6/02
Public Comments
Place, John Executive Director, Center for Internet and
Society, Stanford University Law School
Panel: 2/27/02
Pooley, James Partner, Milbank, Tweed, Hadley & McCoy Panels: 2/27/02,
10/30/02
Poppen, Joel Director, Patent Litigation and Licensing,
Micron Technology, Inc.
Panel: 2/28/02
Potter, Robert Chief, Legal Policy Section, Antitrust
Division, U.S. Department of Justice
Speech: 4/17/02
Pritchard, Thomas, Sr. Digital Video Yellow Pages Public Comments
Proger, Phillip A. Partner, Jones, Day, Reavis & Pogue Panel: 5/2/02
Prywes, Daniel I.
(with David A. Balto)
Partner, Pepper Hamilton LLP Public Comments
Putnam, Jonathan D. Assistant Professor of the Law and
Economics of Intellectual Property,
University of Toronto School of Law
Panel: 4/17/02
Submission:
4/17/02
Quillen, Cecil D., Jr. Senior Advisor, Cornerstone Research
Group
Panels: 3/19/02,
7/11/02
Submissions:
3/19/02, 7/11/02
Public Comments
Rai, Arti K. Assistant Professor of Law, University of
Pennsylvania Law School
Panel: 4/10/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 141
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Rapp, Richard T.
(with Lauren J. Stiroh)
President, National Economic Research
Associates
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Public Comments
Rey, Patrick Professor of Economics, University of
Tolouse, France, and Research Director,
Institut d’Economie Industrielle
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Rhoden, Desi President and Chief Executive Officer,
Advanced Memory International, Inc.
Panel: 2/28/02
Ricciardi, Sal
(with David Kantor)
President, Pharmaceutical Distributors
Association; President, Purity Wholesale
Grocers, Inc.
Public Comments
Riches, Robert M., Jr. Public Comments
Rill, James Partner and Co-Chair of the Antitrust
Practice Group, Howrey, Simon, Arnold &
White
Panel: 5/23/02
Rogan, James E. Undersecretary of Commerce for
Intellectual Property and Director of U.S.
Patent and Trademark Office
Panel: 2/6/02
Submission: 2/6/02
Public Comments
Rubinfeld, Daniel L. Robert L. Bridges Professor of Law, and
Professor of Economics, University of
California, Berkeley
Panel: 2/25/02
Rule, Charles F. (Rick) Partner, Fried, Frank, Harris, Shriver &
Jacobson
Panel: 11/6/02
Safer, Adam J.
(with Ronald S. Katz)
Miller & Wrubel P.C. Public Comments
Sander, Scott President, Chief Executive Officer and Co-
Founder, SightSound Technologies, Inc.
Panel: 3/20/02
Submission:
3/20/02
Saunders, Kurt M. Assistant Professor of Business Law,
California State University, Northridge
Public Comments
Scherer, F.M. Roy E. Larson Professor of Public Policy
and Management, Harvard University
Panel: 7/10/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS142
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Scotchmer, Suzanne Professor of Economics and Public Policy,
University of California, Berkeley
Panels: 2/26/02,
4/10/02
Submissions:
2/26/02, 4/10/02
Seide, Rochelle K. Partner, Baker Botts, LLP Panel: 3/19/02
Shapiro, Carl Transamerica Professor of Business
Strategy, Haas School of Business; Director
and Professor of Economics, Institute of
Business and Economic Research,
University of California, Berkeley
Panels: 2/27/02,
5/01/02, 5/02/02,
11/06/02
Submissions:
5/1/02, 5/2/02
Shelanski, Howard Acting Professor of Law, and Director,
Berkeley Center for Law & Technology,
University of California, Berkeley
Panel: 2/25/02
Sibley, David S. John Michael Stuart Professor of
Economics, University of Texas at Austin
Panel: 5/14/02
Submission:
5/14/02
Sidak, J. Gregory F.K. Weyerhaeuser Fellow in Law and
Economics Emeritus, American Enterprise
Institute
Panel: 5/14/02
Silverstein, David
(with Colin Crossman,
Thomas Griffin, &
Mark Webbink)
Student, Duke University School of Law Public Comments
Snyder, Edward A.
(with James W.
Hughes & Michael J.
Moore)
Dean and Professor of Economics,
University of Chicago Graduate School of
Business
Panel: 3/19/02
Submission:
3/19/02
Public Comments
Sobel, Gerald Partner, Kaye Scholer LLP Panel: 7/10/02
Public Comments
Sprigman,
Christopher J.
Counsel, King & Spalding Panel: 5/1/02
Submission: 5/1/02
Stack, Stephen A., Jr. Partner, Dechert Panel: 5/2/02
Submission: 5/2/02
Stallman, Richard President, Free Software Corp. Panel: 4/9/02
Public Comments
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 143
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Stiroh, Lauren J.
(with Richard T.
Rapp)
Vice President, National Economics
Research Associates
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Public Comments
Stoll, Robert L. Administrator for External Affairs, U.S.
Patent and Trademark Office
Panel: 4/11/02
Stoner, Robert D. Senior Vice President, Economists, Inc. Panels: 2/26/02,
10/30/02
Submission:
2/26/02
Sung, Lawrence M. Assistant Professor, University of Maryland
School of Law, Baltimore
Panels: 2/8/02,
4/17/02
Submissions:
2/8/02, 4/17/02
Swanson, Daniel G. Partner, Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Tada, Toshiaki Senior Associate, Hibiya Sogo; International
Legal Trainee, Weil, Gotshal & Manges LLP
Panel: 5/23/02
Taylor, Robert P. Partner, Howrey Simon Arnold & White
LLP
Panels: 2/27/02,
7/11/02, 10/25/02
Submissions:
2/27/02, 7/11/02
Teece, David J. Mitsubishi Bank Professor of International
Business and Finance, Haas School of
Business, University of California, Berkeley
Panels: 2/26/02,
2/27/02, 4/18/02
Submissions:
2/26/02, 2/27/02
Telecky, Frederick J.,
Jr.
Senior Vice President and General Patent
Counsel, Texas Instruments, Inc.
Panel: 2/28/02
Submission: 6/3/02
Public Comments
Thomas, John R. Associate Professor of Law, The George
Washington University School of Law;
Professor of Law, Georgetown University
Law Center; Visiting Researcher,
Congressional Research Service; Instructor,
U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, Patent
Academy
Panels: 2/8/02,
4/10/02, 4/11/02,
10/25/02, 10/30/02
Submissions:
2/8/02, 4/11/02
Thompson, Earle Intellectual Asset Manager and Senior
Counsel, Texas Instruments, Inc.
Panel: 11/6/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS144
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Thompson, Lawrence
E.
(with Jeffery R.
Kuester)
Associate, Thomas, Kayden, Horstemeyer
& Risley, LLP
Public Comments
Thompson, Mozelle
W.
Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission Panel: 2/25/02
Submission:
2/25/02
Thurston, Richard L. Vice President and General Counsel,
Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing
Company, Ltd.
Panel: 3/20/02
Submission:
3/20/02
Tom, Willard K. Partner, Morgan, Lewis & Bockius, LLP Panels: 2/8/02,
5/22/02
Submission: 2/8/02
Udell, Lawrence J. Executive Director, California Invention
Center, the Center for New Venture
Alliance and Intellectual Property
International
Panel: 2/28/02
Submission:
2/28/02
United States Council
for International
Business
Public Comments
Updegrove, Andrew Partner, Lucash, Gesmer & Updegrove, LLP Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Varian, Hal R. Dean, School of Information Management
and Systems; Professor, Haas School of
Business and Department of Economics,
University of California, Berkeley
Panel: 2/25/02
Submission:
2/25/02
Venit, James S. Partner, Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher &
Flom, LLP, Brussels
Panel: 5/22/02
Submission:
5/22/02
Vishny, Paul Member, D’Ancona & Pflaum, LLC;
General Counsel, Telecommunications
Industry Association
Panel: 11/6/02
Vistnes, Gregory Vice President, Charles River Associates Panel: 5/14/02
Submission:
5/14/02
Wamsley, Herbert C. Executive Director, Intellectual Property
Owners Association
Panel: 7/10/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS 145
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Webbink, Mark
(with Colin Crossman,
Thomas Griffin, &
David Silverstein)
Senior Vice President, General Counsel and
Secretary, Red Hat, Inc.
Panel: 3/20/02
Public Comments
Weil, Matthew F. Partner, McDermott, Will & Emery Panel: 7/11/02
Submission:
7/11/02
Weinstein, Les J. Partner, Squire, Sanders & Dempsey Panel: 2/27/02
Submission:
2/27/02
Weitzner, Daniel J. Director of Technology and Society
Activities, World Wide Web Consortium
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Public Comments
Weller, Charles D. Law Offices of Charles D. Weller Public Comments
White, Lawrence J. Arthur E. Imperatore Professor of
Economics, Leonard N. Stern School of
Business, New York University
Panel: 2/20/06
Submission:
2/20/06
Whitener, Mark D. Antitrust and General Counsel, General
Electric
Panel: 5/1/02
Submission: 5/1/02
Widge, Alik Technology Researcher and Medical
Professional
Public Comments
Wiley, John Shepard,
Jr.
Professor of Law, University of California,
Los Angeles
Panel: 5/1/02
Submission: 5/1/02
Willingmyre, George
T.
President, GTW Associates Public Comments
Wolin, Harry Vice President of Intellectual Property,
Advanced Micro Devices, Inc.
Panel: 3/20/02
Submission:
3/20/02
Yao, Dennis A. Associate Professor of Business and Public
Policy, The Wharton School, University of
Pennsylvania
Panel: 4/18/02
Submission:
4/18/02
Young, Robert Chairman, Center for Public Domain;
Chairman, Red Hat, Inc.
Panel: 4/11/02
Zanfagna, Gary Associate General Counsel for Antitrust,
Honeywell International
Panel: 3/20/02
APPENDIX A: HEARINGS PARTICIPANTS146
Name Affiliation (at time of Hearings)
Ziedonis, Rosemarie Assistant Professor of Management, The
Wharton School, University of
Pennsylvania
Panel: 3/20/02
Submission:
3/20/02
147
APPENDIX B
HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS
Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Economy February 6 - November 6, 2002
Primary source: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/index.htm
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Aharonian, Greg Statistics on Prior Art Citations for
U.S. Computing Patents
2/27/02
Allen, Gwillym Canadian Intellectual Property
Enforcement Guidelines
5/22/02
Anderman, Steve Microsoft in Europe 5/22/02
Arora, Ashish Patents, R&D and Market for
Technology
Refusal to License: A Transaction
Approach
Refusal to License: A Transaction
Based Perspective
2/25/02
5/1/02
5/1/02
Arrow, Kenneth J. Untitled 2/25/02
Baker, Charles P. Statement 7/11/02
Barr, Robert Untitled 2/28/02
Barton, John H. Patents and Antitrust Emerging
Paradigms
2/26/02
Beeney, Garrard R. Pro-Competitive Aspects of
Intellectual Property Pools: A
Proposal for Safe Harbor Provisions
4/17/02
Beier, David Testimony of the Biotechnology
Industry Organization
2/26/02
Besen, Stanley M. Standard Setting and Intellectual
Property: An Outline of the Issues
4/18/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS148
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Bhaskar, R. Antitrust Law in the Federal Circuit:
Conflict in the Public Purpose
7/11/02
Black, Edward J. Testimony 3/20/02
Brodley, Joseph F. Joseph F. Brodley & Maureen
O’Rourke, Patent Settlement
Agreements: Preliminary Thoughts
Questions for FTC/DOJ IP and
Antitrust Patent Settlement Hearing
5/2/02
5/2/02
Brunt, George B. Alcatel Company Presentation 3/20/02
Burk, Dan L. Dan L. Burk & Mark Lemley, Is Patent
Law Technology Specific?
Patent Disclosure Doctrines
3/20/02
7/10/02
Busey, Roxane C. SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW,
AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, REPORT
ON THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
APPEALS FOR THE FEDERAL CIRCUIT
(2002).
Untitled
7/11/02
7/11/02
Cargill, Carl Intellectual Property Rights and
Standards Setting Organizations: An
Overview of Failed Evolution
4/18/02
Carlin, Fiona The EU Committee, American
Chamber of Commerce in Belgium,
Position Paper on the Commission’s
Review of the Technology Transfer
Block Exemption, Regulation 240/96
Review of the Block Exemption on
Technology Transfer
5/22/02
5/22/02
Cary, George S. Antitrust Implications of Patent
Settlements
5/2/02
Caulfield, Barbara A. Business Perspectives on Patents:
Biotech and Pharmaceuticals
3/19/02
Chambers, Scott A. M. Patenting Procedures 2/8/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS 149
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Chin, Yee Wah ABA Comments on EC Evaluation
Report on TTBE
Yee Wah Chin & Thomas G.
Krattenmaker, Antitrust Update,
MERGERS & ACQUISITIONS, December
2001, at 30.
COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN
COMMUNITIES, COMMISSION
EVALUATION REPORT ON THE TRANSFER
OF TECHNOLOGY B LOCK EXEMPTION
REGULATION NO. 240/96:
TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER AGREEMENTS
UNDER ARTICLE 81
Section of Antitrust Law, Section of
International Law and Practice,
Section of Intellectual Property Law,
American Bar Association, Joint
Comments on the Commission
Evaluation Report on the Transfer of
Technology Block Exemption
Regulation No. 240/96 Technology
Transfer Agreements Under Article 81
Unilateral Technology Suppression:
Appropriate Antitrust and Patent Law
Remedies, 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 441 (1998).
5/22/02
5/22/02
5/22/02
5/22/02
5/22/02
Cohen, Wesley M. Patents: Their Effectiveness and Role 2/20/02
Cook, Robert N. A Competition View of Patent
Settlements: Settling Patent Disputes
by Merger: Some Antitrust
Considerations
5/2/02
Detkin, Peter N. A Semiconductor Patent Survey 2/28/02
Deutsch, Donald Statement on Intellectual Property
Strategy in Standards Activity
4/18/02
Dick, Rebecca Extending the Useful Life of
Intellectual Property: Antitrust Risks
and Safety Zones
5/14/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS150
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Dolmans, Maurits EU Standardization: IPR Policies and
RAND Licensing
Standards for Standards
5/22/02
5/22/02
Duffy, John F. Nonobviousness: The Economics and
Legal Process of the Doctrine
7/10/02
Ergas, Henry Intellectual Property Rights &
Competition Law
Treatment of Unilateral Refusals to
License and Compulsory Licensing in
Australia
5/22/02
5/22/02
Evenson, Robert E. IPRs and Innovation 2/20/02
Farrell, Joseph Competition and IP
Incentives to Challenge IP
IP Bundling and Antitrust
2/28/02
5/14/02
5/14/02
Feinstein, Richard A. Per Se Antitrust Risks in Hatch-
Waxman Agreements
5/2/02
Forrester, Ian S. Compulsory Licensing in Europe: A
Rare Cure to Aberrant National
Intellectual Property Rights?
5/22/02
Fox, Stephen P. Opening Statement 2/28/02
Fromm, Jeffery Patent Pools and Cross-Licensing 4/17/02
Futa, Baryn S. Statement 4/17/02
Gellhorn, Ernest Standard-Setting 4/18/02
Gifford, Daniel J. Standards and Intellectual Property:
Licensing Terms: Some Comments
4/18/02
Gilbert, Richard The Evolution of Guidelines
Should Innovation Have a Role in
Merger Policy?
2/6/02
2/25/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS 151
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Gleklen, Jonathan Antitrust Liability for Unilateral
Refusals to License Intellectual
Property: Xerox and Its Critics
Unilateral Refusals to License IP
5/1/02
5/1/02
Glover, Gregory J. PhRMA Statement: Competition in
the Pharmaceutical Marketplace
5/19/02
Gordon, George G. The Implications of Federal Circuit
Jurisdiction for the Development of
Antitrust Law
7/11/02
Greenstein, Shane Market Structure and Innovation: A
Brief Synopsis
2/20/02
Grindley, Peter IP, Cross-Licensing and Patent Pools:
Similarities and Contrasts
4/17/02
Guerin-Calvert, Margaret E. Competition and Innovation in the
Context of Network Economics
2/20/02
Hall, Bronwyn H. Patents and Innovation
Testimony
2/26/02
2/26/02
Harris, H. Stephen, Jr. Competition Law and Intellectual
Property Protection in Japan: A Half-
Century of Progress, a New
Millennium of Challenges
IP and Competition Law
Developments in Japan
5/23/02
5/23/02
Hoerner, Robert J.
The Decline (and Fall?) of the Patent
Misuse Doctrine in the Federal Circuit, 69
ANTITRUST L.J. 669 (2001).
Is Activity Within the Subsections of 35
U.S.C. § 271(d) Protected from a Finding
of Antitrust Violation?, 74 J. PATENT &
TRADEMARK OFFICE S OCIETY 283 (1992).
Patent Misuse
Patent Misuse: Portents for the 1990s, 59
ANTITRUST L.J. 687 (1991).
7/11/02
7/11/02
7/11/02
7/11/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS152
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Holleman, Richard J. A Response: Government Guidelines
Should Not Be Issued in Connection
with Standards Setting
Comments on Standards Setting and
Intellectual Property
4/18/02
4/18/02
Hull, David W. The IMS Case: A Comparative
Perspective
David W. Hull, James R. Atwood &
James B. Perrine, Intellectual Property:
Compulsory Licensing, EUROPEAN
ANTITRUST REV. (2002).
5/22/02
5/22/02
Jacobson, Jonathan M. Counseling in Uncertainty: The Law
of Tying & Intellectual Property
Did the Per Se Rule on Tying Survive
‘Microsoft’?, previously published as:
Jonathan M. Jacobson & Abid Qureshi,
Did the Per Se Rule on Tying Survive
‘Microsoft’?, 226 N.Y.L.J. 1 (2001).
5/14/02
5/14/02
James, Charles Opening Day Comments 2/6/02
Japan Fair Trade Commission
2002 Study Group on “Patents
in New Areas and Competition
Policy”
Untitled 5/23/02
Kahin, Brian Presentation
What are Business Methods?
3/19/02
4/11/02
Katsh, Salem M. Presentation
Presentation
4/10/02
5/14/02
Kattan, Joseph Evaluating Patent Infringement and
Validity in Antitrust Analysis
5/14/02
Kelly, Christopher J. Patent Pools and Antitrust
Enforcement – 1997-2001
4/17/02
Kesan, Jay P. Toward a Better Informed Patent
System
4/10/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS 153
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Kim, Byungbae Korean Competition Policy with
Regard to Intellectual Property Rights
5/23/02
Kirsch, Paul F. Refusals to License IP – The
Perspective of the Private Plaintiff
5/1/02
Klein, Benjamin Antitrust and IP: What the Feds
Should Do About Refusals to Deal
5/1/02
Kovacic, William E. Antitrust Law for Intellectual Property
Attorneys
2/8/02
Koyanagi, Masayuki Japanese Perspective on Relationship
Between IP and Antitrust
5/23/02
Kulbaski, James J. Comments on Patent Pools and
Standards for Federal Trade
Commission Hearings Regarding
Competition & Intellectual Property
4/17/02
Kushan, Jeff Examination Reforms as a Means of
Improving Patent Quality
4/11/02
Lang, John Temple Compulsory Licensing of Intellectual
Property in European Community
Antitrust Law
5/22/02
Langenfeld, James Innovation, Competition, and
Intellectual Property: Providing an
Economic Framework
2/20/02
Leavy, James LESI European Committee, Comments
on the Commission Document:
“Evaluation Report on the Transfer of
Technology Block Exemption
Regulation No. 240/96”
The Technology Transfer Block
Exemption
5/22/02
5/22/02
Lemley, Mark A. Intellectual Property Rights and
Standard Setting Organizations
4/18/02
Lerner, Josh Into the Patent Thicket
Patent Pools: Some Policy
Considerations
2/20/02
4/17/02
Liebowitz, Stan Untitled 2/20/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS154
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Lipsky, Abbott B., Jr. “Amateurs in Black” 5/14/02
Liu, Len-yu The CD Product Patent Licensing
Practices in Taiwan Were in Violation
of the Fair Trade Law
5/23/02
Lo, Allen M. A Need For Intervention: Keeping
Competition Alive in the Networking
Industry in the Face of Increasing
Patent Assertions Against Standards
4/18/02
Love, James Perspectives on Competition and
Intellectual Property Law and Policy
in the Knowledge-Based Economy
3/19/02
Love, John J. Steps Taken to Improve Patent Quality 2/27/02
Lunney, Glynn S., Jr. Patents, the Federal Circuit, and the
Simply Property Perspective
7/10/02
MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K. What to Do About Refusals to License?
What to Do About Unilateral Refusals
to License?
5/1/02
5/1/02
Maebius, Stephen Opening Remarks 4/11/02
Marasco, Amy A. Standards-Setting Practices:
Competition, Innovation and
Consumer Welfare
4/18/02
McGowan, David Enforcement Issues Regarding Pooling
and Cross-Licensing
Enforcement Issues Regarding Pooling
and Cross-Licensing (slides)
4/17/02
4/17/02
Mehta, Kirtikumar Licensing of Intellectual Property
Under EU Competition Rules: The
Review of the Technology Transfer
Block Exemption Regulation
5/22/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS 155
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Melamed, A. Douglas A. Douglas Melamed & Ali M.
Stoeppelwerth, The CSU Case: Facts,
Formalism and the Intersection
of Antitrust and Intellectual Property
Law (April 11, 2002), subsequently
published as: A. Douglas Melamed &
Ali M. Stoppelworth, The CSU Case:
Facts, Formalism and the Intersection of
Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law,
10 GEORGE MASON L. REV . 407 (2002).
5/1/02
Merges, Robert P. Second Order Patent Scope
Patent Standards and Procedures:
Literature Summary and Discussion of
Prospects
2/26/02
2/28/02
Miller, Joseph Scott This Bitter Has Some Sweet: Antitrust
Enforcement Benefits from Patent
Law’s Procedural Rules
5/14/02
Morse, M. Howard Cross-Licensing and Patent Pools 4/17/02
Mossinghoff, Gerald J. Statement 2/6/02
Musacchia, Mary U. Prepared Remarks 4/9/02
Myrick, Ronald Testimony 3/19/02
Nelson, Philip Relationships Between Market
Structure and Innovation
2/20/02
Newberg, Joshua A.
Antitrust, Patent Pools, and the
Management of Uncertainty, 3 ATLANTIC
L.J. 1 (2000).
4/17/02
Nydegger, Rick D. Comments
Comments
2/27/02
4/11/02
Ordover, Janusz A. Antitrust for the New Economy or
New Economics for Antitrust
2/20/02
Patterson, Mark R. Inventions, Industry Standards, and
Intellectual Property
4/18/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS156
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Peterson, Scott K. Patents and Standard-Setting
Processes
Consideration of Patents During the
Setting of Standards
4/18/02
11/6/02
Putnam, Jonathan D. The Regulation of Patent Pools 4/17/02
Quillen, Cecil D., Jr. Statement
Testimony Notes
3/19/02
7/11/02
Rapp, Richard T. Richard T. Rapp & Lauren J. Stiroh,
Standard Setting and Market Power
4/18/02
Rey, Patrick Economics of Compulsory Licensing
Patrick Rey & Jean Tirole, A Primer on
Foreclosure (February 21, 1997).
5/22/02
5/22/02
Rogan, James E. Prepared Remarks 2/6/02
Sander, Scott Prepared Remarks 3/20/02
Scotchmer, Suzanne Competition Policy and Innovation:
The Context of Cumulative Innovation
Cumulative Innovation: Breadth and
Standards for Protection
2/26/02
4/10/02
Shapiro, Carl
Competition Policy and Innovation
(Organisation for Econ. Co-operation
and Development, STI Working Paper
No. 2002/11, 2002).
Antitrust Limits to Patent Settlements
5/1/02
5/2/02
Sibley, David S. Long Term Contracts as Barriers to
Entry
5/14/02
Snyder, Edward A. Untitled 3/19/02
Sprigman, Christopher J. Unilateral Refusals to License IP:
Xerox and the Right to Exclude
5/1/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS 157
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Stack, Stephen A., Jr. Abbott Laboratories and Geneva
Pharmaceuticals, Inc., File No. 981-
0395: Comment on Proposed Consent
Order
Patent Settlements
5/2/02
5/2/02
Stiroh, Lauren J. Richard T. Rapp & Lauren J. Stiroh,
Standard Setting and Market Power
4/18/02
Stoner, Robert Intellectual Property and Innovation 2/26/02
Sung, Lawrence M. Scope and Enforcement of Patent
Rights
Greater Predictability May Result in
Patent Pools
Patent Pools and Cross Licensing
JEANNE CLARK, JOE PICCOLO, BRIAN
STANTON & KARIN TYSON, U.S. PATENT
& TRADEMARK OFFICE, PATENT POOLS:
A SOLUTION TO THE PROBLEM OF
ACCESS IN BIOTECHNOLOGY PATENTS?
(2000).
2/08/02
4/17/02
4/17/02
4/17/02
Swanson, Daniel G. Evaluating Market Power in
Technology Markets when Standards
Are Selected in Which Private Parties
Own Intellectual Property Rights
4/18/02
Taylor, Robert P. Presentation
Statement
2/27/02
7/11/02
Teece, David J. Intellectual Property, Valuation, and
Licensing
IP, Competition Policy, and
Enforcement Issues
2/26/02
2/27/02
Telecky, Frederick J., Jr. Statement 2/28/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS158
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Thomas, John R. Patent Law and Policy: An
Introduction
Intellectual Property Rights in
Computer Software and Business
Methods: A Skeptical View
2/8/02
4/11/02
Thompson, Mozelle W. Economic Perspectives on Intellectual
Property, Competition, and
Innovation
2/25/02
Thurston, Richard L. Business and Other Perspectives on
Real-World Experience with Patents
Competition and Intellectual Property
Law and Policy as It Relates to the
Semiconductor Foundry Industry
3/20/02
3/20/02
Tom, Willard K. Antitrust Law for IP Lawyers:
Agreements Under § 1 of the Sherman
Act
Antitrust for IP Lawyers: Mergers
2/8/02
2/8/02
Udell, Lawrence J. Untitled 2/28/02
Updegrove, Andrew Is There a Need for Government
Regulation of the Standard Setting
Process?: An Analysis of Underlying
Realities
Observations on the Current
Dynamics of Consortium Standard
Setting
Standard Setting and Consortium
Structures
4/18/02
4/18/02
4/18/02
Varian, Hal R. Intellectual Property, Competition and
Innovation: Some Partially-Baked
Ideas
2/25/02
Venit, James S. Intellectual Property and EC Antitrust:
Unilateral Refusals to License
5/22/02
APPENDIX B: HEARINGS SUBMISSIONS 159
Panelist Title Hearing Date
Vistnes, Gregory Bundling and Tying: Antitrust
Analysis in Markets with Intellectual
Property
Practical Issues in Intellectual Property
Investigations: Balancing Rules
Versus Discretion
5/14/02
5/14/02
Webbink, Mark Mark Webbink, Colin Crossman,
Thomas Griffin & David Silverstein,
Red Hat’s Comments to the Joint
FTC/DOJ Hearing on Competition
and Intellectual Property Law
3/20/02
Weil, Matthew F. Statement 7/11/02
Weinstein, Les J. Current Issues Involving the U.S.
Patent System and Competition:
Room for Improvement
Room for Improvement in the Patent
System: Enhancing Both Innovation
and Competition
2/27/02
2/27/02
Weitzner, Daniel J. Testimony 4/18/02
White, Lawrence J. Network Industries and Innovation 2/20/02
Whitener, Mark D. Statement 5/1/02
Wiley, John Shepard, Jr. Antitrust and IP: What the Feds
Should Do About Refusals to Deal
5/1/02
Wolin, Harry Standard Setting in the Semiconductor
Industry: Trends, Benefits and Anti-
competitive Concerns
3/20/02
Yao, Dennis A. Standard Setting Practices:
Competition, Innovation, and
Consumer Welfare
4/18/02
Ziedonis, Rosemarie The Role of Patents in Semiconductors:
Insights from Two Recent Studies
3/20/02
161
APPENDIX C
PUBLIC COMMENTS
Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Economy February 6 - November 6, 2002
Primary source: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/index.htm
Name Title
American Bar Association,
Section of Antitrust Law
Testimony (6/28/02)
REPORT ON THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE
FEDERAL CIRCUIT (2002).
THE E CONOMICS OF INNOVATION: A SURVEY (2002).
American Bar Association,
Section of Intellectual
Property Law
Statement of Robert P. Taylor (7/11/02)
American Intellectual
Property Law Association
(AIPLA)
AIPLA Testimony (4/10/02)
American National
Standards Institute (ANSI)
FTC/DOJ Hearings on the Implications of Competition and
Patent Law and Policy (11/14/02)
Arthur D. Little, Inc. Arthur D. Little Bio-Pharmaceutical Study Finds Significant
Link Between Innovation and Market-Based Drug Pricing
(5/09/02)
Executive Summary: Examining the Relationship Between
Market-Based Pricing and Bio-Pharmaceutical Innovation
(undated)
Aventis Pharmaceuticals,
Inc.
Comments of Dr. Nahed Ahmed (7/15/02)
Balto, David A., and
Daniel I. Prywes
Standard-Setting Disputes: The Need for Guidelines (undated)
Barnes, E. Bruce Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(4/15/02)
APPENDIX C: PUBLIC COMMENTS162
Name Title
Barton, John H. Reforming the Patent System, previously published as:
Reforming the Patent System, 287 SCIENCE 1933 (2000).
International Patent-Antitrust Principles: The United States-
European Balances (5/28/02)
Bessen, James, and Eric
Maskin
Sequential Innovation, Patents, and Imitation (1/00)
Boyce, John R., and Aidan
Hollis
Innovation, Imitation & Preliminary Injunctions in Patents
(5/02)
Buddington, Eric Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(11/29/02)
Carrier, Michael A. Unraveling the Patent-Antitrust Paradox, 150 UNIVERSITY OF
PENNSYLVANIA L. REV. 761 (2002).
Resolving the Patent-Antitrust Paradox Through Tripartite
Innovation (2002), subsequently published as: Resolving the
Patent-Antitrust Paradox Through Tripartite Innovation, 56
VANDERBILT L. REV. 1047 (2003).
Casamento, Gregory John FTC Hearings on Competition and Intellectual Property
(2/20/02)
Craft, James A. Comments Regarding Competition and Intellectual Property
(“Patent Pools and Cross-Licensing: When Do They Promote
or Harm Competition?”) (4/25/02)
Ellis, Mark Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(undated)
Fine, Frank NDC/IMS: A Logical Application of Essential Facilities
Doctrine (undated)
Holleman, Richard J. A Response: Government Guidelines Should Not Be Issued in
Connection with Standards Setting (undated)
Horton, Tom Patenting Our Lives and Our Genes: Where Does Congress
Stand in the Coming Clash? (undated)
Hughes, James W.,
Michael J. Moore, and
Edward A. Snyder
“Napsterizing” Pharmaceuticals: Access, Innovation, and
Consumer Welfare (undated)
APPENDIX C: PUBLIC COMMENTS 163
Name Title
Hunt, Robert M. Nonobviousness and the Incentive to Innovate: An Economic
Analysis of Intellectual Property Reform (3/99)
Patent Reform: A Mixed Blessing For the U.S. Economy?, BUSINESS
REV., Nov.-Dec. 1999, at 15.
Patentability, Industry Structure, and Innovation (8/01)
You Can Patent That? Are Patents on Computer Programs and
Business Methods Good for the New Economy?, BUS. REV., First
Quarter 2001, at 5.
Institute of Electrical and
Electronics Engineers, Inc.
Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(4/17/02)
Intellectual Property
Owners Association
Comments (11/15/02)
Kahin, Brian The Expansion of the Patent System: Politics and Political
Economy (12/31/00)
Comments (undated)
A Possible Higher Standard of Nonobviousness (undated)
Kantor, David A., and Sal
Ricciardi
Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property Law
in the Knowledge-Based Economy (5/10/02)
Katz, Ronald S., and
Adam J. Safer
Why is One Patent Court Deciding Antitrust Law for the Whole
Country? (undated)
Kieff , F. Scott Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property:
Summary of Proposed Testimony (12/20/01)
Konovalov, Zoe The Economics of Open Source Software (11/04/02)
Kuester, Jeffrey R., and
Lawrence E. Thompson
Risks Associated with Restricting Business Method and E-Commerce
Patents, 17 GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY L. REV. 657 (2001).
Kulbaski, James J. Comments on Patent Pools and Standards (1/02)
League for Programming
Freedom
Against Software Patents (2/28/91)
Lee, Rusty Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(3/24/02)
APPENDIX C: PUBLIC COMMENTS164
Name Title
Leggett, Nickolaus E. Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(2/13/02)
Lennros, Hans Question Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(1/12/02)
Lerner, Josh The Patent System and Competition (undated)
Levin, Richard C. Testimony (2/06/02)
Microsoft Corporation Statement of Dan Crouse (undated)
Mitchell, John T. Retailers of Intellectual Property: The Competitive Voice of
Consumers (7/02)
Moree, Jeremiah T. IP Law (1/28/02)
Morgan, Paul F. Personal Comments (undated)
Mossinghoff, Gerald J. Statement (2/06/02)
Musacchia, Mary U. Prepared Remarks (4/09/02)
O’Brien, Vincent E. Economics and Key Patent Damage Cases, 9 UNIVERSITY OF
BALTIMORE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY L.J. 1 (2000).
Olshove, DonPaul Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(4/25/02)
Open GIS Consortium,
Inc.
Intellectual Property Rights Policy of Open GIS Consortium,
Inc. (5/09/02)
Pharmaceutical Research
and Manufacturers of
America
Delivering on the Promise of Pharmaceutical Innovation: The
Need to Maintain Strong and Predictable Intellectual Property
Rights (4/22/02)
Pitofsky, Robert The Essential Facilities Doctrine Under United States Antitrust
Law (undated)
Pritchard, Thomas, Sr.
Untitled (9/20/02)
APPENDIX C: PUBLIC COMMENTS 165
Name Title
Quillen, Cecil D., Jr. Innovation and the U.S. Patent System Today (10/19/92)
Proposal for the Simplification and Reform of the United States
Patent System (1993), previously published as: Proposal for the
Simplification and Reform of the United States Patent System, 21
AIPLA Q.J. 189 (1993).
Testimony of Cecil D. Quillen, Jr. Presented at the Public
Hearing on the Standard of Nonobviousness at the United
States Patent and Trademark Office (7/20/94)
Patent Standards and Innovation (2/2/00)
The U.S. Patent System: Is it Broke? And Who Can Fix It if It
Is? (5/11/01)
Cecil D. Quillen, Jr. & Ogden H. Webster, Continuing Patent
Applications and Performance of the U.S. Patent and Trademark
Office, 11 FEDERAL CIRCUIT BAR J. 1 (2001).
Innovators, Innovation, and the U.S. Patent System (10/17/02)
Cecil D. Quillen, Jr., Ogden H. Webster & Richard Eichmann,
Continuing Patent Applications and Performance of the U.S. Patent
Office – Extended, 12 FEDERAL CIRCUIT BAR J. 35 (2002).
Rapp, Richard T., and
Lauren J. Stiroh
Standard Setting and Market Power (4/18/02)
Ricciardi, Sal Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the
Knowledge-Based Economy, Pharmaceutical Distributors
Association (4/05/02)
Riches, Robert M., Jr. Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(undated)
Rogan, James E. Prepared Remarks (2/6/02)
Saunders, Kurt M.
Patent Nonuse and the Role of Public Interest as a Deterrent to
Technology Suppression, 15 HARVARD J.L. & TECHNOLOGY, Spring
2002, at 1.
Sobel, Gerald Patent Scope and Competition: Is the Federal Circuit’s
Approach Correct? (2001), subsequently published as: Patent
Scope and Competition: Is the Federal Circuit’s Approach Correct?, 7
VIRGINIA J.L. & TECHNOLOGY 3 (2002).
Stallman, Richard The Danger of Software Patents (3/25/02)
APPENDIX C: PUBLIC COMMENTS166
Name Title
Telecky, Frederick J., Jr. Statement (6/3/02)
United States Council for
International Business
Comments (7/12/02)
Webbink, Mark, Colin
Crossman, Thomas
Griffin, and David
Silverstein
Red Hat’s Comments to the Joint FTC/DOJ Hearing On
Competition and Intellectual Property Law (3/20/02)
Weitzner, Daniel J. Supplemental Comments (11/06/02)
W3C Patent Policy (2/5/04)
Weller, Charles D.
Daubert Sounds the Death Knell for Antitrust’s Merger Presumption
After Baby Foods, 1 EXPERT EVIDENCE REP. 168 (2001).
Harmonizing Antitrust Worldwide by Evolving to Michael Porter’s
Dynamic Productivity Growth Analysis, 46 ANTITRUST BULL. 879
(2001).
Patent Reform by Daubert Litigation, 2 EXPERT EVIDENCE REP. 232
(2002).
Widge, Alik Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(2/9/02)
Willingmyre, George T. Intellectual Property Rights Policies of Selected Standards
Developers (5/02)
Approaches to Influence the IPR Policies and Practices in US
and Global Standards Setting (6/14/02)
Comments Regarding Competition & Intellectual Property
(6/14/02)
Considerations in Assessing a Standards Developing
Organization’s Intellectual Property Rights Policies in Advance
of Participation (6/14/02)
167
APPENDIX D
HEARINGS TRANSCRIPTS
Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based
Economy February 6 - November 6, 2002
Primary source: http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/index.htm
February 6, 2002
Welcome and Overview of Hearings
February 8, 2002
Patent Law for Antitrust Lawyers (Morning Session)
Antitrust Law for Patent Lawyers (Afternoon Session)
February 20, 2002
Intellectual Property and Innovation (Morning Session)
Competition and Innovation (Afternoon Session)
February 25, 2002
Economic Perspectives on Intellectual Property, Competition, and Innovation
February 26, 2002
Economic Perspectives on Intellectual Property, Competition, and Innovation (Morning
Session)
Business Perspectives on Patents: Biotech and Pharmaceuticals (Afternoon Session)
February 27, 2002
Business Perspectives on Patents: Software and the Internet (Morning Session)
Diverse Perspectives on Patents (Afternoon Session)
February 28, 2002
Independent Inventor Perspective on Patents (Morning Session)
Economic and Other Perspectives on Patent Standards and Procedures (Morning Session)
Business Perspectives on Patents: Hardware and Semiconductors (Afternoon Session)
March 19, 2002
Diverse Perspectives on Patents (Morning Session)
Business Perspectives on Patents: Biotech and Pharmaceuticals (Afternoon Session)
March 20, 2002
Business Perspectives on Patents: Hardware and Semiconductors (Morning Session)
Business Perspectives on Patents: Software and the Internet (Afternoon Session)
April 9, 2002
Cross-Industry Perspectives on Patents
APPENDIX D: HEARINGS TRANSCRIPTS168
April 10, 2002
Substantive Standards of Patentability (Morning Session)
Patenting Procedures, Presumptions, and Uncertainties (Afternoon Session)
April 11, 2002
Patentable Subject Matter – Business Method and Software Patents (Morning Session)
Patent Criteria and Procedures – International Comparisons (Afternoon Session)
April 17, 2002
Patent Pools and Cross-Licensing: When Do They Promote or Harm Competition?
April 18, 2002
Intellectual Property Strategies in Standards Activities (Morning Session)
Licensing Terms in Standards Activities (Afternoon Session)
May 1, 2002
The Strategic Use of Licensing: Is There Cause for Concern About Unilateral Refusals to Deal?
May 2, 2002
A Competition View of Patent Settlements: Introductory Presentations (Morning Session)
A Competition View of Patent Settlements: Panel Discussion (Afternoon Session)
May 14, 2002
Antitrust Analysis of Specific Intellectual Property Licensing Practices: Bundling, Grantbacks
and Temporal Extensions (Morning Session)
Practical Issues Encountered in Antitrust Analysis of Licensing Practices: The Problem of
Dealing with Uncertain or Disputed Patent Rights (Afternoon Session)
May 22, 2002
Refusals to License and Compulsory Licensing in the European Union, Canada, and Australia
(Morning Session)
Licensing in the European Union: The Technology Transfer Block Exemption and Agreements
that Fall Outside Its Scope (Afternoon Session)
May 23, 2002
Asian Perspectives
July 10, 2002
Trends in Federal Circuit Jurisprudence (Morning Session)
Patent Law Analysis in Federal Circuit Jurisprudence (Afternoon Session)
July 11, 2002
Federal Circuit Jurisprudence: Jurisdiction, Choice of Law, and Competition Policy
Perspectives
October 25, 2002
Competition, Economic, and Business Perspectives on Patent Quality and Institutional Issues:
Competitive Concerns, Prior Art, Post-Grant Review, and Litigation
APPENDIX D: HEARINGS TRANSCRIPTS 169
October 30, 2002
Competition, Economic, and Business Perspectives on Substantive Patent Law Issues: Non-
Obviousness and Other Patentability Criteria
November 6, 2002
Standard Setting Organizations: Evaluating the Anticompetitive Risks of Negotiating IP
Licensing Terms and Conditions Before a Standard Is Set (Morning Session)
Relationships Among Competitors and Incentives to Compete: Cross-Licensing of Patent
Portfolios, Grantbacks, Reach-Through Royalties, and Non-Assertion Clauses
(Afternoon Session)
171
APPENDIX E
UNITED STATES CODE
Sherman Act
C 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2000); Trusts, etc., in restraint of trade illegal; penalty
C 15 U.S.C. § 2 (2000); Monopolizing trade a felony; penalty
Clayton Act
C Section 3, 15 U.S.C. § 14 (2000); Sale, etc., on agreement not to use goods of
competitor
C Section 7, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (2000); Acquisition by one corporation of stock of
another
FTC Act
C 15 U.S.C. § 45 (a)(1) (2000); Unfair methods of competition unlawful;
prevention by Commission
U.S. Copyright Code
C 17 U.S.C. § 102 (2000); Subject matter of copyright: In general
C 17 U.S.C. § 103 (2000); Subject matter of copyright: Compilations and
derivative works
C 17 U.S.C. § 106 (2000); Exclusive rights in copyrighted works
C 17 U.S.C. § 302 (2000); Duration of copyright: Works created on or after
January 1, 1978
U.S. Patent Code
C 35 U.S.C. § 154; Contents and term of patent; provisional rights
C 35 U.S.C. § 173 (2000); Term of design patent
C 35 U.S.C. § 271(d)(4), (5) (2000); Infringement of patent
C 35 U.S.C. § 282 (2000); Presumption of validity; defenses
APPENDIX E: UNITED STATES CODE172
Sherman Act
Section 1, 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2000); Trusts, etc., in restraint of trade illegal; penalty
Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade
or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. Every
person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby
declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be
punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or
by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of
the court.
Section 2, 15 U.S.C. § 2 (2000); Monopolizing trade a felony; penalty
Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with
any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the
several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction
thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other
person, $350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments,
in the discretion of the court.
Clayton Act
Section 3, 15 U.S.C. § 14 (2000); Sale, etc., on agreement not to use goods of competitor
It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the course of such commerce, to
lease or make a sale or contract for sale of goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies, or
other commodities, whether patented or unpatented, for use, consumption, or resale within the
United States or any Territory thereof or the District of Columbia or any insular possession or
other place under the jurisdiction of the United States, or fix a price charged therefor, or
discount from, or rebate upon, such price, on the condition, agreement, or understanding that
the lessee or purchaser thereof shall not use or deal in the goods, wares, merchandise,
machinery, supplies, or other commodities of a competitor or competitors of the lessor or seller,
where the effect of such lease, sale, or contract for sale or such condition, agreement, or
understanding may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any
line of commerce.
Section 7, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (2000); Acquisition by one corporation of stock of another
No person engaged in commerce or in any activity affecting commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital and no person subject to the
jurisdiction of the Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the assets
of another person engaged also in commerce or in any activity affecting commerce, where in
any line of commerce or in any activity affecting commerce in any section of the country, the
effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a
monopoly.
APPENDIX E: UNITED STATES CODE 173
No person shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital and no person subject to the jurisdiction of the Federal Trade Commission shall acquire
the whole or any part of the assets of one or more persons engaged in commerce or in any
activity affecting commerce, where in any line of commerce or in any activity affecting
commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition, of such stocks or assets,
or of the use of such stock by the voting or granting of proxies or otherwise, may be
substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.
This section shall not apply to persons purchasing such stock solely for investment and not
using the same by voting or otherwise to bring about, or in attempting to bring about, the
substantial lessening of competition. Nor shall anything contained in this section prevent a
corporation engaged in commerce or in any activity affecting commerce from causing the
formation of subsidiary corporations for the actual carrying on of their immediate lawful
business, or the natural and legitimate branches or extensions thereof, or from owning and
holding all or a part of the stock of such subsidiary corporations, when the effect of such
formation is not to substantially lessen competition.
Nor shall anything herein contained be construed to prohibit any common carrier subject to the
laws to regulate commerce from aiding in the construction of branches or short lines so located
as to become feeders to the main line of the company so aiding in such construction or from
acquiring or owning all or any part of the stock of such branch lines, nor to prevent any such
common carrier from acquiring and owning all or any part of the stock of a branch or short line
constructed by an independent company where there is no substantial competition between the
company owning the branch line so constructed and the company owning the main line
acquiring the property or an interest therein, nor to prevent such common carrier from
extending any of its lines through the medium of the acquisition of stock or otherwise of any
other common carrier where there is no substantial competition between the company
extending its lines and the company whose stock, property, or an interest therein is so acquired.
Nothing contained in this section shall be held to affect or impair any right heretofore legally
acquired: Provided, That nothing in this section shall be held or construed to authorize or
make lawful anything heretofore prohibited or made illegal by the antitrust laws, nor to exempt
any person from the penal provisions thereof or the civil remedies therein provided.
Nothing contained in this section shall apply to transactions duly consummated pursuant to
authority given by the Secretary of Transportation, Federal Power Commission, Surface
Transportation Board, the Securities and Exchange Commission in the exercise of its
jurisdiction under section 79j of this title, the United States Maritime Commission, or the
Secretary of Agriculture under any statutory provision vesting such power in such
Commission, Board, or Secretary.
APPENDIX E: UNITED STATES CODE174
FTC Act
Section 5, 15 U.S.C. § 45 (a)(1) (2000); Unfair methods of competition unlawful;
prevention by Commission
(a) Declaration of unlawfulness; power to prohibit unfair practices; inapplicability to foreign
trade
(1) Unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts
or practices in or affecting commerce, are hereby declared unlawful.
U.S. Copyright Code
17 U.S.C. § 102 (2000); Subject matter of copyright: In general
(a) Copyright protection subsists, in accordance with this title, in original works of authorship
fixed in any tangible medium of expression, now known or later developed, from which they
can be perceived, reproduced, or otherwise communicated, either directly or with the aid of a
machine or device. Works of authorship include the following categories:
(1) literary works;
(2) musical works, including any accompanying words;
(3) dramatic works, including any accompanying music;
(4) pantomimes and choreographic works;
(5) pictorial, graphic, and sculptural works;
(6) motion pictures and other audiovisual works;
(7) sound recordings; and
(8) architectural works.
(b) In no case does copyright protection for an original work of authorship extend to any idea,
procedure, process, system, method of operation, concept, principle, or discovery, regardless of
the form in which it is described, explained, illustrated, or embodied in such work.
APPENDIX E: UNITED STATES CODE 175
17 U.S.C. § 103 (2000); Subject matter of copyright: Compilations and derivative
works
(a) The subject matter of copyright as specified by section 102 includes compilations and
derivative works, but protection for a work employing preexisting material in which copyright
subsists does not extend to any part of the work in which such material has been used
unlawfully.
(b) The copyright in a compilation or derivative work extends only to the material contributed
by the author of such work, as distinguished from the preexisting material employed in the
work, and does not imply any exclusive right in the preexisting material. The copyright in such
work is independent of, and does not affect or enlarge the scope, duration, ownership, or
subsistence of, any copyright protection in the preexisting material.
17 U.S.C. § 106 (2000); Exclusive rights in copyrighted works
Subject to sections 107 through 122, the owner of copyright under this title has the exclusive
rights to do and to authorize any of the following:
(1) to reproduce the copyrighted work in copies or phonorecords;
(2) to prepare derivative works based upon the copyrighted work;
(3) to distribute copies or phonorecords of the copyrighted work to the public by
sale or other transfer of ownership, or by rental, lease, or lending;
(4) in the case of literary, musical, dramatic, and choreographic works,
pantomimes, and motion pictures and other audiovisual works, to perform the
copyrighted work publicly;
(5) in the case of literary, musical, dramatic, and choreographic works,
pantomimes, and pictorial, graphic, or sculptural works, including the
individual images of a motion picture or other audiovisual work, to display the
copyrighted work publicly; and
(6) in the case of sound recordings, to perform the copyrighted work publicly by
means of a digital audio transmission.
17 U.S.C. § 302 (2000); Duration of copyright: Works created on or after January 1,
1978
(a) In General.--Copyright in a work created on or after January 1, 1978, subsists from its
creation and, except as provided by the following subsections, endures for a term consisting of
the life of the author and 70 years after the author's death.
APPENDIX E: UNITED STATES CODE176
U.S. Patent Code
35 U.S.C. § 154; Contents and term of patent; provisional rights
(a) In General--
(1) Contents.--Every patent shall contain a short title of the invention and a grant to the
patentee, his heirs or assigns, of the right to exclude others from making, using, offering
for sale, or selling the invention throughout the United States or importing the invention
into the United States, and, if the invention is a process, of the right to exclude others
from using, offering for sale or selling throughout the United States, or importing into
the United States, products made by that process, referring to the specification for the
particulars thereof.
(2) Term.--Subject to the payment of fees under this title, such grant shall be for a term
beginning on the date on which the patent issues and ending 20 years from the date on
which the application for the patent was filed in the United States or, if the application
contains a specific reference to an earlier filed application or applications under section
120, 121, or 365(c) of this title, from the date on which the earliest such application was
filed.
35 U.S.C. § 173 (2000); Term of design patent
Patents for designs shall be granted for the term of fourteen years from the date of grant.
35 U.S.C. § 271(d)(4), (5) (2000); Infringement of patent
(d) No patent owner otherwise entitled to relief for infringement or contributory infringement
of a patent shall be denied relief or deemed guilty of misuse or illegal extension of the patent
right by reason of his having done one or more of the following:
. . . .
(4) refused to license or use any rights to the patent; or
(5) conditioned the license of any rights to the patent or the sale of the patented product
on the acquisition of a license to rights in another patent or purchase of a separate
product, unless, in view of the circumstances, the patent owner has market power in the
relevant market for the patent or patented product on which the license or sale is
conditioned.
35 U.S.C. § 282 (2000); Presumption of validity; defenses
A patent shall be presumed valid. Each claim of a patent (whether in independent, dependent,
or multiple dependent form) shall be presumed valid independently of the validity of other
claims; dependent or multiple dependent claims shall be presumed valid even though
APPENDIX E: UNITED STATES CODE 177
dependent upon an invalid claim. Notwithstanding the preceding sentence, if a claim to a
composition of matter is held invalid and that claim was the basis of a determination of
nonobviousness under section 103(b)(1), the process shall no longer be considered nonobvious
solely on the basis of section 103(b)(1). The burden of establishing invalidity of a patent or any
claim thereof shall rest on the party asserting such invalidity.
The following shall be defenses in any action involving the validity or infringement of a patent
and shall be pleaded:
(1) Noninfringement, absence of liability for infringement or unenforceability,
(2) Invalidity of the patent or any claim in suit on any ground specified in part II of this
title as a condition for patentability,
(3) Invalidity of the patent or any claim in suit for failure to comply with any
requirement of sections 112 or 251 of this title,
(4) Any other fact or act made a defense by this title.
In actions involving the validity or infringement of a patent the party asserting invalidity or
noninfringement shall give notice in the pleadings or otherwise in writing to the adverse party
at least thirty days before the trial, of the country, number, date, and name of the patentee of
any patent, the title, date, and page numbers of any publication to be relied upon as
anticipation of the patent in suit or, except in actions in the United States Court of Federal
Claims, as showing the state of the art, and the name and address of any person who may be
relied upon as the prior inventor or as having prior knowledge of or as having previously used
or offered for sale the invention of the patent in suit. In the absence of such notice proof of the
said matters may not be made at the trial except on such terms as the court requires. Invalidity
of the extension of a patent term or any portion thereof under section 154(b) or 156 of this title
because of the material failure--
(1) by the applicant for the extension, or
(2) by the Director,
to comply with the requirements of such section shall be a defense in any action involving the
infringement of a patent during the period of the extension of its term and shall be pleaded. A
due diligence determination under section 156(d)(2) is not subject to review in such an action.
179
APPENDIX F
CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS IN REPORT
A
Addamax Corp. v. Open Software Foundation, Inc., 152 F.3d 48 (1st Cir. 1998).
Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492 (1988).
American Society of Mechanical Engineers v. Hydrolevel Corp., 456 U.S. 556 (1982).
Andrx Pharmaceuticals Inc. v. Kroger Co., 543 U.S. 939 (2004), denying cert. to In re Cardizem
CD Antitrust Litigation, 332 F.3d 896 (2003).
• Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae, Andrx, 543 U.S. 939
(No. 03-779), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2004/2pet/6invit/
2003-0779.pet.ami.inv.pdf.
Aronson v. Quick Point Pencil Co., 440 U.S. 257 (1979).
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985).
Atari Games Corp. v. Nintendo of America, Inc., 897 F.2d 1572, 1576 (Fed. Cir. 1990).
B
Baker-Cammack Hosiery Mills, Inc. v. Davis Co., 181 F.2d 550 (4th Cir. 1950).
Bayer AG v. Housey Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 228 F. Supp. 2d 467 (D. Del. 2002).
Bement v. National Harrow Co., 186 U.S. 70 (1902).
Blue Cross & Blue Shield United v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406 (7th Cir. 1995).
Boggild v. Kenner Products, 776 F.2d 1315 (6th Cir. 1985), cert. denied, 477 U.S. 908 (1986).
Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979).
Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., No. CIV A 05-3350 MLC, 2006 WL 2528545 (D.N.J. Aug. 31,
2006), appeal docketed, No. 06-4292 (3d Cir. Oct. 4, 2006).
Brulotte v. Thys Co., 379 U.S. 29 (1964).
C
CSU, L.L.C. v. Xerox Corp., 531 U.S. 1143 (2001), denying cert. to 203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
• Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae, CSU, 531 U.S. 1143 (No. 00-62),
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2000/2pet/6invit/2000-0062.
pet.ami.inv.pdf.
Carpet Seaming Tape Licensing Corp. v. Best Seam Inc., 616 F.2d 1133 (9th Cir. 1980).
Chemical Products Technologies, LLC v. Monsanto Co., No. 4:01-4384-12 (D.S.C. Nov. 13, 2001)
(Complaint and Jury Demand).
APPENDIX F: CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS180
Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918).
Continental Ore Co. v. Union Carbide Corp., 370 U.S. 690 (1962).
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752 (1984).
Cutter Laboratories, Inc. v. Lyophile-Cryochem Corp., 179 F.2d 80 (9th Cir. 1949).
D
Data General Corp. v. Grumman Systems Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147 (1st Cir. 1994).
Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 509 U.S. 579 (1993).
Dawson Chemical Co. v. Rohm & Haas Co., 448 U.S. 176 (1980).
Dehydrating Process Co. v. A. O. Smith Corp., 292 F.2d 653 (1st Cir. 1961).
In re Dell, 121 F.T.C. 616 (1996).
• Complaint, In re Dell, 121 F.T.C. at 616-18 (No. C-3658), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/decisions/vol121.htm.
E
ESS Technology, Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 RMW, 2001 WL 1891713 (N.D. Cal. 2001).
Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127 (1961).
eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837 (2006).
• Brief for the United States as Amicus Curaie Supporting Respondent, eBay, 126
S. Ct. 1837 (No. 05-130), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/briefs/2005/
3mer/1ami/2005-0130.mer.ami.pdf.
Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. United States, 309 U.S. 436 (1940).
F
Fox Motors, Inc. v. Mazda Distributors (Gulf), Inc., 806 F.2d 953 (10th Cir. 1986).
G
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).
Golden Bridge Technology, Inc. v. Nokia, Inc., 416 F. Supp. 2d 525 (E.D. Tex. 2006).
Grid Systems Corp. v. Tex. Instruments Inc., 771 F. Supp. 1033 (N.D. Cal. 1991).
H
Hartford-Empire Co. v. United States, 323 U.S. 386 (1945).
Heaton-Peninsular Button-Fastener Co. v. Eureka Specialty Co., 77 F. 288 (6th Cir. 1896).
APPENDIX F: CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS 181
Hynix Semiconductor Inc. v. Rambus Inc., 441 F. Supp. 2d 1066 (N.D. Cal. 2006).
I
Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281 (2006).
• Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae Supporting Petitioners, Illinois
Tool, 126 S. Ct. 1281 (No. 04-1329), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/
briefs/2005/3mer/1ami/2004-1329.mer.ami.pdf.
Image Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997).
Independent Ink, Inc. v. Illinois Tool Works, Inc., 396 F.3d 1342 (Fed Cir. 2005), rev’d, 126 S. Ct.
1281 (2006).
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust Litigation, 203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust Litigation, No. MDL-1021 (D. Kan. Jan. 8,
1999) (Order).
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust Litigation, 989 F. Supp. 1131 (D. Kan. 1997).
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust Litigation, 964 F. Supp. 1479 (D. Kan. 1997).
Industrial Promotion Co. v. Versa Products, Inc., 467 N.W.2d 168 (Wis. Ct. App. 1991).
Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195 F.3d 1346 (Fed. Cir. 1999).
International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392 (1947).
J
Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984).
K
Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922 (1st Cir. 1984).
Khan v. State Oil Co., 93 F.3d 1358 (7th Cir. 1996), vacated, 522 U.S. 3 (1997).
King v. Anthony Pools, Inc., 202 F. Supp. 426 (S.D. Cal. 1962).
Kobe v. Dempsey Pump Co., 198 F.2d 416 (10th Cir. 1952).
L
Lear v. Adkins, 395 U.S. 653 (1969).
M
MCA Television Ltd. v. Public Interest Corp., 171 F.3d 1265 (11th Cir. 1999).
APPENDIX F: CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS182
Matsushita Electrical Industrial Co. v. Cinram International, Inc., 299 F. Supp. 2d 370 (D. Del.
2004).
Matthew Bender & Co. v. West Publishing Co., 158 F.3d 693 (2d Cir. 1998).
• Brief for Amicus Curiae United States of America in Support of Appellees,
Matthew Bender & Co., 158 F.3d 693 (No. 97-7430), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f1100/1191.pdf.
McDermott, Inc. v. AmClyde, 511 U.S. 202 (1994).
MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 764 (2007).
• Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae Supporting Petitioner,
MedImmune, 127 S. Ct. 764 (No. 05-608), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/osg/
briefs/2005/3mer/1ami/2005-0608.mer.ami.pdf.
Meehan v. PPG Industries, Inc., 802 F.2d 881 (7th Cir. 1986), cert. denied, 479 U.S. 1091 (1987).
Mercoid Corp. v. Mid-Continent Investment Co., 320 U.S. 661 (1944).
Micron Technology, Inc. v. Rambus Inc., 189 F. Supp. 2d 201 (D. Del. 2002).
Miller Insituform, Inc. v. Insituform of North America, Inc., 830 F.2d 606 (6th Cir. 1987).
Motion Picture Patents Co. v. Universal Film Manufacturing Co., 243 U.S. 502 (1917).
Mozart Co. v. Mercedes-Benz of North America, Inc., 833 F.2d 1342 (9th Cir. 1987).
N
National Collegiate Athletic Association v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468
U.S. 85 (1984).
National Society of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978).
Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1 (1958).
P
Pfaff v. Wells Electronics, Inc., 525 U.S. 55 (1998).
• Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae Supporting Respondent, Pfaff, 525
U.S. 55 (No. 97-1130), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f1800/
1836.pdf.
Pitney Bowes, Inc. v. Mestre, 701 F.2d 1365 (11th Cir. 1983).
Professional Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Industries, Inc., 508 U.S. 49 (1993).
R
Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961).
In re Rambus, Inc., No. 9302 (F.T.C. July 31, 2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/
d9302/060802commissionopinion.pdf.
APPENDIX F: CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS 183
In re Rambus Inc., No. 9302 (F.T.C. 2002).
• Complaint, Rambus, No. 9302, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/
d9302/020618admincmp.pdf.
Rambus Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, 164 F. Supp. 2d 743 (E.D. Va. 2001), rev’d in part, 318
F.3d 1081 (Fed. Cir. 2003).
S
SCM Corp. v. Xerox Corp., 645 F.2d 1195 (2d Cir. 1981).
Samsung Electronics Co. v. Rambus Inc., 439 F. Supp. 2d 524 (E.D. Va. 2006).
Scheiber v. Dolby Laboratories, Inc., 293 F.3d 1014 (7th Cir. 2002).
Schor v. Abbott Laboratories, 457 F.3d 608 (7th Cir. 2006).
Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of California, 377 U.S. 13 (1964).
Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies, Inc., 157 F. Supp. 2d 180 (D. Conn. 2001).
Southco, Inc. v. Kanebridge Corp. (Southco II), 390 F.3d 276 (3d Cir. 2004) (en banc), cert. denied,
126 S. Ct. 336 (2005).
• Brief Amicus Curiae of the United States of America in Support of Appellee
Kanebridge Corp., Southco II, 390 F.3d 276 (No. 02-1243), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f201000/201034.pdf.
Southco, Inc. v. Kanebridge Corp. (Southco I), 258 F.3d 148 (3d Cir. 2001).
• Brief Amicus Curiae of the United States of America Urging Reversal in
Support of Appellant Kanebridge Corp., Southco I, 258 F.3d 148 (No. 00-1102),
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f4900/4953.pdf.
Square D Co. v. Niagara Frontier Tariff Bureau, Inc., 476 U.S. 409 (1986).
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949).
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163 (1931).
Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Co. v. United States, 226 U.S. 20 (1912).
In re Summit Technology, Inc., 127 F.T.C. 208 (1999), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/
decisions/docs/Volume127.pdf.
• Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment, Summit Tech,
No. 9286, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/1998/08/d09286ana.htm.
• Complaint, Summit, 127 F.T.C. at 208 (No. 9286).
• Decision and Order, Summit, 127 F.T.C. at 217 (No. 9286).
• Order Reopening the Record and Dismissing the Complaint, In re VISX, Inc.,
No. 9286 (F.T.C. Feb. 7, 2001), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2001/02/
summitvisxorder.htm.
Symbol Technologies, Inc. v. Proxim Inc., No. Civ. 01-801-SLR, 2004 WL 1770290 (D. Del. July
28, 2004).
APPENDIX F: CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS184
T
Townshend v. Rockwell International Corp., 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,890, 2000 WL 433505
(N.D. Cal. 2000).
U
USM Corp. v. SPS Technologies, Inc., 694 F.2d 505 (7th Cir. 1982).
U.S. Philips Corp. v. International Trade Commission, 424 F.3d 1179 (Fed. Cir. 2005).
In re Union Oil Co. of California, No. 9305 (F.T.C. Nov. 25, 2003), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/11/031126unionoil.pdf, rev’d, No. 9305 (F.T.C. July 7,
2004), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9305/
040706commissionopinion.pdf.
• Complaint, Unocal, No. 9305 (F.T.C. Mar. 4, 2003), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/03/unocalcp.htm.
United Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965).
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919).
United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 (1966).
United States v. Jerrold Electronics Corp., 187 F. Supp. 545 (E.D. Pa. 1960), aff’d per curiam, 365
U.S. 567 (1961).
United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287 (1948).
United States v. Loew’s, Inc., 371 U.S. 38 (1962).
United States v. Masonite Corp., 316 U.S. 265 (1942).
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc).
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000), aff’d in part, rev’d in part, 253
F.3d 34.
• Complaint, Microsoft 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (No. 98-1232), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f1700/1763.pdf.
United States v. New Wrinkle, Inc., 342 U.S. 371 (1952).
United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131 (1948).
United States v. Pilkington plc, No. 94-345, 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 70,842, 1994 WL 750645
(D. Ariz. Dec. 22, 1994).
• Complaint, Pilkington plc, No. 94-345, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f0000/0014.pdf.
• United States v. Pilkington plc and Pilkington Holdings Inc.; Proposed Final
Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 59 Fed. Reg. 30,604 (June 14, 1994),
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f220800/220860.pdf,
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f220800/220861.pdf.
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940).
United States v. Singer Manufacturing Co., 374 U.S. 174 (1963).
APPENDIX F: CITED CASES AND SUPPORTING DOCUMENTS 185
United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 333 U.S. 364 (1948).
United States v. United Shoe Machinery Co. of New Jersey, 247 U.S. 32 (1918).
United States v. Univis Lens Co., 316 U.S. 241 (1942).
United States v. Westinghouse Electric Corp., 648 F.2d 642 (9th Cir. 1981).
V
In re VISX, Inc., 127 F.T.C. 236 (1999), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/decisions/docs/
Volume127.pdf.
• Decision and Order, VISX, 127 F.T.C. at 236 (No. 9286).
Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004).
• Brief for the United States and the Federal Trade Commission as Amici Curiae
Supporting Petitioner, Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (No. 02-682), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f201000/201048.pdf.
Vogel v. American Society of Appraisers, 744 F.2d 598 (7th Cir. 1984).
W
Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery & Chemical Corp., 382 U.S. 172 (1965).
Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Board of Realtors, 850 F.2d 803 (1st Cir. 1988).
Z
Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 100 (1969).
187
APPENDIX G
REFERENCES CITED IN REPORT
ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW , ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS (5th ed. 2002).
Aghion, Philippe, and Patrick Bolton, Contracts as a Barrier to Entry, 77 AMERICAN ECON. R EV.
388 (1987).
Andewelt, Roger B., Analysis of Patent Pools Under the Antitrust Laws, 53 ANTITRUST L.J. 611
(1985).
10 AREEDA, PHILLIP E., EINER ELHAUGE, AND HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW: AN
ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION (2004).
3 AREE DA, PHILLIP E., AND HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST
PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION (2d ed. 2002).
Bakos, Yannis, and Eric Brynjolfsson, Bundling and Competition on the Internet, 19 MARKETING
SCIENCE 63 (2000).
Bakos, Yannis, and Eric Brynjolfsson, Bundling Information Goods: Prices, Profits, and Efficiency,
45 MANAGEMENT SCIENCE 1613 (1999).
Balto David, and Robert Pitofsky, Antitrust and High-Tech Industries: The New Challenge, 43
ANTITRUST BULLETIN 583 (1998).
Barnett, Thomas O., Assistant Attorney Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Letter to Robert A. Skitol,
Esq., Drinker Biddle & Reath LLP (Oct. 30, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/
atr/public/busreview/219380.pdf.
Barton, John H., Patents and Antitrust: A Rethinking in Light of Patent Breadth and Sequential
Innovation, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 449 (1997).
Biester, Edward G., III, An Overview of the IP-Antitrust Intersection: Reevaluating the 1995
Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, ANTITRUST, Summer 2002,
at 8.
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES188
BLAIR, ROGER D., AND JEFFREY L. HARRISON, M ONOPSONY: ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS
(1993).
Boyle, Peter M., Penelope M. Lister, and J. Clayton Everett, Jr., Antitrust Law at the Federal
Circuit: Red Light or Green Light at the IP-Antitrust Intersection?, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 739
(2001).
BUREAU OF CONSUMER PROTECTION, FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, STANDARDS AND
CERTIFICATION: FINAL STAFF REPORT (1983).
Burtis, Michelle M., and Bruce H. Kobayashi, Why an Original Can Be Better than a Copy:
Intellectual Property, the Antitrust Refusal to Deal, and ISO Antitrust Litigation, 9 SUPREME
COURT ECON. REV. 143 (2001).
Carlson, Steven C., Patent Pools and the Antitrust Dilemma, 16 YALE J. ON REGULATION 359 (1999).
Carlton, Dennis W., and J. Mark Klamer, The Need for Coordination Among Firms, with Special
Reference to Network Industries, 50 UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO L. REV. 446 (1983).
CARLTON, DENNIS W., AND JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (4th ed.
2005).
Carrier, Michael A., Why Antitrust Should Defer to the Intellectual Property Rules of Standard-
Setting Organizations: A Commentary on Teece & Sherry, 87 MINNESOTA L. REV. 2019
(2003).
Center for the New Europe, Edited Transcript of a CNE Market Insights Event: Tying and
Bundling: From Economics to Competition Policy (Sept. 19, 2002),
http://www.cne.org/pub_pdf/2002_09_19_tying_bundling.htm.
Church, Jeffrey, and Neil Gandal, Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization, 40
J. OF INDUSTRIAL ECON. 85 (1992).
Church, Jeffrey, and Roger Ware, Network Industries, Intellectual Property Rights and Competition
Policy, in COMPETITION POLICY AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE-
BASED E CONOMY 230-39 (Robert D. Anderson & Nancy T. Gallini eds., 1998).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES 189
CLARK, JEANNE , JOE PICCOLO, BRIAN STANTON, AND KARIN TYSON , U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK
OFFICE, PATENT POOLS: A SOLUTION TO THE PROBLEM OF ACCESS IN BIOTECHNOLOGY
PATENTS? (2000), available at http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/pac/dapp/opla/
patentpool.pdf.
Commission Notice (EC), Guidelines on the Application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to Technology
Transfer Agreements, 2004 O.J. (C 101) 2 , available at http://www.europa.eu.int/eur-
lex/pri/en/oj/dat/2004/c_101/c_10120040427en00020042.pdf.
COMMITTEE ON INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN GENOMIC & PROTEIN RESEARCH &
INNOVATION, NATIONAL ACADEMIES, REAPING THE BENEFITS OF GENOMIC AND PROTEOMIC
RESEARCH: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS, INNOVATION, AND PUBLIC HEALTH (Stephen
A. Merrill & Anne-Marie Mazza eds., 2006).
COMMITTEE ON INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECON., NATIONAL
ACADEMIES, A PATENT SYSTEM FOR THE 21ST CENTURY (Stephen A. Merrill et al. eds.,
2004).
COMPETITION BUREAU, G OVERNMENT OF CANADA, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ENFORCEMENT
GUIDELINES (2000), available at http://www.strategis.ic.gc.ca/pics/ct/ipege.pdf.
COMPETITION COMMISSION OF SINGAPORE, GUIDELINES ON THE TREATMENT OF INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY RIGHTS (2005), available at http://www.ccs.gov.sg/NR/rdonlyres/
A67B68FC-DB6F-415B-9DF1-5A97FC6855A9/6714/CCSGuidelineonIPR20051228websit
efinal2.pdf.
COURNOT, AUGUSTIN, RESEARCHES INTO THE MATHEMATICAL PRINCIPLES OF THE THEORY OF
WEALTH (1929).
Donovan, Richard E., Antitrust Issues in Licensing, in ADVANCED LICENSING AGREEMENTS FOR
THE NEW ECONOMY 2001, at 643 (2001).
Easterbrook, Frank H., Intellectual Property is Still Property, 13 HARVARD J.L. & PUBLIC POLICY
108 (1990).
Economides, Nicholas, The Economics of Networks, 14 INTERNATIONAL J. OF INDUSTRIAL
ORGANIZATION 673 (1996).
Evans David, and Michael Salinger, Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive
Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 YALE J. ON REGULATION 37 (2005).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES190
Farrell, Joseph, and Garth Saloner, Converters, Compatibility and the Control of Interfaces, 40 J. OF
INDUSTRIAL ECON. 9 (1992).
Farrell, Joseph, and Garth Saloner, Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product
Preannouncements, and Predation, 76 AMERICAN ECON. R EV. 940 (1986).
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, TO PROMOTE INNOVATION: THE PROPER BALANCE OF COMPETITION
AND PATENT L AW AND POLICY (2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/
innovationrpt.pdf.
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, ENTERING THE 21ST CENTURY: COMPETITION POLICY IN THE WORLD
OF B2B ELECTRONIC MARKETPLACES (2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/
10/b2breport.pdf.
Feldman, Robin C., The Insufficiency of Antitrust Analysis for Patent Misuse, 55 HASTINGS L.J. 399
(2003).
Franzinger, Michael R., Latent Dangers in a Patent Pool: The European Commission’s Approval of the
3G Wireless Technology Licensing Agreements, 91 CALIFORNIA L. REV. 1693 (2003).
Gilbert, Richard J., Antitrust for Patent Pools: A Century of Policy Evolution, 2004 STANFORD
TECHNOLOGY L. REV. 3 (2004), http://stlr.stanford.edu/STLR/Articles/04_STLR_3/
index.htm.
Gilbert, Richard, Symposium on Compatibility: Incentives and Market Structure, 40 J. OF
INDUSTRIAL ECON. 1 (1992).
Gilbert, Richard, and Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Issues in the Licensing of Intellectual Property: The
Nine No-No’s Meet the Nineties, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY,
MICROECONOMICS 283.
Gordon, George G., and James P. Denvir, III, Is There Life After a Patent?: Strategies to
Maximize the Value of Product Life-Cycles After a Patent Expires, Presentation Before
the American Bar Association, Antitrust Section 281-84 (May 3-4, 2001) (on file with the
Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission).
Grimes, Warren S., The Antitrust Tying Law Schism: A Critique of Microsoft III and a Response to
Hylton and Salinger, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 199 (2002).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES 191
Grindley, Peter C., and David J. Teece, Managing Intellectual Capital: Licensing and Cross-
Licensing in Semiconductors and Electronics, CALIFORNIA MANA GEMEN T REV., Winter 1997,
at 8.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart, The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of
Vertical and Lateral Integration, 94 J. OF POLITICAL ECON. 691 (1986).
Guidelines on the Application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to Technology Transfer
Agreements (EC), 2004 O.J. (C 101) 2 , available at http://www.europa.eu.int/eur-
lex/pri/en/oj/dat/2004/c_101/c_10120040427en00020042.pdf.
Heller, Michael A., and Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in
Biomedical Research, 280 SCIENCE 698 (1998).
Hovenkamp, Herbert, IP Ties and Microsoft Rule of Reason, 47 ANTITRUST BULLETIN 369 (2002).
1 HOVENKAMP, HERBERT, MARK D. JANIS, AND MARK A. LEMLEY , IP AND ANTITRUST: AN
ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW (2002).
12 HOVENKAMP, HERBERT, ANTITRUST LAW (1999).
Hovenkamp, Herbert, Mark D. Janis, and Mark A. Lemley, Unilateral Refusals to License, 2 J. OF
COMPETITION L. & ECON. 1 (2006).
James, Charles A., Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Letter to Ky P.
Ewing, Esq. (Nov. 12, 2002), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/
200455.pdf.
JAPAN FAIR TRADE COMMISSION, GUIDELINES FOR PATENT AND KNOW-HOW LICENSING
AGREEMENTS UNDER THE ANTIMONOPOLY ACT (1999), available at http://www.jftc.go.jp/
e-page/legislation/ama/patentandknow-how.pdf.
Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro, Systems Competition and Network Effects, J. OF ECON.
PERSPECTIVES , Spring 1994, at 93.
Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro, Product Introduction with Network Externalities, 40 J. OF
INDUSTRIAL ECON. 55 (1992).
Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro, Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network Externalities,
94 J. OF POLITICAL ECON. 822 (1986).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES192
Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro, On the Licensing of Innovations, 16 RAND J. OF ECON. 504
(1985).
Klein, Benjamin, Market Power in Franchise Cases in the Wake of Kodak: Applying Post Contract
Hold-Up Analysis to Vertical Relationships, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 283 (1999).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable
Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297 (1978).
Klein Benjamin, and John Shepard Wiley Jr., Competitive Price Discrimination as an Antitrust
Justification for Intellectual Property Refusals to Deal, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 599 (2003).
Klein, Joel I., Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Letter to Carey R. Ramos,
Esq. (June 10, 1999), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/
2485.pdf.
Klein, Joel I., Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Letter to Garrard R.
Beeney, Esq. (Dec. 16, 1998), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/
2121.pdf.
Klein, Joel I., Acting Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Letter to G[a]rrard
R. Beeney, Esq. (June 26, 1997), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/
busreview/215742.pdf.
Klein, Joel I., Acting Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Cross-Licensing
and Antitrust Law, Address Before the American Intellectual Property Law Association
(May 2, 1997), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/1118.pdf.
Kolasky, William J., GE/Honeywell: Continuing the Transatlantic Dialogue, 23 UNIVERSITY OF
PENNSYLVANIA J. OF INTERNATIONAL ECON. L. 513 (2002).
KOREA FAIR TRADE C OMMISSION, GUIDELINES OF REVIEWING UNDUE EXERCISE OF INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY RIGHTS (2000), available at http://ftc.go.kr/data/hwp/irp_guidelines.doc.
Law, Stephen M., Inter-temporal Tie-ins: A Case for Tying Intellectual Property Through Licensing,
11 INTERNATIONAL J. OF THE ECON. OF BUSINESS 3 (2004).
Lemley, Mark A., Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, 90 CALIFORNIA
L. REV. 1889 (2002).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES 193
Lerner, Josh, and Jean Tirole, Efficient Patent Pools, 94 AMERICAN ECON. REV. 691 (2004).
Levin, Richard C., Alvin K. Klevorick, Richard R. Nelson, and Sidney G. Winter, Appropriating
the Returns from Industrial Research and Development, 1987 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON.
ACTIVI TY 783.
Levine, Gail F., B2Bs, E-Commerce & the All-Or-Nothing Deal, 28 RUTGERS COMPUTER &
TECHNOLOGY L.J. 383 (2002).
Licensing Settlement Ends Patent Suit by Rambus, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 22, 2005, at C15.
Lipsky, Abbott B., Jr., Deputy Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Current
Antitrust Division Views on Patent Licensing Practices, Remarks Before the American
Bar Association Antitrust Section (Nov. 5, 1981), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH)
13,129.
Majewski, Suzanne E., and Dean V. Williamson, Incomplete Contracting and the Structure of R&D
Joint Venture Contracts, in 15 ADVANCES IN THE STUDY OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP,
INNOVATION, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND
ENTR EPRENEURSHIP 201 (Gary D. Libecap ed., 2004).
Majoras, Deborah Platt, Chairman, Federal Trade Commission, Recognizing the Procompetitive
Potential of Royalty Discussions in Standard Setting, Remarks at Standardization and
the Law: Developing the Golden Mean for Global Trade (Sept. 23, 2005), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/majoras/050923stanford.pdf.
Mansfield, Edwin, How Rapidly Does New Industrial Technology Leak Out?, 34 J. OF INDUSTRIAL
ECON. 217 (1985).
Masoudi, Gerald F., Deputy Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Intellectual
Property and Competition: Four Principles for Encouraging Innovation, Address Before
the Digital Americas 2006 Meeting (April 11, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/
atr/public/speeches/215645.pdf.
1 MCCARTHY, J. THOMAS, MCCARTHY ON TRADEMARKS AND UNFAIR COMPETITION (4th ed. 2005).
McCullen, Sharon Brawner, The Federal Circuit and Ninth Circuit Face-Off: Does a Patent Holder
Violate the Sherman Act by Unilaterally Excluding Others from a Patented Invention in More
than One Relevant Market?, 74 TEMPLE L. REV. 469 (2001).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES194
Melamed, A. Douglas, and Ali M. Stoeppelwerth, The CSU Case: Facts, Formalism and the
Intersection of Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law, 10 GEORGE MASON L. REV. 407
(2002).
Merges, Robert P., Institutions for Intellectual Property Transactions: The Case of Patent Pools, in
EXPANDING THE BOUNDARIES OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY : INNOVATION POLICY FOR THE
KNOW LEDGE SOCIETY 123 (Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss et al. eds., 2000), available at
http://www.law.berkeley.edu/institutes/bclt/pubs/merges/pools.pdf.
Merges, Robert P., Contracting into Liability Rules: Intellectual Property Rights and Collective Rights
Organizations, 84 CALIFORNIA L. REV. 1293 (1996).
Mueller, Janice M., Patent Misuse Through the Capture of Industry Standards, 17 BERKELEY
TECHNOLOGY L.J. 623 (2002).
Mueller, Janice M., No “Dilettante Affair”: Rethinking the Experimental Use Exception to Patent
Infringement for Biomedical Research Tools, 76 WASHINGTON L. REV. 1 (2001).
Muris, Timothy J., The FTC and the Law of Monopolization, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 693 (2000).
Nielsen, Jane, Reach-Through Rights in Biomedical Patent Licensing: A Comparative Analysis of
Their Anticompetitive Reach, 32 FEDERAL L. REV. 169 (2004).
Newberg, Joshua A., Antitrust, Patent Pools and the Management of Uncertainty, 3 ATLANTIC L.J. 1
(2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020417joshuanewberg.pdf.
Ordover, Janusz A., A Patent System for Both Diffusion and Exclusion, J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES,
Winter 1991, at 43.
ORGANISATION FOR ECON. CO-OPERATION & DEVELOPMENT, GENETIC INVENTIONS, INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY RIGHTS AND LICENSING PRACTICES: EVIDENCE AND POLICES (2002).
Oversight of Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws Before the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Business Rights,
and Competition of the Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 107th Congress 134 (2002)
(statement of the Federal Trade Commission), available at http://a257.g.akamaitech.net/
7/257/2422/03jul20031230/www.access.gpo.gov/congress/senate/pdf/107hrg/87867.
pdf.
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES 195
Pate, R. Hewitt, Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Competition and
Intellectual Property in the U.S.: Licensing Freedom and the Limits of Antitrust,
Address Before the 2005 EU Competition Workshop (June 3, 2005), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/209359.pdf.
Pate, R. Hewitt, Acting Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust and
Intellectual Property, Remarks at the American Intellectual Property Law Association
2003 Mid-Winter Institute (Jan. 24, 2003), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/
public/speeches/200701.pdf.
Pate, R. Hewitt, Refusals to Deal and Intellectual Property Rights, 10 GEORGE MASON L. REV. 429
(2002).
Patterson, Mark R., Inventions, Industry Standards, and Intellectual Property, 17 BERKELEY
TECHNOLOGY L.J. 1043 (2002).
Posner, Richard A., Antitrust in the New Economy, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925 (2001).
Principles and Guidelines for Recipients of NIH Research Grants and Contracts on Obtaining
and Disseminating Biomedical Research Resources, 64 Fed. Reg. 72,090, 72,091 (Dec. 23,
1999), available at http://ott.od.nih.gov/pdfs/64FR72090.pdf.
Quélin, Bertrand V., Tamym Abdessemed, Jean-Philippe Bonardi, and Rodolphe Durand,
Standardisation of Network Technologies: Market Processes or the Result of Inter-firm Co-
operation?, 15 J. ECON. SURVEYS 543 (2001).
Rasmusen, Eric B., J. Mark Ramseyer, and John S. Wiley, Jr., Naked Exclusion, 81 AMERICAN
ECON. R EV. 1137 (1991).
Scotchmer, Suzanne, Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research and the Patent Law,
J. OF ECON. PERSPECTIVES, Winter 1991, at 29.
Segal, Ilya R., and Michael D. Whinston, Naked Exclusion: Comment, 90 AMERICAN ECON. REV.
296 (2000).
Shapiro, Carl, Competition Policy and Innovation (Organisation for Econ. Co-operation and
Development, STI Working Paper No. 2002/11, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/
opp/intellect/020501carlshapiro.pdf.
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES196
Shapiro, Carl, Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting, in 1
INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY 119 (Adam B. Jaffe et al. eds., 2000).
Shapiro, Carl, and Hal R. Varian, The Art of Standards War, CALIFORNIA MANA GEMEN T REV.,
Winter 1999, at 8.
SHAPIRO, CARL, AND HAL R. VARIAN, I NFORMATION RULES: A STRATEGIC GUIDE TO THE NETWORK
ECONOMY (1999).
Simmons, Ian, Patrick Lynch, and Theodore H. Frank, “I Know It When I See It”: Defining and
Demonstrating “Blocking Patents, ANTITRUST, Summer 2002, at 48.
Simpson, John, and Abraham Wickelgren, The Use of Exclusive Contracts to Deter Entry (Bureau
of Econ., Federal Trade Commission, Working Paper No. 241, 2001), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/be/workpapers/wp241.pdf.
Skitol, Robert A., Concerted Buying Power: Its Potential for Addressing the Patent Holdup Problem in
Standard Setting, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 727 (2005).
Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act, Pub. L. No. 105-298, 112 Stat. 2827 (1998).
Spengler, Joseph J., Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy, 58 J. OF POLITICAL ECON. 347 (1950).
Standards-Setting and United States Competitiveness: Hearing Before the House Subcommittee on
Environment, Technology, and Standards of the House Committee on Science, 107th Congress
(2001).
Statement of the Federal Trade Commission: In the Matter of Union Oil Company of
California, Dkt. No. 9305 and Chevron/Unocal, File No. 051-0125 (June 10, 2005),
available at www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9305/050802statement.pdf.
Steinman, David R., and Danielle S. Fitzpatrick, Antitrust Counterclaims in Patent Infringement
Cases: A Guide to Walker Process and Sham-Litigation Claims, 10 TEXAS INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY L.J. 95 (2001).
Swanson, Daniel G., and William J. Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties,
Standards Selection, and Control of Market Power, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 1 (2005).
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES 197
TAIWAN FAIR TRADE COMMISSION, RULES FOR REVIEW OF TECHNOLOGY LICENSING ARRANGEMENT
C ASES, available at http://www.globalcompetitionforum.org/regions/asia/Taipei/
Technology%20Licensing.pdf.
Tassey, Gregory, Standardization in Technology-Based Markets, 29 RESEARCH POLICY 587 (2000).
TEECE, DAVID J., MANAGING I NTELLECTUAL CAPITAL: ORGANIZATIONAL, S TRATEGIC, AND POLICY
DIMENSIONS (2002).
Teece, David J., Peter Grindley, and Edward Sherry, Understanding the Licensing Option, in
MANAGING INTELLECTUAL CAPITAL 135 (2000).
Teece David J., and Edward F. Sherry, Standards Setting and Antitrust, 87 MINNESOTA L. REV.
1913 (2003).
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST D IVISION POLICY GUIDE TO MERGER REMEDIES (2004),
reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,171, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/
public/guidelines/205108.pdf.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST D IVISION MANUAL (3d ed. 1998, rev. 2002), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/foia/divisionmanual/three.htm.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL T RADE COMMISSION, COMMENTARY ON THE HORIZONTAL
MERGER GUIDELINES (2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/
215247.pdf.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL T RADE COMMISSION, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR
COLLABORA TIONS AMONG COMPETITORS (2000), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶
13,161, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL T RADE COMMISSION, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES
(1992, rev. ed. 1997), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg.pdf.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL T RADE COMMISSION, STATEMENTS OF ANTITRUST
ENFORCEM ENT POLICY IN HEALTH CARE (1996), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶
13,153, at 20,812-14, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/
1791.pdf.
APPENDIX G: REFERENCES198
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL T RADE COMMISSION, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE
LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶
13,132, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.pdf.
VARIAN, HAL R., INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS: A MODERN APPROACH (4th ed. 1992).
WILLIAMSON, OLIVER E., THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS,
RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985).
Wilson, Bruce B., Deputy Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of Justice, Patent and
Know-How License Agreements: Field of Use, Territorial, Price and Quantity
Restrictions, Remarks Before the Fourth New England Antitrust Conference (Nov. 6,
1970), reprinted in ANTITRUST PRIMER: PATENTS, FRANCHI SI NG, TREBLE DAMAGE SUITS 11.
World Wide Web Consortium, Press Release, World Wide Web Consortium Approves Patent
Policy (May 21, 2003), http://www.w3.org/2003/05/patentpolicy-pressrelease.html.en.
Worley, Regis C., The MPEG LA Patent Pool: A Rule of Reason Analysis and Suggestion to Improve
Procompetitiveness, 24 THOMAS JEFFERSON L. REV . 299 (2002).
199
INDEX
A
Abdessemed, Tamym 38
Activities
joint 7, 37, 53-55
ex ante 7, 8, 37, 53, 54, 56
SSO 7, 37, 53, 54
standards development 51, 53
Addamax Corp. v. Open Software Foundation, Inc., 152
F.3d 48 (1st Cir. 1998) 51
Aghion, Philippe 120
Agreements
bundling 5, 10, 105, 106, 114, 121
cross-licensing 5, 8, 9, 41, 57-59, 61-63, 66, 67, 85,
91, 92, 96, 98, 100, 116
naked 50-52, 55, 63, 106, 120
nonexclusive 62, 69, 89, 91, 92
patent-licensing 78
patent-pooling 5, 8, 57, 58, 62, 64, 67, 69
reach-through 5, 10, 88, 92-97, 99, 101, 116, 117
reciprocal 84
royalty 5, 8, 10, 51, 54, 57, 61, 89, 94-97, 101,
116-118
sham 51, 55, 121
Alchian, Armen A. 35
Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486
U.S. 492 (1988) 35, 50
American Society of Mechanical Engineers v. Hydrolevel
Corp., 456 U.S. 556 (1982) 35, 50
Andewelt, Roger B. 71, 84
Andrx Pharmaceuticals Inc. v. Kroger Co., 543 U.S. 939
(2004) 91
Antalics, Michael 39, 42, 43
Anticommons 92, 95, 96, 117
Antitrust-IP Guidelines 1-4, 9-13, 21, 22, 58, 59,
62-64, 67, 73, 74, 76, 80, 81, 87, 88, 91-93, 99-102,
109-111, 114-116, 121, 122
Areeda, Phillip E. 18, 19, 26, 118
Aronson v. Quick Point Pencil Co., 440 U.S. 257 (1979)
117
Arora, Ashish 15, 23
Arrangements
platform 70, 71, 109
pooling 5, 8, 58, 59, 62, 63, 67, 69, 71, 78, 84, 99,
100
reach-through 5, 10, 88, 94, 101
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472
U.S. 585 (1985) 27, 28
Atari Games Corp. v. Nintendo of America, Inc., 897 F.2d
1572, 1576 (Fed. Cir. 1990) 13
B
Bahr, Robert W. 39
Baker-Cammack Hosiery Mills, Inc. v. Davis Co., 181 F.2d
550 (4th Cir. 1950) 66
Bakos, Yannis 107, 108
Balto, David 34
Barnett, Thomas O. 55
Barr, Robert 60, 61, 65
Barton, John H. 62, 93
Baumol, William J. 46
Bayer AG v. Housey Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 228 F. Supp.
2d 467 (D. Del. 2002) 97, 117
Beeney, Garrard 58, 64, 68, 74-76, 79, 80-85
Bement v. National Harrow Co., 186 U.S. 70 (1902) 29,
66
Besen, Stanley M. 40, 48, 49, 53
Bid rigging 37, 52
Biester, Edward G., III 109
Bilateral
agreements 57, 59, 69, 89
licensing solution 57
Biotechnology 59, 60, 65, 66, 93, 95
Blackburn, Robert 59, 93, 95, 96
Blair, Roger D. 51
Blanket license 52, 83
Block booking 11, 106-108
Blocking patents 61, 71, 73, 74, 84, 89, 92, 121
Blue Cross & Blue Shield United v. Marshfield Clinic, 65
F.3d 1406 (7th Cir. 1995) 22
Boggild v. Kenner Products, 776 F.2d 1315 (6th Cir.
1985) 117
Bolton, Patrick 120
Bonardi, Philippe 38
Boyle, Peter M. 26
Bresnahan, Timothy 38
INDEX200
Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System,
Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979) 52, 66
Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., No. CIV A 05-3350
MLC, 2006 WL 2528545 (D.N.J. Aug. 31, 2006) 46
Brulotte v. Thys Co., 379 U.S. 29 (1964) 12, 97, 113, 117
Brynolfsson, Eric 107, 108
Bundling 5, 10-12, 63, 103-116, 120-22
technological 10, 103, 107, 109
trade secrets 12, 116, 120, 121
Burtis, Michelle M. 18, 58, 94
Business review 9, 67-72, 74, 76-83, 85, 92
procedure 72
Business Review Letter 68-72, 74, 76-79, 81-83
C
CSU, L.L.C. v. Xerox Corp., 531 U.S. 1143 (2001) 25
In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litigation, 332 F.3d 896
(2003) 91
Cargill, Carl 33, 38, 39, 41-43, 46, 48, 49
Carlson, Steven C. 63
Carlton, Dennis W. 38, 103, 119
Carpet Seaming Tape Licensing Corp. v. Best Seam Inc.,
616 F.2d 1133 (9th Cir. 1980) 66
Carrier, Michael A. 54
Chemical Products Technologies, LLC v. Monsanto Co.,
No. 4:01-4384-12 (D.S.C. Nov. 13, 2001) 120
Chen, Raymond T. 58
Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231
(1918) 18, 52
Church, Jeffrey 34, 38
Clark, Jeanne 65, 74
Cohen, Wesley M. 96
Cohen, William 58
Cole, Pam 15
Collaborative de jure standards 36
Collaborative standard setting 35, 37, 39, 41, 43, 45,
47, 49, 51, 53, 55
and Patents 35, 37, 39, 41, 43, 45, 47, 49, 51, 53, 55
Competing standards 34, 79
multiple 34
Competition
downstream 8, 24, 36, 37, 51, 67, 85, 92, 94-96,
100, 102
ex ante 8, 36, 37, 50, 52-56
horizontal 4, 8, 67, 71, 81
Competitive effects 6, 9, 21, 24, 72, 76, 97, 102, 104,
106
Complements 48, 66, 71, 74-77
Conduct
joint 37, 54
unilateral 6, 18, 19, 22, 27-31, 36, 54
Congress 26, 27, 50, 99, 110, 113, 115
Consent decrees 60, 74, 121
Consent orders 74
Consortia 34, 43, 46
Consumer
choice 6, 33, 34, 52
harm 6, 36, 52, 104
welfare 1, 6, 33, 104, 108
Continental Ore Co. v. Union Carbide Corp., 370 U.S. 690
(1962) 30
Contracts
exclusive 12, 116, 119, 120, 122
long-term 119, 120
Coordination 8, 38, 51, 62, 67, 81, 83, 85, 99, 100
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S.
752 (1984) 31
Copyright 2, 27, 39, 66, 89, 99, 109-111, 113, 121,
122
holders 27, 122
pooling arrangement 66
protection 27, 121, 122
regimes 121
Costs
business 17, 40, 43, 50, 76-78, 95, 111
manufacturing 4, 49, 65, 75
potential 7, 8, 10, 34, 35, 43, 50, 60, 79, 89, 95
reducing 8, 34, 57, 65, 84, 121
relative 35, 37, 49
switching 7, 35, 37, 38, 44
up-front 94, 95
Crawford, Robert G. 35
Cross licensing 5, 8, 9, 19, 41, 57-64, 66, 67, 75, 78,
84, 85, 88, 91, 92, 96, 98, 100, 116
arrangements 63, 100
Cutter Laboratories, Inc. v. Lyophile-Cryochem Corp., 179
F.2d 80 (9th Cir. 1949) 66
D
Damages 26, 35, 51
Data General Corp. v. Grumman Systems Support Corp.,
36 F.3d 1147 (1st Cir. 1994) 27, 29
Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 509 U.S.
579 (1993) 113
Dawson Chemical Co. v. Rohm & Haas Co., 448 U.S. 176
(1980) 29
INDEX 201
Deadweight loss 12, 97, 118, 122
Dehydrating Process Co. v. A. O. Smith Corp., 292 F.2d
653 (1st Cir. 1961) 106
In re Dell, 121 F.T.C. 616 (1996) 36, 43, 44
Denvir, James P., III 119, 122
Design
dominant 34
freedom 60, 61
patent 59-61, 85, 90, 93, 115
products 34, 60, 61, 93, 115
Detkin, Peter N. 60
Deutsch, Donald R. 33, 39, 43
Development costs 34, 42, 50, 57, 61, 64, 65, 95, 107
Dick, Rebecca P. 115, 116, 120-122
Disclosure 1, 7, 23, 37, 39, 40, 42-45, 48, 53, 54
obligations 42, 43
policies 42-44
requirements 7, 42, 53
rules 7, 40, 42, 43, 45, 53
unilateral 23, 54
Donovan, Richard E. 80
Downstream 8, 24, 36, 37, 46, 51, 63, 67, 75, 81-83,
85, 92-96, 100, 102, 117
Durand, Rodolphe 38
DVD 68-72, 75-79, 81-83, 85
DVD Business Review Letter 68-72, 76-79, 81-83
E
ESS Technology, Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292
RMW, 2001 WL 1891713 (N.D. Cal. 2001) 46
Earp, David J. 96, 97
Easterbrook, Frank H. 100
Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor
Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127 (1961) 21, 45
eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837 (2006)
29, 60, 113
Economides, Nicholas 38
Efficiencies 6, 8, 11, 12, 33, 57-59, 64, 71-75, 84, 85,
88, 89, 92, 94, 101-105, 107-110, 114, 121, 122
Eisenberg, Rebecca S. 92-95, 117
Elhauge, Einer 118
Entry 12, 36, 62, 73, 96, 97, 99, 107, 115, 116, 119, 120,
122
Essentiality 68-71, 75, 77, 78
Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. United States, 309 U.S. 436
(1940) 21
Evans, David 103, 122
Everett, Clayton, Jr. 26
Ewing, Ky P. 68
Ex ante 7, 8, 35-37, 39, 41, 48-56, 119
agreements 8, 50, 51, 53, 55, 57
commitments 35, 41, 49, 55
discussion 8, 48, 55
joint 7, 8, 37, 52-56
licensing 7, 8, 35, 37, 39, 41, 48-57
negotiations 7, 8, 37, 41, 49-55
Exclusionary 1, 2, 18, 20, 28, 44, 50, 54, 101, 106
Exclusive licenses 79, 80
Experts
independent 50, 65, 71, 78
Extension 20, 25, 26, 122
F
Farrell, Joseph 38-41, 47-50, 58, 88, 89, 92, 96, 98,
104, 105, 108, 114, 116, 118, 122
Feldman, Robin C. 97, 117
Fitzpatrick, Danielle S. 44
Foreclosure 8, 24, 58
Fox, Stephen P. 66, 85
Fox Motors, Inc. v. Mazda Distributors (Gulf), Inc., 806
F.2d 953 (10th Cir. 1986) 106
Frank, Theodore H. 73
Franzinger, Michael R. 76
Fraud 5, 17, 18, 21, 44, 73, 74, 78
Free-riding 80, 119
Friedman, Bradford L. 59
Fromm, Jeffrey 58-62, 66, 72, 76, 79, 82-84, 88-91,
93, 97, 98, 117
FTC Act 44
FTC Innovation Report 57, 90, 93, 95
Futa, Baryn S. 58, 65, 66, 83, 84
G
Galbreath, Carolyn 40
Gandal, Neil 38
Gellhorn, Ernest 39
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F.
Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970) 46
Gifford, Daniel J. 34, 40
Gilbert, Richard J. 4, 34, 38, 62, 63, 97, 107, 118, 120
Gleklen, Jonathan I. 15-21, 23, 25, 26, 28, 29, 31
Golden Bridge Technology, Inc. v. Nokia, Inc., 416 F.
Supp. 2d 525 (E.D. Tex. 2006) 51
Goods 46, 67, 71, 81, 99, 100, 106-108
finished 46
INDEX202
patented 81, 99, 106
substitutable 71
unpatented 100, 106
Gordon, George G. 119, 122
Grantbacks 5, 10, 19, 46, 59, 66, 80, 81, 85, 88-94,
97-99, 101, 104, 115, 116
clauses 72, 89, 90, 92, 93
exclusive 19, 80, 90-92
requirements 66
tailored 81
Grid Systems Corp. v. Tex. Instruments Inc., 771 F. Supp.
1033 (N.D. Cal. 1991) 26
Grimes, Warren S. 109
Grindley, Peter 39, 58-61, 64, 65, 76, 81, 83, 84, 89
Grosman, Sanford J. 35
Group boycott 51
H
Hall, Bronwyn H. 59
Harm
innovation 6, 58, 66, 67, 71, 74, 92, 95, 96, 101,
102, 112, 116
Harrison, Jeffrey L. 51
Hart, Oliver D. 35
Hartford-Empire Co. v. United States, 323 U.S. 386
(1945) 29, 66
Heaton-Peninsular Button-Fastener Co. v. Eureka
Specialty Co., 77 F. 288 (6th Cir. 1896) 29
Heller, Michael A. 92-95, 117
Hold up 5, 7, 8, 35-49, 52-55, 57, 58, 62, 64, 90, 121
Holleman, Richard 40- 42, 47, 50, 54, 55
Hovenkamp, Herbert 11, 18, 19, 26, 30, 31, 52, 81,
92, 93, 105, 107, 109, 111-113, 115, 117, 118, 122
Hynix Semiconductor Inc. v. Rambus Inc., 441 F. Supp.
2d 1066 (N.D. Cal. 2006) 45
I
Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 126 S.
Ct. 1281 (2006) 2, 11, 22, 25, 27, 39, 63, 99, 100, 104,
105, 109, 110, 113, 115
Image Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125
F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997) 5, 15-20, 22, 25, 30, 32
Incentives 1, 2, 8, 12, 13, 19-21, 23-25, 27, 40, 47, 48,
79, 81, 85, 90, 91, 96-99, 108, 118, 119
Independent Ink, Inc. v. Illinois Tool Works, Inc., 396 F.3d
1342 (Fed Cir. 2005) 113
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust
Litigation, 203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000) 5, 15-20,
22, 25, 26, 32
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust
Litigation, 989 F. Supp. 1131 (D. Kan. 1997) 26
In re Independent Service Organizations Antitrust
Litigation, 964 F. Supp. 1479 (D. Kan. 1997) 16
Industrial Promotion Co. v. Versa Products, Inc., 467
N.W.2d 168 (Wis. Ct. App. 1991) 121
Industry
biomedical 96
biotechnology 59, 60, 95
computer 59, 60, 91
semiconductor 59, 60
standards 6, 7, 33, 34, 39, 40, 43-46, 64, 76
Infringement 19-21, 23, 25, 26, 31, 44-46, 59-61, 65,
73, 84, 93, 96, 101, 102, 111, 117
Injunctions 60
Innovation 1-4, 6, 8, 12, 13, 16-18, 20-26, 32-36,
52-54, 56-58, 60-62, 66-68, 74-82, 84, 85, 90-102,
116-118
and consumer welfare 6, 33
cost-reducing process 67
downstream 8, 46, 51, 75, 81, 85, 92-96, 102, 117
effects 6, 8, 9, 12, 20, 21, 24, 33, 38, 46, 58, 80, 92,
97, 101, 102, 104, 110, 111
foreclosure of 8, 58
incentives 1, 8, 12, 13, 21, 23-25, 53, 81, 85, 91, 96,
98, 101, 118, 122
preserving 12, 13, 122
independent 5, 55, 68, 80, 90
investments 2, 35, 46, 60, 64, 67
Intellectual property
bottleneck 25
bundling 5, 10, 11, 63, 103-116, 121, 122
disclosure rules 7, 42, 43
exploitation of 25, 100, 107
holders 7, 8, 17, 35, 36, 40-43, 48-50, 54, 55, 57, 90,
94, 100
infringement 21, 23, 25, 44, 46, 60, 61, 65, 111, 117
investments 2, 35, 60, 80
licenses 5, 8, 9, 12, 24, 40, 46, 48, 50, 57-59, 61-63,
79, 83-85, 89, 99, 101
pooled 58, 74, 79, 84, 100
tying 11, 107, 114
Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195 F.3d 1346 (Fed. Cir.
1999) 25, 29
International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392
(1947) 21, 104, 105, 109
INDEX 203
Internet 6, 33, 46-48, 59, 65, 76, 95, 107, 108
Interoperability 33
Inventions 1, 2, 20, 29-31, 39, 46, 59, 80, 81, 94, 95,
117
follow-on 80, 92
upstream 94, 95
Inventors 8, 31, 57
Investments 2, 17, 21, 25, 29, 35, 46, 58, 60, 64, 67,
74, 80, 85, 91, 101
long-term 60
relationship-specific 35, 64
standards-specific 35
sunk 35, 60, 74
J
Jacobson, Jonathan M. 104, 105, 109, 111-113
James, Charles A. 13, 68
Janis, Mark D. 11, 30, 31, 81, 92, 93, 105, 107, 115,
117, 122
Japan 62, 69, 87
Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S.
2 (1984) 11, 104-106, 109, 112
Joint ventures 34, 51, 116
K
Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922
(1st Cir. 1984) 22
Kattan, Joseph 40, 48, 52
Katz, Michael L. 33, 34, 38, 64, 104, 108, 116, 122
Kelly, Christopher J. 58, 69, 75, 77, 79, 83, 84
Khan v. State Oil Co., 93 F.3d 1358 (7th Cir. 1996) 112
King v. Anthony Pools, Inc., 202 F. Supp. 426 (S.D. Cal.
1962) 66
Kirsch, Paul F. 15, 17, 18, 24, 29, 31
Kirschner, Michael K. 95
Klamer, J. Mark 38
Klein, Benjamin 15, 24, 35
Klein, Joel I. 68, 84
Klevorick, Alvin K. 115
Kobayashi, Bruce H. 18
Kobe v. Dempsey Pump Co., 198 F.2d 416 (10th Cir.
1952) 66
Kohn, Robert H. 95
Kolasky, William J. 112
Kulbaski, James J. 58, 64, 65, 75, 76, 80
L
Law, Stephen M. 118
Lear v. Adkins, 395 U.S. 653 (1969) 90
Lemley, Mark A. 11, 30, 31, 33, 36, 38, 39, 42-44, 46,
47, 49, 53, 81, 92, 93, 105, 107, 115, 117, 122
Lerner, Josh 58, 64, 74, 76, 77, 79, 80, 83, 85
Leverage 94, 104
Levin, Richard C. 115
Levine, Gail 15, 39, 40, 52, 58, 88
Liability rules 23, 29, 65
Liberal licensing 60
License
agreements 5, 22, 52, 53, 57, 61-64, 66, 76, 78, 80,
84, 89, 92, 94-96, 118, 119, 121
claims 16, 17, 20, 25, 26, 44, 45, 62
compulsory 6, 21-24
copyrights 29, 121
fees 46, 61, 74, 76
implied 27, 30, 44
know-how 23, 89, 98, 120, 121
negotiation 48, 53, 89
nonexclusive 42, 62, 74, 78-81, 89, 91, 92
one-stop 65
partial 57, 76, 83, 84
perpetual 45
portfolio 57, 59-62, 66, 92, 98
reach-through 5, 94-97, 99, 101, 102
reciprocal 48
royalty 5, 12, 23, 40, 46-48, 57, 61, 65, 66, 69, 70,
74, 75, 79, 80, 83-85, 89, 94-97, 118, 119
third-party 73
Licensees
exclusive 78-80, 119
freedom 54, 61
Licensing
administrator 68-70, 82
agreements 3, 5, 8-10, 50, 51, 55, 57-59, 61-64, 66,
67, 76, 84, 85, 87-89, 91-96, 98-102, 116-118, 121,
122
efficiencies 8, 11, 57-59, 64, 71, 73, 84, 85, 88, 89,
92, 94, 101, 102, 104, 105, 109, 110, 114, 121, 122
negotiations 7, 8, 37, 38, 41, 49-55, 57, 59, 61, 84
regime 62, 99, 121
Licensors 8, 16, 22, 28, 41, 47, 48, 59, 61, 67, 69-71,
78-82, 84, 85, 89-93, 95, 96, 117-119
Lipsky, Abbott B., Jr. 98, 104, 105, 111-114
Lister, Penelope M. 26
Litigation costs 40, 61, 65, 84
INDEX204
Lo, Allen M. 40, 41, 48
Long term contracts 119
Lynch, Patrick 73
M
MCA Television Ltd. v. Public Interest Corp., 171 F.3d
1265 (11th Cir. 1999) 108
MPEG-2 Business Review Letter 68, 69, 71, 72,
76-79, 81-83
MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K. 15, 17-20, 29, 31
Majewski, Suzanne E. 15, 35
Majoras, Deborah Platt 52, 54
Mandatory package licensing 107
Mansfield, Edwin 121
Manufacturing 4, 30, 49, 55, 60, 62, 65, 75, 81
Marasco, Amy A. 6, 33, 39, 43, 50, 53
Marginalization, double 96
Marshall, Frances 58, 59, 88
Market
analysis 8, 9, 11, 12, 17, 20, 35, 39, 57, 62, 73, 87,
97-101, 103, 105, 113-115, 122
competitive 24, 35, 39, 48, 75, 81, 95, 97, 104, 105,
107, 109, 122
conditions 11, 22, 49, 104, 105, 119
defined 20, 23, 99
definition 20, 111
division 2, 10, 19, 62, 63, 82, 116, 123
downstream 24, 75, 81, 82, 95
effects 9, 11, 12, 20, 21, 34, 38, 39, 52, 58, 63, 67,
97, 99, 104-106, 109-111, 114
power 1, 2, 4, 8, 11, 12, 16, 17, 20-24, 29, 34-36,
39, 46-48, 52-54, 63, 97-100, 104-106, 109-123
price 8, 10, 19, 21-24, 49, 53, 58, 62, 63, 67, 73, 81,
83, 85, 100, 106
relevant 11, 20, 26, 64, 67, 83, 97, 99, 102, 106,
110, 111
Masoudi, Gerald F. 101
Mathias, Sarah 58, 88
Matsushita Electrical Industrial Co. v. Cinram
International, Inc., 299 F. Supp. 2d 370 (D. Del. 2004)
67, 79
Matthew Bender & Co. v. West Publishing Co., 158 F.3d
693 (2d Cir. 1998) 113
McCarthy, J. Thomas 4
McCullen, Sharon Brawner 26
McCurdy, Daniel 43
McDermott, Inc. v. AmClyde, 511 U.S. 202 (1994) 91
McFalls, Michael 58, 80, 88-92, 97, 98
McGarey, Barbara M. 58, 88, 92-96
McGowan, David 58, 75, 78-81, 84, 85
MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 764
(2007) 90, 91
Meehan v. PPG Industries, Inc., 802 F.2d 881 (7th Cir.
1986) 117
Melamed, A. Douglas 15, 17, 19, 20, 23, 25, 27-29,
31
Mercoid Corp. v. Mid-Continent Investment Co., 320 U.S.
661 (1944) 21, 29
Merges, Robert P. 58, 65, 76
Microeconomics 62, 71, 97, 107, 118, 121
Micron Technology, Inc. v. Rambus Inc., 189 F. Supp. 2d
201 (D. Del. 2002) 45
Milgrim, Roger M. 4
Miller, Joseph Scott 108
Miller Insituform, Inc. v. Insituform of North America,
Inc., 830 F.2d 606 (6th Cir. 1987) 30
Misappropriation 21, 119
Misuse 25, 26, 33, 44, 96, 97, 108, 111, 112, 115, 117
Monopolist 22-24, 27, 30, 65, 108, 120
Monopolization 21, 25, 35
Monopoly
lawful 2, 19, 23
power 1, 2, 12, 16, 20-23, 29-31, 44, 97, 99, 104,
110, 117, 120, 122
prices 1, 22-24
Monopsony 48, 49, 51, 52
Morse, M. Howard 58, 63, 71, 72, 74, 76, 80, 82, 83,
85, 92
Motion Picture Patents Co. v. Universal Film
Manufacturing Co., 243 U.S. 502 (1917) 30
Mozart Co. v. Mercedes-Benz of North America, Inc., 833
F.2d 1342 (9th Cir. 1987) 106
Mueller, Janice M. 33, 34, 93, 94, 95, 96, 97
Muris, Timothy J. 35
N
Naked agreements 50, 51, 55, 106
National Collegiate Athletic Association v. Board of
Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85
(1984) 11, 39, 105
National Society of Professional Engineers v. United
States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978) 50
Negotiations 7, 8, 28, 37, 38, 41, 49-55, 57, 59, 61,
64, 84
bilateral 8, 41, 54, 57
Nelson, Richard R. 115
INDEX 205
Network effects 33, 34, 38
Network industries 34, 38
Networks 6, 19, 27, 33, 38, 40
Newberg, Joshua A. 58, 63, 74
Nielsen, Jane 92, 94
Noerr-Pennington 45, 122
Non-assertion 5, 10, 59, 88-93, 97-101, 116
Non-disclosure 40, 44
Nondiscriminatory 7, 36, 46, 47, 49, 70
Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1
(1958) 104, 112
O
Oehler, Ross 95
Oligopolistic 62
One monopoly rent 24
Ordover, Janusz A. 58, 60, 62, 88, 92, 96, 98, 99
Output 8, 58, 64, 82, 100
P
Package license 12, 84, 107, 108, 110, 112
Partial-pool licenses 83
Pate, R. Hewitt 15, 18, 20, 54, 82, 90, 101
Patent
applications 42, 43, 104
biotechnology 59, 65, 93, 95
claims 16, 17, 20, 25, 26, 31, 44, 45, 62, 66, 67, 76,
90, 93
competing 74-76, 79
complementary 5, 9, 48, 62, 63, 66, 71, 74, 76-78,
81, 83, 84, 96
disclosure rule 43
essential 21, 54, 64-66, 68-71, 74-78, 81, 83, 85, 92,
108
expert 65, 68-71, 78, 113
expiration 12, 97, 115-122
hold-up 8, 35, 42
infringement 19, 44, 73, 93, 96, 117
invalid 71, 78, 90, 91, 96
misuse 25, 26, 33, 44, 96, 97, 108, 111, 115, 117
doctrine 26, 44, 97, 115, 117
rules 97
pooling 5, 8, 9, 52, 57-59, 62, 64, 66-69, 71, 72,
77-79, 82, 84, 85, 99, 100
portfolio 8, 41, 43, 57-63, 66, 67, 77, 84, 85, 91, 92,
96, 98-100
rival 65, 74, 79
royalty-free 42, 47, 48, 61, 74, 89
scope 19, 20, 59, 72, 80, 81, 90, 91, 93, 96, 120
substitutable 64, 71, 77
tying cases 111
unenforceable 78, 90
valid 4, 66, 71, 78
validity 51, 78, 90
Patent Act 6, 25, 31
Patent breadth 62, 93
Patterson, Mark R. 39, 40, 46, 52, 53
Perloff, Jeffrey M. 103, 119
Peterson, Scott K. 33, 40, 46, 47, 49, 53, 55
Pfaff v. Wells Electronics, Inc., 525 U.S. 55 (1998) 113
Piccolo, Joe 65, 74
Pitney Bowes, Inc. v. Mestre, 701 F.2d 1365 (11th Cir.
1983) 117, 121
Pitofsky, Robert 34
Polk, C. Edward 15, 104, 116
Pool
administrator 68, 69, 82, 84
agreement 63, 64, 68, 69, 72-74, 78, 80, 85
anticompetitive effects of 9, 58
business review letters 67-69, 72, 77, 78
of complementary patents 66, 74, 77
partial 57, 83, 84
royalty rates 66, 80, 85
Poppen, Joel 60
Portfolio cross-licensing agreements 57, 58, 91, 92,
96, 100
Posner, Richard A. 2
Potential competitors 8, 10, 32, 37, 39, 51, 58, 63, 67,
99, 102
Predatory 17, 28
Price
bundled 11, 107, 112
competition 8, 20, 24, 28, 31, 37, 38, 48, 51-55, 67,
71, 73, 74, 78, 83, 99-102, 106
discrimination 24, 109
fixing 8, 10, 19, 21, 37, 51, 52, 58, 62, 63, 85
terms 7, 8, 21, 24, 28, 37, 47, 49, 52-55, 82, 83
Price fixing 19, 51, 55, 74, 78, 113
Price fixing, naked 37, 52, 62, 63
Procompetitive 4, 5, 7, 9, 11, 19, 37, 42, 52-55, 58,
62, 63, 67, 76, 84, 85, 87-89, 109, 110
activity 52, 54, 55, 62, 87, 100
benefits 9, 37, 42, 52, 54, 58, 63, 67, 84, 85, 110
conduct 19, 37, 63, 100, 105
effects 5, 9, 11, 12, 58, 63, 76, 109, 110
Product
INDEX206
complex 60, 106
homogeneous 81
market 2-4, 8, 11, 20, 22, 33, 34, 38, 39, 41, 42, 49,
57, 62, 64, 75, 82, 95, 97-101, 103-106, 109-112,
115, 119, 120
noninfringing 96, 115
platform software 112
prices of 51, 71, 74, 82
rival 79
second-generation 81
standardized 36, 55
Production
complementary factors of 4, 62, 76, 87
costs 4, 61, 65, 76
facilities 4, 99
Professional Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia
Pictures Industries, Inc., 508 U.S. 49 (1993) 21
Profits 20, 24, 28, 38, 48, 79, 95, 108
Property, tangible 3, 4, 21, 63, 107, 108
Proprietary information 71, 81, 82, 121
Pure bundling 103
Putnam, Jonathan D. 58
Q
Quélin, Bertrand V. 38
Qureshi, Abid 109
R
RAND (reasonable and nondiscriminatory) 7, 36, 42,
46, 47, 49, 53, 54, 64, 70
R&D 2, 8, 17, 48, 57, 59-62, 64, 67
Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke Co.,
364 U.S. 656 (1961) 35, 50
In re Rambus, Inc., No. 9302 (F.T.C. July 31, 2006) 36,
37, 44
Rambus Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, 164 F. Supp.
2d 743 (E.D. Va. 2001) 44
Ramos, Carey R. 68
Ramseyer, J. Mark 120
Rapp, Richard T. 38, 39
Rasmusen, Eric B. 120
Reach-through 5, 10, 59, 88, 92-97, 99, 101, 102,
116, 117
Refusals 5, 6, 15-32, 63, 84
conditional 6, 19, 31
unconditional 6, 18, 19, 22, 23, 27, 29-32
Relief 25, 112
Rents 35, 90, 119
Research 15, 39, 40, 45, 57-60, 66, 67, 81, 91-97, 101,
115-117
biotechnology 59, 60, 66, 93
tool 91-97, 101, 116, 117
Restraint 9, 10, 29, 51, 52, 63, 64, 73, 93, 99, 102, 122
Restrictions 5, 8, 19, 24, 31, 58, 67, 96, 98, 100, 101,
119, 121, 122
Rey, Patrick 24, 25
Royalties 7-9, 10, 12, 23, 35, 36, 40, 41, 44-48, 53, 54,
57-61, 64-66, 69-71, 77, 79, 80, 82-85, 93-97, 101,
116-119
charge 23, 45, 48, 101, 117-11
cumulative 8, 95, 101
distributing 64
excessive 82, 96, 101
fixed 36, 61
legitimate 101
negotiated 69, 84, 97
post-expiration 113, 117, 118
reach-through 59, 88, 93-97, 101, 116, 117
reasonable 7, 36, 46, 70, 80, 82, 83, 94
running 61
stacking 8, 57, 58, 61, 65, 95, 96
up-front 94, 95
Royalty rates 12, 23, 36, 40, 51, 54, 61, 66, 70, 77, 80,
83, 85, 92, 97, 118, 119
Royalty-free 42, 46-48, 61, 74, 89, 92
Rule, Charles F. (Rick) 58, 62, 88, 90, 92, 93, 94, 96-
100, 102, 118
S
SCM Corp. v. Xerox Corp., 645 F.2d 1195 (2d Cir. 1981)
30
SSO (Standard-setting organizations) 7, 8, 33-47,
49-55
intellectual property policies 43
policies 42-44
requirements 7, 37, 42, 53
rules 7, 36, 40, 42, 43, 45, 50, 51, 53, 54
Safeguards 9, 46, 58, 72
Safety zone 112
Salinger, Michael 103, 122
Saloner, Garth 38
Samsung Electronics Co. v. Rambus Inc., 439 F. Supp. 2d
524 (E.D. Va. 2006) 45
Scheffman, David L. 58, 88, 104, 116
INDEX 207
Scheiber v. Dolby Laboratories, Inc., 293 F.3d 1014 (7th
Cir. 2002) 25, 26, 97, 113, 118
Scherer, F. M. 95
Schor v. Abbott Laboratories, 457 F.3d 608 (7th Cir.
2006) 101
Scope 19, 20, 34, 59, 72, 80, 81, 90, 91, 93, 96, 120
Scotchmer, Suzanne 81
Segal, Ilya R. 120
Semiconductors 43, 44, 59-62
Sham 5, 17, 18, 44, 51, 55, 63, 102, 121, 123
Shapiro, Carl 15, 17-19, 21-23, 28, 29, 33-36, 38, 40,
42, 47, 50, 57-62, 64, 65, 74, 83, 85, 88, 91, 96, 97,
99, 107, 117, 118, 120
Sherman Act 8, 15, 16, 21, 26-28, 30, 31, 35, 37, 39,
51, 52, 54, 79, 101, 106
Sherry, Edward F. 48
Sibley, David S. 104, 105, 116, 119
Sidak, J. Gregory 104, 105, 107, 112
Simmons, Ian 73
Simon, James 60
Simpson, John 120
Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of California, 377 U.S. 13
(1964) 30
Skitol, Robert A. 52, 53, 55
Software 16, 38, 51, 59, 68, 81, 95, 104, 108, 109, 112
Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies, Inc.,
157 F. Supp. 2d 180 (D. Conn. 2001) 51
Spengler, Joseph J. 65
Sprigman, Christopher J. 15, 17, 19-21, 23-25, 29, 31
Southco, Inc. v. Kanebridge Corp. (Southco II), 390 F.3d
276 (3d Cir. 2004) (en banc) 113
Southco, Inc. v. Kanebridge Corp. (Southco I), 258 F.3d
148 (3d Cir. 2001) 113
Square D Co. v. Niagara Frontier Tariff Bureau, Inc., 476
U.S. 409 (1986) 27
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949)
105
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163 (1931)
66
Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Co. v. United States,
226 U.S. 20 (1912) 34, 66
Standard setting 7, 33-43, 45, 49, 50, 52-55
Standard-setting process 7, 35-39, 41-43, 45, 49, 50,
52, 53, 55
Standards 5-7, 33-36, 38-48, 50-55, 64, 69, 76, 79, 81,
96, 110, 114
de facto 34, 36
development 34, 42, 46, 47, 50, 51, 53, 64
interoperability 33
war 34
Stanton, Brian 65, 74
State Oil v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997) 113
Steinman, David R. 44
Stiroh, Lauren J. 39, 40
Stoeppelwerth, Ali M. 17, 19, 25, 28, 29
Stoner, Robert D. 95
Substitutes 2, 4, 7, 9, 12, 22, 34, 36, 38, 63, 66-69, 71,
74-79, 85, 100, 106, 111, 115, 116, 122
economic 66, 71, 111
noninfringing 115
partial 76
patents 7, 9, 66-71, 74-78, 85
products 2, 7, 12, 34, 67, 69, 71, 74, 85, 116, 122
technological 77
technologies 2, 7, 66, 67, 71, 75, 76
Sullivan, Mary 58
In re Summit Technology, Inc., 127 F.T.C. 208 (1999)
67, 73, 74, 76-79
Sung, Lawrence M. 58, 59, 66
Surplus 64, 81, 108
Swanson, Daniel G. 36, 40, 46-48
Symbol Technologies, Inc. v. Proxim Inc., No. Civ.
01-801-SLR, 2004 WL 1770290 (D. Del. July 28,
2004) 44
T
Tacit agreement 51, 64
Tassey, Gregory 33
Technology
blocking 61, 71, 73, 74, 84, 89, 92
competing 74-76
complementary 2, 4, 48, 62, 66, 71, 74, 76, 84
developing 35, 38, 52, 55, 109
disseminate 97, 118
public domain 52, 121
Technology markets 36, 64
Teece, David J. 39, 43, 48, 59-61, 89
Telecky, Fredrick J., Jr. 44, 61, 62, 90
Telecommunications 6, 33, 40, 46, 68
Television 11, 68, 106-108
Temporal extensions 104, 115
Territories 121
Thompson, Earle 40, 41, 47, 49, 50
Tie 11, 103-107, 109-112, 114, 118, 119, 122
technological 11, 103, 107, 109
Tied product 11, 106, 107, 110, 111
Tirole, Jean 24, 77, 80, 83
INDEX208
Townshend v. Rockwell International Corp., 2000-1 Trade
Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,890, 2000 WL 433505 (N.D. Cal.
2000) 19
Trade secrets 4, 12, 23, 116, 120, 121
Trademarks 4
Transaction
costs 8, 10, 34, 57, 61, 65, 75, 79, 84, 89, 95, 121
efficiencies 57, 84, 89, 121
Tying
arrangements 5, 11, 12, 31, 63, 104, 105, 109, 110,
114, 122
product-to-patent 109
product 2, 10-12, 22, 31, 39, 63, 103-107, 109-112
sales 106
Tyson, Karin 65, 74
U
USM Corp. v. SPS Technologies, Inc., 694 F.2d 505 (7th
Cir. 1982) 26
U.S. Philips Corp. v. International Trade Commission, 424
F.3d 1179 (Fed. Cir. 2005) 109, 117, 121
Unilateral
refusals 5, 6, 15-23, 25, 27-32, 63
termination 28
In re Union Oil Co. of California, No. 9305 (F.T.C. Nov.
25, 2003) 36, 45
United Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965)
45, 122
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919) 27
United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 (1966) 100
United States v. Jerrold Electronics Corp., 187 F. Supp.
545 (E.D. Pa. 1960) 106
United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287 (1948)
21, 66
United States v. Loew’s, Inc., 371 U.S. 38 (1962) 103,
106, 108
United States v. Masonite Corp., 316 U.S. 265 (1942) 21
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir.
2001) (en banc) 18, 104, 107-109, 112
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30
(D.D.C. 2000) 46, 107
United States v. New Wrinkle, Inc., 342 U.S. 371 (1952)
66
United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131
(1948) 109
United States v. Pilkington plc, No. 94-345, 1994-2
Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 70,842, 1994 WL 750645 (D.
Ariz. Dec. 22, 1994) 121
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150
(1940) 51, 52
United States v. Singer Manufacturing Co., 374 U.S. 174
(1963) 66
United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 333 U.S. 364 (1948)
66
United States v. United Shoe Machinery Co. of New
Jersey, 247 U.S. 32 (1918) 29
United States v. Univis Lens Co., 316 U.S. 241 (1942) 21
United States v. Westinghouse Electric Corp., 648 F.2d
642 (9th Cir. 1981) 30
Updegrove, Andrew 33, 40, 41, 43, 46-48
V
In re VISX, Inc., 127 F.T.C. 236 (1999) 67, 73, 74, 76-79
Validity 46, 51, 78, 90, 108
Varian, Hal R. 34, 36, 71
Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004) 6, 22, 23, 27-29, 32
Vertical integration 20, 35, 65
Vishny, Paul 40, 46, 47, 50
Vistnes, Gregory 104, 107, 121
Vogel v. American Society of Appraisers, 744 F.2d 598
(7th Cir. 1984) 55
W
Ware, Roger 34
Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery &
Chemical Corp., 382 U.S. 172 (1965) 21
Welfare 1, 6, 33, 66, 74, 76, 104, 108, 109
Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Board of Realtors,
850 F.2d 803 (1st Cir. 1988) 106
Wetzner, Daniel J. 40, 46, 47
Whinston, Michael D. 120
Whitener, Mark D. 15, 17-19, 22, 23, 28, 29, 31
Wickelgren, Abraham 120
Wiley, John Shepard, Jr. 15, 24, 120
Williamson, Dean V. 35
Williamson, Oliver E. 35, 64
Wilson, Bruce B. 98
Winston, Tor 39, 40
Winter, Sidney G. 115
Worley, Regis C. 76
Y
Yao, Dennis A. 39, 40
INDEX 209
Z
Zanfagna, Gary 43
Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S.
100 (1969) 97, 117
210
Acknowledgments:
The Agencies thank the Hearings participants for the contribution of their expertise and time to
this project. The Agencies also thank the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office for participating in
many of the panels at the Hearings.
The Agencies thank the Competition Policy Center and the Berkeley Center for Law and
Technology at the University of California at Berkeley for providing facilities to allow some of
the Hearings to be held on the west coast.
Cover:
The clip art on the cover was obtained under license from Microsoft Corporation.
The image of Article I of the U.S. Constitution is from the website of the National Archives.
Patent on front cover:
Patent No. U.S. Pat. No. 2,221,776 – Electron Photography (Nov. 19, 1940)
U.S. Department of Justice Federal Trade Commission
www.usdoj.gov/atr www.ftc.gov