Aggressive Uses of Chapter
11 of the Federal
Bankruptcy Code
by Walker F. Todd
Walker F. Todd is an assistant gener
al counsel and research officer at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Substantial contributions to and
useful comments on this article
were provided by Jo hn M . Davis,
Mark Sniderman, and Erica Groshen
of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, and by Andrea Berger
Kalodner, member, New York Bar.
20
Introduction
The filing of a voluntary bankruptcy petition
under Chapter 11 of the Bankruptcy Code of 1978
by the LTV Corporation on July 17, 1986 focused
renewed attention on the recent evolution of
corporate reorganizations under the Bankruptcy
Code. This article reviews that evolution and
offers alternative explanations for the kinds of
uses noted in recent Chapter 11 petitions. To
some observers, a Chapter 11 petition is becom
ing one of the standard financial strategies of
large corporations. In a period of disinflation, the
filing of a Chapter 11 petition is not a completely
unexpected or unnatural response to the need to
reduce corporate obligations.
Alternative legal mechanisms do
exist for the orderly downsizing of corporate
assets and liabilities in the face of a generally fal
ling price level or a significantly reduced demand
in specific markets. Those alternatives include
assignments for the benefit of creditors, corporate
liquidations, and corporate dissolutions and reor
ganizations under state law, as well as contractual
agreements for nonbankruptcy lending ( “work
outs)- However, those alternatives often are
unsatisfactory because they do not provide a con
venient method for debtors to stay all creditors
claims automatically or to reject burdensome
contingent liabilities. Thus, corporate reorganiza
tion under Chapter 11 typically is the debtor’s
preferred alternative. Creditors also may prefer
the orderly process of negotiation with a debtor
through creditors committees under the supervi
sion of a federal bankruptcy court, instead of
attempts to reorganize the debtor without the
court’s protection and assistance.
A more restrained, and probably
more accurate, view of bankruptcy petitions such
as that filed by LTV is that a Chapter 11 filing may
be helpful in restructuring large claims of secured
creditors and of creditors with the priority claims
described in section 507 of the Bankruptcy Code
(11 U.S.C. section 507). Nevertheless, the use of
Chapter 11 filings as a sword rather than a shield
was not traditionally contemplated under the
1978 Bankruptcy Code or the prior United States
bankruptcy acts.
I. An Economic Perspective
Basic economics textbooks pay little, if any, atten
tion to bankruptcy proceedings as a mechanism
for allocating resources. When an uncompetitive
firm becomes insolvent, economics texts gener
ally assume that its assets w ill be liquidated to
satisfy creditors and that the firm no longer will
exist. Economists call this process exit from the
market. Shareholders may suffer large losses,
including the complete loss of their investments.
At times, new investors purchase some of the liqui
dated assets on favorable terms, putting up fresh
capital, and a new firm enters the market. Some
former assets are scrapped, some former employ
ees are not re-employed, and some former credi
tors are not paid fully. The new firm generally has
a better chance of succeeding than the old firm be
cause it has some combination of lower costs,
greater productivity, and better management.
Economists describe this market-driven process
as being efficient because investors purchase
1986 Quarter 3
assets or new stock in the firm at market prices.
Those investors could have used their capital for
other purposes.
In practice, corporate reorganiza
tions under the Bankruptcy Code allocate re
sources in a manner that may differ significantly
from an economist’s description of corporate
reorganizations. Under Chapter 11, troubled firms
essentially bargain with creditors committees
and, occasionally, with their own employees
regarding the conditions under which they can
remain “going concerns.Negotiations with
employees typically would cover the restructuring
of executives compensation contracts and
unions collective bargaining agreements.
The bankruptcy judge acts as a
mediator/arbitrator, following the Bankrupcty
Rules. However, the real power to affect the day-
to-day operations of a debtor is in the hands of
the creditors committees. Usually, management
of the bankrupt firm attempts to remain in con
trol of the ongoing operations of the enterprise.
In such cases, management is referred to as the
“debtor in possession. Often, as was the case
with the LTV filing, bank creditors already have a
functioning committee that has been negotiating
with management before a bankruptcy petition is
filed. Thus, it is not at all inaccurate to describe
the bankruptcy judge as a detached mediator or
referee. Usually, the judge plays only a small role
in preparing a reorganization plan. That plan
ordinarily is drafted by the debtor and must be
ratified by the creditors committees. The com
mittees may serve as active, involved co-managers
of the bankrupt firm, and it is not unusual for
counsel for the creditors committees to meet at
least weekly with management.
If no agreement between the bank
rupt firm and its creditors can be reached volun
tarily, the court, usually acting through a trustee,
can impose a solution. One possible solution is a
complete liquidation of the firm, but such a solu
tion is used in Chapter 11 cases only after a judge
determines that no viable alternative exists. It
would be mere coincidence if a firm reorganized
in a Chapter 11 proceeding had the same assets,
liabilities, capitalization, labor force, wage rates,
and productivity as a market-organized firm.
Indeed, a Chapter 11 proceeding may support, at
least temporarily, the continued existence of a
firm that otherwise would have been liquidated.
Corporate reorganization arguably
is always a smoother process for all concerned
rather than a straight liquidation under Chapter 7
of the Bankruptcy Code. That is why the threat of
filing a Chapter 7 petition serves management as
a strong bargaining tactic in dealing with credi
tors committees. Regardless of the outcome of a
Chapter 11 proceeding, all parties theoretically
have a sense of participation and partial control
in a corporate reorganization. If reorganization
produces a new firm that proves to be uncompet
itive, and if further restructuring is required, at
least the affected parties w ill have time to adjust
to the changed circumstances.
Yet, to the extent that a Chapter 11
petition thwarts the discipline of the market
place, the ultimate costs of corporate reorganiza
tion to society may be greater than those of cor
porate liquidation. This can occur because the
court’s judgment as to the viability of the reorgan
ized firm and any arrangement reflecting the
vested interests of the creditors may be wrong.
On the other hand, lawyers seem to believe that
creditors lawyers, bankruptcy judges, and trustees
usually assess the possibilities of corporate reor
ganizations accurately because of their repeated
experiences with working out the consequences
of Chapter 11 petitions. Also, the continued pres
ence of corporate management in debtor-in-
possession arrangements under most Chapter 11
plans guarantees that the role of business judg
ment will be significant. Thus, in the end, the
normal result of a corporate reorganization tradi
tionally has not been completely at odds with the
overall lessons o f hum an experience. 21
II. Priorities Among Creditors
Section 507 o f the Bankruptcy Code prescribes a
schedule of the priorities of distribution for
claims of classes of creditors in a bankruptcy pro
ceeding. A simplified listing of the priorities
under Section 507 is as follows:
Administrative expenses o f the
bankrupt’s estate.
Postpetition unsecured claims
arising prior to the appointment of a bankruptcy
trustee.
Up to $2,000 per claimant for
unsecured claims for accrued but unpaid wages,
salaries, commissions, vacation, and sick leave
pay.
After deducting the $2,000 per
employee above, unsecured claims for up to
$2,000 per claimant for contributions to
employee benefits.
Unsecured claims of farmers
against grain elevators or of fishermen against fish
processing plants.
Up to $900 per unsecured claim
ant for security deposits and down payments for
services not rendered or goods not provided.
Unsecured claims of govern
mental units for taxes, customs duties, and penal
ties accrued but unpaid.
Claims for employees wages and
benefits have third and fourth priority in the
schedule. General, unsecured, unsubordinated
1986 Quarter 3
claims, including the balance of claims for wages
and benefits, are given no priority and, thus,
effectively have eighth priority behind all
other classes of prior claims.
Secured claims are not subject to
the schedule of priorities, but bankruptcy trustees
may restrain secured creditors from realizing upon
their liens in return for providing adequate pro
tection” to the secured creditors while their claims
are stayed. Unfortunately, one man’s “adequate
protection may be another m ans outrageous in
fringement of rights. In practice, secured creditors
often are forced to renew their extensions of cred
it to bankrupt enterprises in order to allow those
enterprises to continue operating for the benefit
of all creditors, both secured and unsecured.
Holders of investment securities
have no priority of claim and generally are paid, if
at all, only after all prior classes of creditors are
paid in full. A normal ranking of security holders
is as follows:
Subordinated debt holders,
including bond and note holders.
Preferred shareholders.
Common equity shareholders.
2 2 Holders of investment securities
are referred to the terms of the relevant legal
documents to determine the relative priority of
different types of investment securities within the
classes of investment security holders.
III. Evolution of the Bankruptcy Code
The power to establish uniform laws on bank
ruptcies was given to Congress under Article I,
section 8, clause 4, of the United States Constitu
tion. Bankruptcy was bound up with controver
sies regarding debtors prison under the common
law and, for the first century of its existence, the
United States had no permanent bankruptcy law.1
Congress managed to keep bankruptcy laws on
the books only briefly, during the years 1800-
1803, 1841-1843, and 1867-1878. Disputes regard
ing the availability and liberality of discharges
from debts in bankruptcy proceedings created the
political pressures that caused the repeal of those
early bankruptcy acts. Generally, Jeffersonians,
Jacksonians, and Southern and Western Demo
crats favored liberal bankruptcy laws as a means
of discharging prior debts and granting debtors
fresh starts in life. Naturally, Tories, High Federal
ists, Whigs, and Republicans (that is, the creditor
class) opposed the liberal discharges available to
nonmerchant debtors under bankruptcy laws.2 In
I
A good overview of the comparative histories of the evolution of
bankruptcy acts in the United State s and the United Kingdom is
Vem Countryman, A History of American Bankruptcy Law, 81 Commer
cial Law Journal 226 (1976 ), from which much of the historical informa
tion in this commentary is taken.
the aftermath of the depression following the
Panic of 1893, the first permanent bankruptcy law
was passed in 1898. That legislation provided
principally for straight liquidations. Then, in fits
and starts between 1932 and 1938, in the throes
of resolving the problems of a time when “so
many were debtors, and so few were solvent,
the forerunners o f the reorganization provisions
of the present Bankruptcy Code were enacted in
1938. Provisions for corporate reorganizations
(Chapter 10) and corporate arrangements (Chap
ter 11) appeared for the first time as part of the
Chandler Amendments of 1938. Still, bankruptcy
was a defensive measure for corporate debtors,
and the requirement of corporate good faith in
filing bankruptcy petitions, not difficult to estab
lish during the Great Depression, routinely was
enforced by the courts.
The present Bankruptcy Code was
enacted in 1978. Chapters 10 and 11 of the 1938
bankruptcy act were combined in the new Chap
ter 11. Under the new Chapter 11, the stay of
creditors claims became automatic upon the fil
ing of the petition. The automatic stay was seen
as a procedural improvement from the debtors
perspective because, previously, the stay had to
be requested separately, and creditors could re
sist the application for a stay, even after the Chap
ter 11 petition was filed. Also, the requirement of
actual insolvency at the time of filing under the
1938 act was eliminated in the new Chapter 11.
The Bankruptcy Code was
amended in 1984, following a June 1982 United
States Supreme Court decision striking down cru
cial parts of the 1978 Code.3 The 1984 amend
ments primarily were procedural, covering the
jurisdiction and tenure of bankruptcy judges.
However, the 1984 amendments also restricted
the extent of discharges in consumer bankrupt
cies, established standards for judging the reaso
nableness of employers rejections of collective
bargaining agreements, reordered the priority of
distributions of stored grain to farmers, and
exempted certain repurchase agreements cover
ing financial instruments from the automatic stay
provisions of the Code.
2
See Countryman (id) at 229-230. Of course Jeffersonians object
ed when the first bankruptcy act (1800) made discharges availa
ble only to merchants. On the other hand, Hamiltonians found the act
useful. Robert Morris, once the financier of the American Revolution, and
by then the most daring real estate plunger in the United States,"
financed speculative housing development in the District of Columbia,
beginning in 1796. Unfortunately, in 179 7, a financial panic arose from
the outbreak of the wars between England and revolutionary France.
Morris was ruined and spent more than three years in the Philadelphia
debtors' prison. His discharge in 1801 under the 1800 bankruptcy act
probably was the most famous bankruptcy discharge in the nineteenth
century. See John C. Miller, The Federalist Era: 1780-1801, 252 (1960).
3
Northern Pipeline Construction Co. v. Marathon Pipe Line Co., 458
U .S . 50 (1982).
1986 Quarter 3
Throughout the evolution of the
present Bankruptcy Code, the statutes enacted
have been reasonably clear expressions of the
Congressional view that bankruptcy should be a
defensive, nonroutine measure and should not
be used to advance the financial interests of cor
porate debtors beyond the point that would have
been achieved by competition in a free market
among solvent corporations.
IV. Aggressive Uses of Bankruptcy
A potentially disturbing trend of filings under the
Bankruptcy Code began with the classic “surprise
filingby the Johns-Manville Corporation in 1982.
Johns-Manville, facing an unpredictable amount
of claims for damage thought to be caused by
asbestos, proposed a Chapter 11 reorganization
under which all present and future asbestos claim
ants would be reimbursed from a separate fund
created by Johns-Manville. Meanwhile, the normal
business operations of the corporation continued,
comparatively unimpeded by the claims of asbes
tos victims. The victims fund is to receive up to
$2.5 b illion over 25 years, including the contribu
tion of at least 50 percent of the comm on voting
equity shares of the corporation. The Johns-
Manville case has been questioned in some of
the bankruptcy literature as lacking the elements
of a good-faith filing, but at this writing it appears
that the settlement will stand.4
Other potentially disturbing bank
ruptcy decisions soon followed in the wake of
the Johns-Manville case. In February 1984, the
United States Supreme Court decided, 5-4, in
National Labor Relations Board v. Bildisco & Bil-
disco, Inc., that employers undergoing Chapter 11
reorganizations unilaterally may abrogate or m od
ify collective bargaining agreements that are
seriously burdensome to the employer when, on
balance, the equities of the case favor modifica
tion of burdensome terms.5
4
See, e.g., Mark J , Roe, Bankruptcy and Mass Tort, 84 Columbia
La w Review 846 (1984); No te, The Manville Corporation bank
ruptcy; an abuse of the judicial process? 11 Pepperdine L aw Review 151
(1983); Note, Manville: good faith reorganization or "insulated" bank
ruptcy? 12 Hofstra La w Review 121 (1983); N ote , Manville corporation
and the "good faith standard for reorganization under the Bankruptcy
Code, 14 University of Toledo La w Review 1467 (1983); Note , Manville
bankruptcy: treating mass tort claims in Chapter 11 proceedings, 96 Har
vard La w Review 112 1 (1983).
A thorough account of the Bildisco decision, 465 U .S . 513 (1984),
and the enactment of the collective bargaining provisions of the
Bankruptcy Code Am endments of 1984 is Thomas R. Haggard, The Con
tinuing Conflict Between Bankruptcy and Labor Law -The Issues that
Bildisco and the 1984 Bankruptcy Amendments Did Not Resolve, 1986
Brigham Young University L aw Review 1. See also, Benjamin Weintraub
and Alan N . Resnick, Bankruptcy La w Manual, Problems with Labor
Unions: Rejecting Collective Bargaining Agreements, paragraph 8.11 (9)
(1986). See In re Bildisco, 682 F.2 d 72 (3d Cir. 1982).
The Bildisco case illustrates the way
that bankruptcy courts usually resolve fundamen
tal conflicts between provisions of the Bankruptcy
Code and other provisions of federal law: Bank-
rupcty provisions prevail. It is only natural for
bankruptcy courts to consider the creation of via-
bly reorganized entities as their paramount duty
in Chapter 11 cases. The remedy for those dis
tressed by such tendencies on the part of the
bankruptcy courts is to petition Congress for
amendments to the Bankruptcy Code that would
specifically address such conflicts. However, as is
noted below, the bankruptcy courts have modified
somewhat their tendency to elevate bankruptcy
procedures above other considerations of federal
or state law only in environmental pollution cases.
Labor leaders lobbied Congress to
overturn the effect of the Bildisco decision, and
Congress did so in the July 1984 amendments to
the Bankruptcy Code (11 U.S.C. section 1113,
“Rejection of collective bargaining agreements).
Although they still allow employers to reject col
lective bargaining agreements, these amendments
establish standards for judging the reasonable
ness of the rejection in light of good-faith efforts
to negotiate modification o f the agreements. In 23
the first court test of the 1984 amendments, In re
Wheeling-Pittsburgh Steel Corp. (W.D. Pa. 1985),
the district court sustained an employer’s rejec
tion of wage provisions of a union contract under
section 1113, even though it was arguable that
the employer had not bargained in good faith on
the wage concessions. The union was holding
out for further bank lenders concessions before
agreeing to the wage concessions. Upon appeal
(May 1986), the Third Circuit Court of Appeals re
manded the case to the district court, finding that
the standards for rejection established by section
1113 of the Bankruptcy Code had not been met.6
In the Daikon Shield (intrauterine
device) litigation, a Chapter 11 filing by the AH.
Robins Company (March 1986) was intended to
forestall future product liability claims against the
company. At the date of filing, Robins had settled
9,300 claims for $517 m illion, with 5,000 more
claims still pending. As in the Johns-Manville case,
the Robins filing was intended to cut off future
product liability claims and to enable the rest of
the company to continue operating without the
burden of those claims. However, enough allega
tions of high-level corporate malfeasance emerged
in the Robins case that the court appointed a spe
cial m onitor to review the ongoing operations of
senior management. Management remains in
control of the company at this writing.7
Wheeling Pittsburgh Steel Corp. v. United Steelworkers of
America, 791 F.2d 1074 (3d Cir. 1986).
1986 Quarter 3
In other aggresive filing develop
ments under the Bankruptcy Code, a new line of
cases is evolving that might limit corporations
capacity to cut off liability for toxic waste pollu
tion of the environment by filing Chapter 11 peti
tions. In January 1986, the United States Supreme
Court decided, 5-4, that bankruptcy trustees may
not abandon corporate property under 11 U.S.C.
section 554 (a) that is burdensome to the bank
ruptcy estate if the abandonment causes envir
onmental damage that contravenes state laws or
health and safety regulations. The case decided in
January 1986 was Midlantic Bank v. New Jersey
Department of Environmental Protection, which
was an appeal of two 1984 Third Circuit cases
involving Quanta Resources Corporation.8 It is
noteworthy that, in the
Midlantic case, Justice
Rehnquist wrote the dissenting opinion which
stated, in relevant part:
The Bankruptcy Court may
not, in the exercise of its equitable powers,
enforce its views of sound public policy at
the expense of the interests the Code is
designed to protect. In these cases, it is
undisputed that the properties in question
24 were burdensome and of inconsequential
value to the estate. Forcing the trustee to
expend estate assets to clean up the sites
would plainly be contrary to the purposes
of the Code.
The Midlantic case involved a
liquidation, but comparable concerns would arise
in Chapter 11 cases if abandonment of contami
nated property seemed essential to achieving a
financially successful corporate reorganization. In
the future, it is not inconceivable that corpora
tions would attempt to cut off toxic waste liability
by filing Chapter 11 petitions with the intent to
abandon contaminated property. At present, the
weight of court decisions appears to be against
such aggressive use of Chapter 11 petitions.9
The original bankruptcy court order
in the Bildiscocase was issued in 1981. Since
then, Bildisco has had two progeny worthy of
note: Wilson Foods and Continental Air Lines. In
7
See A.H. Robins Co. v. Piccinin, 788 F.2 d 994 (4th Cir. 1986). The
Fourth Circuit upheld a preliminary injunction staying all claims
arising from Daikon Shield litigation against personally named co
defendants (typically, officers and directors of Robins) once the Robins
Chapter 11 petition w as filed. This decision is viewed as an affirmation
of the broad injunctive powers of a bankruptcy court to stay all claims
involving a debtor reorganizing under Chapter 11.
8
Midlantic, 474 U .S
___________
88 L.Ed .2 d 859 (1986). The
Supreme Court made a similar finding in the case of Ohio v. Ko-
vacs, 469 U .S
__________
, 83 L.Ed .2 d 6 49 (1985). In Kovacs, the
Supreme Court held that a discharge in bankruptcy was allowed for a
debtor whose property w as seized by a state receivership which began
to clean up a toxic w aste site and then ordered the debtor to pay for the
clean-up. The Supreme Court left for another ruling (Midlantic) the reso
lution of the issue of allowing bankruptcy trustees to abandon contami
nated property.
April 1983, Wilson, then the fifth-largest meat
packer in the United States, filed a Chapter 11 pe
tition in Oklahoma. W ilson then unilaterally re
jected collective bargaining agreements covering
two-thirds of its employees and reduced wages
by 40 to 50 percent. W ilson’s petition showed an
estimated positive net worth of more than $67
m illion. After reducing wages, Wilson was re
ported to have obtained a new line of credit for
$80 m illion from a New York City bank.10
In September 1983, Continental,
then the eighth-largest airline in the United States,
filed a Chapter 11 petition in Texas. Continental
had been bargaining with its employees for wage
concessions as part of a corporate strategy for be
coming an efficient, low-cost carrier in a deregu
lated environment. After the filing, Continental
unilaterally rejected contracts with several unions,
including the pilots union. All employees tempo
rarily were laid off. A few days later, one-third of
the employees were recalled, but new wages were
reduced from former levels by more than half in
some instances. Although Continental had a
heavy debt burden at the time of filing, net worth
still was positive. The reorganized Continental,
together with low-cost affiliates such as New York
Air, is a strong competitor over major airline
routes in the United States and on certain interna
tional routes; furthermore, it is usually mentioned
as a potential acquirer o f other, troubled airlines.
During the spring and summer of 1986, Conti
nental’s parent company, Texas Air, was involved
in negotiations to acquire Eastern Airlines and
People Express. At this writing, it appears that
those acquisitions will be consummated.
Taking the Chapter 11 baton from
Continental is Frontier Airlines, a unionized carrier
serving the western United States that was
acquired in 1985 by the ultimate low-cost air car
rier, People Express. Facing a heavy debt burden
and expanded price competition over most of its
domestic routes, People Express offered Frontier
for sale in the late spring of 1986. One potential
acquirer, United Airlines, was close to completing
the purchase of Frontier but, as of this writing,
has not done so.
One of the obstacles to Uniteds ac
quisition of Frontier was its inability to negotiate
9
In United States v. Maryland Bank & Trust Co.,
______
F.Sup p.
______
(D. M d „) slip op. Apr. 9, 1986), the environmental protec
tion laws were extended to enable the Environmental Protection Agency
to maintain lawsuits against innocent parties foreclosing on contami
nated property and to require them to pay for the costs of cleaning up
the property. It is believed that such precedents will complicate Chapter
11 proceedings in the future by raising the spectre of unscheduled liabili
ties in amounts that, if not stayed or discharged, would disrupt the
orderly reorganization of companies operating under Chapter 11 in cases
involving infringement of environmental protection laws.
1 Graeme Browning, Using Bankruptcy to Reject Labor Con-
U tracts, 70 American Bar Association Journal 60 (Feb. 1984).
1986 Quarter 3
a mutually satisfactory transitional salary scale for
Frontier’s pilots, who generally earned less than
United’s pilots. Other potential acquirers of Fron
tier apparently were w illing to purchase it only if
the collective bargaining agreements with the
principal Frontier unions were rejected. People
Express apparently threatened to file a Chapter 11
petition for Frontier in order to induce Frontiers
unions to be more forthcoming. Thus, the Fron
tier case illustrates another variation of the
aggressive use of Chapter 11 filings: The threat to
file becomes a bargaining chip in labor negotia
tions. United’s negotiations regarding Frontier
were interrupted by the filing of a Chapter 11
petition for Frontier on August 28, 1986.11
One debtor that has shown real
initiative following a bankruptcy reorganization is
Wickes Corporation, a California-based building
supply company that filed its Chapter 11 petition
in April 1982, shortly before the upturn from the
1981-82 recession began. Reorganized under
strong management, Wickes reduced operating
expenses, closed unprofitable stores, and renego
tiated or rejected a number of building leases for
its stores. Wickes emerged from Chapter 11 in
early 1985. A year later, in April 1986, Wickes
attempted to acquire the National Gypsum Cor
poration for approximately $1.2 billion. After that
takeover attempt failed, during August 1986,
Wickes mounted a new hostile tender offer for
Owens-Coming Fiberglas Corporation, Toledo,
Ohio. Wickes apparently intended to finance the
tender offer with an issue of so-called junk
bonds and with the planned post-acquisition
sale of Owens-Coming operations not closely
related to the core operations o f Wickes. The
tender offer was valued at $2.1 billion. O n August
29, 1986, Wickes terminated the offer, but analysts
estimated that Wickes had a net gain of at least
$30 m illion from the increased value of Owens-
Coming shares acquired during the takeover
attempt. It is significant that a company that not
long ago filed a Chapter 11 petition, apparently in
good faith, has been able to mount hostile tender
offers for multi-billion-dollar corporations within
little more than a year after ceasing to operate
under the supervision of a bankruptcy court.
V. Implications for the Bankruptcy System
The sequence of all the cases cited above is a
signal that something might be wrong in the
bankruptcy system. For bankruptcy specialists,
and for economists generally, those cases are like,
in the words of Thomas Jefferson, a fire-bell in
the night
...
[W] e have the wolf by the ears, and
we can neither hold him, nor safely let him go.
Justice is in one scale, and self-preservation in the
other.12 Jefferson was writing about the perni
cious effects of slavery on the preservation of the
Union and about the controversies raised by the
Missouri Compromise. The message of those
words, however, for defenders of the notions of a
free market and of market discipline in American
enterprise, is that actions currently taken under
Chapter 11, while perfectly legal under the pres
ent Bankruptcy Code, may be moving inexorably
in the direction of a race to the courthouse to
enable solvent, albeit troubled, corporations to
gain positive advantages over competitors. Such a
race for competitive advantage through the legal
process eventually undermines the free-market
system, as well as the other laws overridden by
the Bankrutpcy Code, such as environmental pro
tection or labor laws.
Yet, competitors in any line of bus
iness have the w olf by the ears in that they
cannot safely renounce the use of Chapter 11 fil
ings as a means of reducing operating costs
unless
all significant competitors in that line of 25
business refrain from filing as long as they are
solvent. Thus, justice (fair play) demands that all
solvent competitors refrain from filing, but self-
preservation demands that all competitors retain
the capacity to file as long as any significant com
petitor has that capacity.
If efficiency in the market is
achieved most easily by becoming a low-cost
producer under the protective umbrella of a
Chapter 11 filing, why should any corporation
exert itself to achieve efficiency by bargaining
and by open competition in a free market? Before
1978, a showing o f insolvency was a prerequisite
of a Chapter 11 filing, but that requirement was
dropped in the present Bankruptcy Code.13 The
question now presented is whether the benefits
that were supposed to flow from the removal of
the requirement of insolvency have been out
weighed by the deficiencies if they are, in fact,
deficiencies of the present statute. After all, in
the words of one bankruptcy expert,
Chapter 11 is supposed to be
rehabilitative,... a device “which can be
used to cure a company thats ill or hemor
rhaging. It is better to apply the cure while
a company has strength and vitality left
before letting it die.14
n
Press reports in early September 1986 indicated that Armco,
a major producer of steel, also allegedly w as using the threat
of a Chapter 11 filing to induce its employees union to make wage con
cessions. In fact, the union agreed to the concessions and no Chapter 11
petition was filed.
" I ^ Letter from Thom as Jefferson to Jo hn Holm es, April 2 2,18 2 0,
L d in The Portable Thomas Jefferson 567, Merrill D . Peterson
ed. (19 75 , reprinted 1980).
13
Browning, supra note 10.
1986 Quarter 3
Thus, it is important to remember
that not all observers believe that the present
uses of Chapter 11 are all bad. The issue of good
faith in filing could be addressed satisfactorily by
scrutinizing Chapter 11 filings in light of the
question: Is this company financially troubled
enough to justify the filing?By that standard,
some of the recent Chapter 11 filings (for exam
ple, Wickes, LTV, and Frontier) might not be par
ticularly troublesome.
VI. Summary
The law of bankruptcy has been intended since
1898 to grant debtors relief from claims of unse
cured trade creditors, bank lenders, and the like,
but not to affect substantially the claims of em
ployees for accrued, but unpaid, wages and bene
fits, or the claims of governmental units for taxes.
Such claims were, and still are, given priority in
the distribution of assets of bankruptcy estates.
Since 1982, a new trend has emerged in which
aggressive bankruptcy filings are used to achieve
the greater financial objectives of the corporations
filing Chapter 11 petitions. The 1984 amend-
2 6 ments to the Bankruptcy Code were intended to
rein in perceived abuses of the corporate capacity
to disavow employment contracts. Some may
argue that the July 17, 1986 filing by LTV Corpora
tion was yet another corporate effort in the direc
tion that was opposed by the 1984 amendments.
It is possible to contend that the filing was
designed to enable LTV to modify its collective
bargaining agreements substantially or to reject
future liability for employee benefits, including
pension or insurance liabilities. O n the other
hand, LTV clearly was having financial troubles,
and issues regarding the good faith of its failing
still have to be resolved by the bankruptcy court.
The cases described above fall into
three broad categories:
1. Contingent products liability or environ
mental protection
Johns-Manville (1982)
AH. Robins (1986)
Midlantic (1986) (Chapter 7)
2. Executory collective bargaining agreements
Bildisco (1981-1984).
Wilson Foods (1983)
Continental Air Lines (1983)
Frontier Airlines (1986)
3. Restructuring and downsizing corporate
liabilities
Wickes (1982)
Z7V(1986).
The Supreme Court thus far seems to be sustain
ing the primacy o f bankruptcy considerations in
the second and third categories of cases, while
continuing to sustain the primacy of environmen
tal protection laws in cases that do not involve
mass tort litigation.
In any case, it is clear that compan
ies with the benefit of the protection afforded by
Chapter 11 filings have advantages in corporate
financial structure that are not available to sim
ilarly situated, but presumably solvent, com peti
tors who do not file. Thus, it is reasonable to
predict that, in a disinflationary environment, an
increased number of aggressive Chapter 11 filings
will occur in any industry in which a significant
competitor alters its costs of production by filing
a Chapter 11 petition. In the absence of a more
orderly, formal procedure for downsizing corpo
rate assets and liabilities in the United States, such
a use o f Chapter 11 is neither illogical nor com
pletely unforeseeable. The remedy for aggressive
uses of Chapter 11, if a remedy becomes desira
ble as a matter of public policy, is to be found by
following the traditional path of Congressional
enactment of corrective amendments of the
Bankruptcy Code.
At the same time, the purpose of
the 1978 revisions of Chapter 11 should be kept
in mind: The rehabilitation of ailing companies
should be effected before they become termi
nally ill. If nothing concentrates the m ind like the
prospect of being hanged, then the opportunity
for a debtor to file a Chapter 11 petition before its
case is terminal ought to serve a constructive
purpose: It should encourage lenders,
employees, and the companys other constituent
groups to cooperate in attempting to improve the
chances for restoring the companys competitive
viability in order to avoid the filing. The same
spirit of cooperation should prevail if a filing
occurs despite everyone’s best efforts.
" I / Roy Carlin, Esq., bankruptcy counsel for Wilson Foods,
J L I quoted in Browning, supra note 10.
1986 Quarter 3
Economic Commentary
A Correct Value for the Dollar?
by Owen F. Humpage and
Nicholas V. Karamouzis
January 1, 1986
Bank H olding Company Voluntary
Nonbanking Asset Divestitures
by Gary Whalen
January 15, 1986
Ju nk Bonds and Public Policy
by Jerome S. Fons
February 1, 1986
Can W e Count on Private Pensions?
by James F. Siekmeier
February 15, 1986
Am erican A utom obile Manufacturing:
Its Turning Japanese
by Michael F. Bryan and Michael W. Dvorak
March 1, 1986
Should W e Be Concerned About the
Speed o f the Depreciation?
by Owen F. Humpage
March 15, 1986
The Government Securities Market
and Proposed Regulation
by James J. Balazsy,Jr.
April 1, 1986
A Revised Picture: Has O ur View
of the Economy Changed?
by Theodore G. Bernard
April 15, 1986
Monetary Policy Debates Reflect
Theoretical Issues
by James G. Hoehn
May 1, 1986
How G ood Are Corporate Earnings?
by Paul R. Watro
May 15, 1986
The Thrift Industry: Reconstruction
in Progress
by Thomas M. Buynak
June 1, 1986
The Emerging Service Economy
by Patricia E. Beeson and Michael F. Bryan
June 15, 1986
Domestic Nonfinancial Debt: After
Three Years o f Monitoring
by John B. Carlson
July 1, 1986
Equity, Efficiency, and
Mispriced Deposit Guarantees
by James B. Thomson
July 15, 1986
Target Zones for Exchange Rates?
by Owen F. Humpage and
Nicholas V. Karamouzis
August 1, 1986
W ill the D ollar’s Decline Help
O h io Manufacturers?
by Amy Durrell, Philip Israilevich,
and KJ. Kowalewski
August 15, 1986
Im plications of a Tariff on O il Im ports
by Gerald H. Anderson and KJ. Kowalewski
September 1, 1986
Alternative Methods for Assessing Risk-Based
Deposit-Insurance Premiums
by James B. Thomson
September 15, 1986
27
1986 Quarter 3
Economic Review
28
Quarter I 1985
Beauty and the Bulls: The Investment Character
istics of Paintings
by Michael F. Bryan
The Reserve Market and the Information Con
tent of Ml Announcements
by William T. Gavin and Nicholas V. Karamouzis
Quarter II 1985
Vector Autoregressive Forecasts of Recession
and Recovery: Is Less More?
by Gordon Schlegel
Revenue Sharing and Local Public Expenditure:
Old Questions, New Answers
by Paul Gary Wyckoff
Quarter III 1985
The Impact of Bank Holding Company Consoli
dation: Evidence from Shareholder Returns
by Gary Whalen
The National Debt: A Secular Perspective
by John B. Carlson and E. J. Stevens
The Ohio Economy: A Time Series Analysis
by James G. Hoehn and James J. Balazsy, Jr.
Quarter I 1986
The Impact of Regional Difference in Unionism
on Employment
by Edward Montgomery
The Changing Nature of Regional Wage Differ
entials from 1975 to 1983
by Lorie Jackson
Labor Market Conditions in Ohio Versus the
Rest of the United States: 1973-1984
by James L. Medoff
Quarter II 1986
Metropolitan Wage Differentials:
Can Cleveland Still Compete?
by Randall W. Eberts
and Joe A Stone
The Effects of Supplemental Income
and Labor Productivity on Metropolitan
Labor Cost Differentials
by Thomas F. Luce
Reducing Risk in Wire Transfer Systems
by E.J. Stevens
Quarter IV 1985
Stochastic Interest Rates in the Aggregate Life-
Cycle/Permanent Income Cum Rational Expec
tations Model
by Kim J. Kowalewski
New Classical and New Keynesian Models of
Business Cycles
by Eric Kades
1986 Quarter 3